[House Hearing, 105 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] REDUCING THE TAX BURDEN ======================================================================= HEARINGS before the COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED FIFTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION __________ JANUARY 28, FEBRUARY 4 AND 12, 1998 __________ Serial 105-97 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Ways and MeansU.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 60-897CC WASHINGTON : 2000 COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS BILL ARCHER, Texas, Chairman PHILIP M. CRANE, Illinois CHARLES B. RANGEL, New York BILL THOMAS, California FORTNEY PETE STARK, California E. CLAY SHAW, Jr., Florida ROBERT T. MATSUI, California NANCY L. JOHNSON, Connecticut BARBARA B. KENNELLY, Connecticut JIM BUNNING, Kentucky WILLIAM J. COYNE, Pennsylvania AMO HOUGHTON, New York SANDER M. LEVIN, Michigan WALLY HERGER, California BENJAMIN L. CARDIN, Maryland JIM McCRERY, Louisiana JIM McDERMOTT, Washington DAVE CAMP, Michigan GERALD D. KLECZKA, Wisconsin JIM RAMSTAD, Minnesota JOHN LEWIS, Georgia JIM NUSSLE, Iowa RICHARD E. NEAL, Massachusetts SAM JOHNSON, Texas MICHAEL R. McNULTY, New York JENNIFER DUNN, Washington WILLIAM J. JEFFERSON, Louisiana MAC COLLINS, Georgia JOHN S. TANNER, Tennessee ROB PORTMAN, Ohio XAVIER BECERRA, California PHILIP S. ENGLISH, Pennsylvania KAREN L. THURMAN, Florida JOHN ENSIGN, Nevada JON CHRISTENSEN, Nebraska WES WATKINS, Oklahoma J.D. HAYWORTH, Arizona JERRY WELLER, Illinois KENNY HULSHOF, Missouri A.L. Singleton, Chief of Staff Janice Mays, Minority Chief Counsel Pursuant to clause 2(e)(4) of Rule XI of the Rules of the House, public hearing records of the Committee on Ways and Means are also published in electronic form. The printed hearing record remains the official version. Because electronic submissions are used to prepare both printed and electronic versions of the hearing record, the process of converting between various electronic formats may introduce unintentional errors or omissions. Such occurrences are inherent in the current publication process and should diminish as the process is further refined. C O N T E N T S __________ Page Advisories announcing the hearing................................ 2 WITNESSES Congressional Budget Office, June E. O'Neill, Director........... 202 ______ American Council for Capital Formation, Mark Bloomfield.......... 264 American Family Business Institute, Harold I. Apolinsky.......... 112 American Farm Bureau Federation: Carl B. Loop, Jr............................................. 109 Dean Kleckner................................................ 305 American Forest & Paper Association, Douglas P. Stinson.......... 125 American Institute of Certified Public Accountants: David Lifson................................................. 69 Michael Mares................................................ 170 American Tree Farm System, Douglas P. Stinson.................... 125 Apolinsky, Harold I., American Family Business Institute, and Small Business Council of America.............................. 112 Associated General Contractors of America, Richard Forrestel, Jr. 104 Bartlett, Bruce R., National Center for Policy Analysis.......... 75 Beach, William W., Heritage Foundation........................... 137 Blair, Robert A., S Corporation Association...................... 237 Bloomfield, Mark, American Council for Capital Formation......... 264 CATO Institute, Stephen Moore.................................... 230 Clements, Christopher and Kimberly, National Beer Wholesalers Association, and Golden Eagle Distributors, Inc................ 98 Cold Spring Construction Company, Richard Forrestel, Jr.......... 104 Communicating for Agriculture, Wayne Nelson...................... 243 Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm, Douglas P. Stinson...................... 125 Cox, Hon. Christopher, a Representative in Congress from the State of California............................................ 93 Entin, Stephen J., Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation....................................................... 276 Feenberg, Daniel, National Bureau of Economic Research........... 65 Florida Farm Bureau Federation, Carl B. Loop, Jr................. 109 Forest Industries Council on Taxation, Douglas P. Stinson........ 125 Forrestel, Richard, Jr., Associated General Contractors of America, and Cold Spring Construction Company.................. 104 Foster, J.D., Tax Foundation..................................... 157 Golden Eagle Distributors, Inc., Christopher and Kimberly Clements....................................................... 98 Graetz, Michael J., Yale Law School.............................. 48 Hannay, Roger, National Association of Manufacturers, and Hannay Reels, Inc..................................................... 134 Hartman, David A., Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation, and Hartland Banks, N.A............................................ 309 Herger, Hon. Wally, a Representative in Congress from the State of California.................................................. 15 Hulshof, Hon. Kenny C., a Representative in Congress from the State of Missouri.............................................. 253 Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation, David A. Hartman.......... 309 Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation, Stephen J. Entin.......................................................... 276 Kelly, W. Thomas, Savers & Investors League...................... 326 Kies, Kenneth J., Price Waterhouse LLP........................... 187 Kleckner, Dean, American Farm Bureau Federation.................. 305 Kucinich, Hon. Dennis J., a Representative in Congress from the State of Ohio.................................................. 256 Lifson, David, American Institute of Certified Public Accountants 69 Loop, Carl B., Jr., American Farm Bureau Federation, Florida Farm Bureau Federation, and Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses, Inc..... 109 Mallory, Sharon, and Darryl Pierce, Straughn, IN................. 19 Mares, Michael, American Institute of Certified Public Accountants.................................................... 170 McCrery, Hon. Jim, a Representative in Congress from the State of Louisiana...................................................... 91 McIntosh, Hon. David M., a Representative in Congress from the State of Indiana............................................... 18 Mizell, Jeannine, U.S. Chamber of Commerce, and Mizell Lumber and Hardware Company, Inc.......................................... 128 Moore, Stephen, CATO Institute................................... 230 National Association of Manufacturers, Roger Hannay.............. 134 National Beer Wholesalers Association, Christopher and Kimberly Clements....................................................... 98 National Bureau of Economic Research, Daniel Feenberg............ 65 National Center for Policy Analysis, Bruce R. Bartlett........... 75 National Society of Accountants, and National Tax Consultants, Inc., William Stevenson........................................ 281 Nelson, Wayne, Communicating for Agriculture..................... 243 Regalia, Martin A., U.S. Chamber of Commerce..................... 164 Riley, Hon. Bob, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama........................................................ 37 Salmon, Hon. Matt, a Representative in Congress from the State of Arizona........................................................ 35 Savers & Investors League, W. Thomas Kelly....................... 326 S Corporation Association, Robert A. Blair....................... 237 Serotta, Abram, Serotta, Maddocks, Evans & Co.................... 215 Small Business Council of America, Harold I. Apolinsky........... 112 Stevenson, William, National Society of Accountants, and National Tax Consultants, Inc........................................... 281 Stinson, Douglas P., American Forest & Paper Association, American Tree Farm System, Forest Industries Council on Taxation, Washington Farm Forestry Association, and Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm................................................ 125 Tax Foundation, J.D. Foster...................................... 157 Thune, Hon. John R., a Representative in Congress from the State of South Dakota................................................ 154 U.S. Chamber of Commerce: Jeannine Mizell.............................................. 128 Martin A. Regalia............................................ 164 Washington Farm Forestry Association, Douglas P. Stinson......... 125 Weller, Hon. Jerry, a Representative in Congress from the State of Illinois.................................................... 12 SUBMISSIONS FOR THE RECORD American Bar Association, Section of Taxation, statement......... 338 American Trucking Associations, Inc., Robert C. Pitcher, Alexandria, VA, statement...................................... 344 Bond Market Association, statement............................... 346 Distribution & LTL Carriers Association, Alexandria, VA, Kevin M. Williams, statement............................................ 348 Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation, Michael Schuyler, statement and attachments............................ 350 Johnson, Calvin H., University of Texas at Austin, School of Law, letter and attachments......................................... 365 Kennelly, Hon. Barbara B., a Representative in Congress from the State of Connecticut........................................... 9 Kleczka, Hon. Gerald D., a Representative in Congress from the State of Wisconsin............................................. 11 National Air Transportation Association, Alexandria, VA, statement...................................................... 375 National Cattlemen's Beef Association, Clark S. Willingham, statement...................................................... 376 North Dakota Public Service Commission, Bruce Hagen, statement... 377 White House Conference on Small Business, statement.............. 378 REDUCING THE TAX BURDEN ---------- WEDNESDAY, JANUARY 28, 1998 House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, Washington, DC. The Committee met, pursuant to notice, at 11:35 a.m., in room 1100, Longworth House Office Building, Hon. Bill Archer (Chairman of the Committee) presiding. [The advisories announcing the hearings follow:] ADVISORY FROM THE COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS CONTACT: (202) 225-1721 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE January 21, 1998 No. FC-10 Archer Announces Hearing Series on Reducing the Tax Burden Congressman Bill Archer (R-TX), Chairman of the Committee on Ways and Means, today announced that the Committee will hold a hearing series on proposals to reduce the Federal tax burden on the American public. The hearing will begin on Wednesday, January 28, and be continued on Wednesday, February 4, and Thursday, February 12, 1998, in the main Committee hearing room, 1100 Longworth House Office Building, beginning at 10:00 a.m. each day. The first hearing day will address proposals intended to correct perceived unfairness in the tax code, focusing on the ``marriage tax penalty,'' and the estate and gift tax (or ``death tax''). Oral testimony for January 28th will be from invited witnesses only. Both invited and public witnesses will have the opportunity to testify on Feb 4th and 12th. Any individual or organization not scheduled for an oral appearance may submit a written statement for consideration by the Committee or for inclusion in the printed record of the hearing. BACKGROUND: The Federal tax burden, as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product, has been rising in recent years. It is currently 19.9 percent, a height not reached since World War II. The annual Federal budget deficit has declined greatly over the past several years, and current projections show years of budget surpluses. The rising tax burden and improved fiscal outlook have elicited various tax reduction proposals. This hearing series is designed to explore some of these proposals. In announcing the hearing, Chairman Archer stated: ``If the politicians in Washington exercise restraint, we soon may find ourselves in a post-deficit era, where our greatest challenges will be social and moral, not economic. I believe the era we're entering will test how big a government the people want, or whether they want a smaller, less taxing government that enhances individual power, freedom, and opportunity, strengthening our moral fabric, freeing families to provide more for themselves, their neighbors and their communities. We must care for each other more, and tax each other less.'' FOCUS OF THE HEARING: The first hearing day will address proposals intended to rectify perceived unfair provisions in the tax code. It will focus on the ``marriage tax penalty'' and the estate and gift tax (or ``death tax''). The second day (February 4th) will consider tax rates: What are they and what should they be? That session also will address alternative minimum tax relief for individuals, proposals to reduce Federal income or payroll taxes, and provisions in the tax code that operate as ``hidden rates'' and which cause effective tax rates to exceed statutory rates. The third day (February 12th) will review new savings incentives and likely will address modifications to the new capital gains law, such as eliminating the 18-month holding period for the new 10 and 20 percent capital gain rates, and proposals to provide an exclusion for interest and dividend income. The hearing may be continued on additional days on other tax reduction topics. DETAILS FOR SUBMISSIONS OF REQUESTS TO BE HEARD: Requests to be heard on February 4th and February 12th must be made by telephone to Traci Altman or Bradley Schreiber at (202) 225-1721 no later than the close of business, Thursday, January 29, 1998. The telephone request should be followed by a formal written request to A.L. Singleton, Chief of Staff, Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, 1102 Longworth House Office Building, Washington, D.C. 20515. The staff of the Committee will notify by telephone those scheduled to appear as soon as possible after the filing deadline. Any questions concerning a scheduled appearance should be directed to the Committee staff at (202) 225-1721. In view of the limited time available to hear witnesses, the Committee may not be able to accommodate all requests to be heard. Those persons and organizations not scheduled for an oral appearance are encouraged to submit written statements for the record of the hearing. All persons requesting to be heard, whether or not they are scheduled for oral testimony, will be notified as soon as possible after the filing deadline. Witnesses scheduled to present oral testimony are required to summarize briefly their written statements in no more than five minutes. THE FIVE-MINUTE RULE WILL BE STRICTLY ENFORCED. The full written statement of each witness will be included in the printed record, in accordance with House Rules. In order to assure the most productive use of the limited amount of time available to question witnesses, all witnesses scheduled to appear before the Committee are required to submit 300 copies of their prepared statement and an IBM compatible 3.5-inch diskette in ASCII DOS Text or WordPerfect 5.1 format, for review by Members prior to the hearing. Testimony should arrive at the Committee office, room 1102 Longworth House Office Building, 48 hours prior to each hearing day (no later than 10:00 a.m.). WRITTEN STATEMENTS IN LIEU OF PERSONAL APPEARANCE: Any person or organization wishing to submit a written statement for the printed record of the hearing should submit at least six (6) single-space legal-size copies of their statement, along with an IBM compatible 3.5-inch diskette in ASCII DOS Text or WordPerfect 5.1 format only, with their name, address, and hearing date noted on a label, by the close of business, Wednesday, March 11, 1998, to A.L. Singleton, Chief of Staff, Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, 1102 Longworth House Office Building, Washington, D.C. 20515. If those filing written statements wish to have their statements distributed to the press and interested public at the hearing, they may deliver 200 additional copies for this purpose to the Committee office, room 1102 Longworth House Office Building, at least one hour before the hearing begins. FORMATTING REQUIREMENTS: Each statement presented for printing to the Committee by a witness, any written statement or exhibit submitted for the printed record or any written comments in response to a request for written comments must conform to the guidelines listed below. Any statement or exhibit not in compliance with these guidelines will not be printed, but will be maintained in the Committee files for review and use by the Committee. 1. All statements and any accompanying exhibits for printing must be typed in single space on legal-size paper and may not exceed a total of 10 pages including attachments. At the same time written statements are submitted to the Committee, witnesses are now requested to submit their statements on an IBM compatible 3.5-inch diskette in ASCII DOS Text or WordPerfect 5.1 format. Witnesses are advised that the Committee will rely on electronic submissions for printing the official hearing record. 2. Copies of whole documents submitted as exhibit material will not be accepted for printing. Instead, exhibit material should be referenced and quoted or paraphrased. All exhibit material not meeting these specifications will be maintained in the Committee files for review and use by the Committee. 3. A witness appearing at a public hearing, or submitting a statement for the record of a public hearing, or submitting written comments in response to a published request for comments by the Committee, must include on his statement or submission a list of all clients, persons, or organizations on whose behalf the witness appears. 4. A supplemental sheet must accompany each statement listing the name, full address, a telephone number where the witness or the designated representative may be reached and a topical outline or summary of the comments and recommendations in the full statement. This supplemental sheet will not be included in the printed record. The above restrictions and limitations apply only to material being submitted for printing. Statements and exhibits or supplementary material submitted solely for distribution to the Members, the press and the public during the course of a public hearing may be submitted in other forms. Note: All Committee advisories and news releases are available on the World Wide Web at `HTTP://WWW.HOUSE.GOV/WAYS__MEANS/'. The Committee seeks to make its facilities accessible to persons with disabilities. If you are in need of special accommodations, please call 202-225-1721 or 202-226-3411 TTD/TTY in advance of the event (four business days notice is requested). Questions with regard to special accommodation needs in general (including availability of Committee materials in alternative formats) may be directed to the Committee as noted above. ***NOTICE--CHANGE IN TIME*** ADVISORY FROM THE COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS CONTACT: (202) 225-1721 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE January 23, 1998 No. FC-10-Revised Time Change for Full Committee Hearing on Wednesday, January 28, 1998, on Reducing the Tax Burden Congressman Bill Archer (R-TX), Chairman of the Committee on Ways and Means, today announced that the full Committee hearing on reducing the tax burden, previously scheduled for Wednesday, January 28, 1998, at 10:00 a.m., in the main Committee hearing room, 1100 Longworth House Office Building, will begin instead at 11:30 a.m. All other details for the hearing remain the same. (See full Committee press release No. FC-10, dated January 21, 1998.) Chairman Archer. The Committee will come to order. I would like our guests and staff to take seats as quickly as possible so that we can commence. Today is the first in a series of hearings to examine proposals to reduce the tax burden on individuals while correcting perceived unfairness in the Tax Code. This will probably be a neverending task as long as we have the income tax, but we must proceed to do the best that we can. The tax burden on the American people is the highest in our Nation's peacetime history. The social and moral consequences of high taxation on America's families are devastating. Families are struggling today because the government is taking their money before they have a chance to invest it in themselves, their children, and their communities. It's money that is denied to workers, diminishing their ability to pay for their own childcare needs, healthcare needs, or to prepare for their retirement years in comfort and security. American workers are caught in a tax trap. The harder they work, the longer they work, the more they pay. Can the people in the back of the room hear me? This is very important. I want everyone to be able to hear. Mr. McDermott. There's nothing wrong with the speakers down here. Chairman Archer. I can hear you very well. Be sure that the PA system works the same for Charlie Rangel when it's his turn. [Laughter.] American workers are truly caught in a tax trap today in the United States because the longer they work, the harder they work, the more they pay. That is wrong. It shouldn't be that way. I personally believe that we must care for each other more and tax each other less. That is why, to strengthen families and children while protecting against big government, we must reduce the debt and the record high tax burden on the American people. We must remember that when we pay down the debt, that helps preserve Social Security without forcing Americans to pay record high taxes. There is room both to save Social Security and to protect Americans from high taxes. Yes, Congress must shore up Social Security, and we will do so. But we must also look at the ways our existing Tax Code unfairly prevents individuals from saving more of their income to reach their retirement goals. If we agree to the President's request to maintain the high tax status quo, we will perpetuate a marriage penalty on 21 million couples. We will force more than 25 million Americans, many of whom make as little as $26,000 a year, into higher tax brackets. The first focus of this morning's hearing will be the marriage tax penalty. Based on a recent CBO study, matrimony translates into an average of $1,400 in additional taxes for some 42 percent of American couples. The marriage tax penalty is a well-known topic on Capitol Hill. As many will recall, the Contract With America and the Balanced Budget Act of 1995 contained provisions to lessen the tax bite on working married couples. This relief suffered under the veto pen of the President, so it is important that we turn our attention once again to what 21 million married couples perceive as unfair. I am pleased that we are joined this morning by Sharon Mallory and Darryl Pierce of Indiana, who will share with the Committee their personal experience with the marriage penalty. Today's hearing will also focus on the death tax, which with its estate, gift, and generation-skipping components, can cause the tax collector to compound the tragedy of a family death by taking over half of the deceased person's lifetime savings. I must add, that's only the beginning. As you get into the later years of your life, if you continue to produce and to earn more, you will have up to 44 percent in income tax taken out of your earnings. The remaining amount will be taxed at 55 percent, so that your heirs, your children, will receive only 25 percent of what you have worked very hard in your later years to be able to accomplish. The death tax forces the sale or reorganization of family-owned businesses and it costs jobs. It creates development pressure on farm and ranch land, and contributes to the loss of open space. Last year we were able to take a first step to providing relief from the death tax. We convinced the Clinton administration to support death tax relief after they initially accused those who sought such reductions as being ``selfish.'' As I said earlier, taxes are at a record high level. I hope no one will defend the high tax status quo. The purpose of these hearings is to listen to various tax relief proposals so the Committee can determine which taxes should be reduced. I intend to be conservative in my approach. I will resist the temptation to over promise. We are still within the constraints of reducing the deficit and keeping a balanced budget. Yes, there is room to pay down the debt and to cut taxes. But no, we must never let the budget be tipped out of balance again. Before we begin, I would like to recognize Mr. Rangel for any comments that he might like to make. Mr. Rangel. That's very kind of you, Mr. Chairman. Welcome back. As the Committee starts to work, I think the better we can understand the agenda, the more closely we can work together as Democrats and Republicans. I gather from what I have heard over the airwaves and read in the paper that your top priority is going to be rooting up or pulling out the IRS and bringing a flat tax, consumption tax or some kind of tax that would be even-handed across the board. If that is your priority, since I have been waiting for it for 3 years, do you have any idea whether we might get a chance to vote for that in this Committee? I hate to be against something when I haven't the slightest idea what it's going to be. Will we have a chance to vote on any of these simplified taxes this year? Chairman Archer. We would be happy to have the outward expressed support, Mr. Rangel, of you and the Minority on the Committee. I am sure we could move the bill rather rapidly when that occurs. The President has not seen fit to make any proposal for structural tax reform. So perhaps it will be left up totally to the Congress. It needs to be bipartisan. It can not be driven just by one party. It's too important to the lives of all the people in this country. Mr. Rangel. But it's hard to know which idea we're supporting. There are so many different ideas. You have some and Mr. Armey has some. They were all in the closet. So if someone could get organized and bring something to us, then we can see whether or not the bill with its simplification and its cost would warrant us joining together to pass it. So would that be done this year or are we just going to just air it out and let people be educated about the possibility of changing the system? Chairman Archer. I think it's very hard to predict what we will do in that regard this year. I do know that we will continue to have hearings on this issue, where all Members will be able to become better versed on the various reform plans and be able to crystallize their own opinion as to what vehicle they believe is the best. But at this point, I cannot anticipate whether we will have a markup of a bill. But I can anticipate this: we will have a tax relief bill within the current income tax of some kind this year. Mr. Rangel. I think then my Democratic colleagues on the Committee won't have to worry about the flat tax this year. We can concentrate on some of the ideas that the President has. You might have noticed, Mr. Chairman, that the President had any number of ideas that fell within the jurisdiction of this Committee. Certainly Social Security, low-income housing credits, expansion of Medicare, educational zones, childcare, school construction, and the African trade bill. My God, it looked like a program just designed for us. Now I share your concern about the marriage tax penalty and the death taxes and the other reduction in taxes that you have, but so that we might be able to plan and work more closely together, could you give me any idea of when you intend to see whether or not the President's agenda would be able to get on the Ways and Means calendar? Chairman Archer. As we move through the various items that are before the Committee, particularly with each individual Subcommittee, there will be plenty of opportunity to flush out all proposals and consider all options this year. Mr. Rangel. Welcome back, Mr. Chairman. I'm glad I won't have much time to deal with the flat tax, but there's so many other things that we could work on, I look forward to working with you. Chairman Archer. You are most welcome, Mr. Rangel. Should you wish to submit any proposal on your own as to what is the appropriate way to restructure the income tax, we would be pleased to have that in the hopper too. Mr. McDermott. Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Yes. Mr. McDermott. Mr. McDermott. Mr. Chairman, I would like to ask unanimous consent to enter my statement in the record. I offered to eliminate the marriage tax penalty last year. I want the record to show that all the Republicans voted against my repeal proposal last year which was the same as your 1995 tax proposal. So it will be interesting to hear the rhetoric today about this whole issue as we come back to it. Chairman Archer. Without objection, all Members will be able to insert any written statement into the record at this point. [The opening statements follow:] Opening Statement of Hon. Jim McDermott, a Representative in Congress from the State of Washington I applaud the Chairman for choosing to hold a hearing on the problem of the marriage penalty. This is an issue which I tried to address during last year's Balanced Budget debate. The proposal I offered last year, which I would like to mention today, would have eliminated the marriage penalty for many taxpayers by adjusting the standard deduction. It was not a new idea. The proposal I advocate was included in the 1995 Budget Conference report passed by Congress. To be fair, you could characterize this as a bipartisan fix to the marriage penalty. The marriage penalty fix I support simply would increase the standard deduction for joint filers so that it equals twice that of single filers. The standard deduction in tax year 1997 is $6,900 for joint returns and $4,150 for single returns. Two singles get a combined standard deduction of $8,300 compared to $6,900 for a couple--thus penalizing the couple for getting married. In my view, increasing the standard deduction for joint filers is the simplest, fairest, easiest, and most fiscally responsible way in which to address the structural marriage tax penalties within the code. As you can see from the attached charts to be inserted into the record, the fix I proposed last Congress would have eliminated virtually all marriage penalties, and, it even provides a modest bonus for one-earner families. The McDermott plan is progressive: Since most high-income taxpayers do not use the standard deduction, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) has found that only 36% of the benefits from this type of change goes to taxpayers earning $50,000 or more--meaning--64% of the benefits go to couples earning less than $50,000/year. CBO found that other leading repeal proposals direct at least 65% of the benefits to those taxpayers earning more than $50,000/year. The McDermott plan is comparatively affordable: CBO estimates that increasing the standard deduction for joint filers costs roughly $4 billion/year. Estimates prepared by the Joint Committee on Taxation verify this finding. Meanwhile, CBO found other leading repeal proposals cost as much as $29 billion/year. The McDermott plan is family friendly: In addition to eliminating the marriage penalty, the standard deduction fix slightly increases the marriage bonus (see charts)--making it more affordable for the spouses of single earners who prefer to have a parent stay at home to care for their child or children. This bonus provides a small incentive without creating a new program and is not excessive so that it overly penalizes individuals for being unmarried. The McDermott plan is simple compared to the problems raised by other repeal proposals which will force taxpayers to do their taxes twice in order to figure out which is the best choice for their family. In 1997, repeal of the marriage penalty was pushed aside by the Republican Majority. Inexplicably, in the W&M Committee, where roughly 20 members signed the Contract with America, my amendment failed. Most likely, the Majority preferred cutting taxes for corporations (not mentioned in their contract). In my view, a tactical decision was made that it was more important to provide tax cuts preferred by the business community (such as reducing the corporate AMT and corporate capital gains tax cuts) than it was to address the marriage penalty. In fact, no legislation was introduced during the 105th Congress to repeal the marriage penalty until after the budget agreement passed Congress last August. Now that repeal of the marriage penalty is finally being addressed and if it sincerely is a priority of this Congress, I would urge my colleagues to take a second look at my proposal before they rush to advocate an alternative. Structural Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses in 1997 Dollar and Percentage Amounts by which Joint Income Tax Liabilities Exceed those of Two Singles (Marriage Tax Bonus Shown in Parenthesis) ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Income Levels Joint Income ($000s) Tax Liability 50/50 60/40 70/30 100/0 ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- $20 $1,170 $210 22% $345 42% $378 48% ($810) (41%) $25 $1,920 $210 12% $210 12% $384 25% ($810) (30%) $30 $2,670 $210 9% $210 9% $269 11% ($810) (23%) $35 $3,420 $210 7% $210 7% $210 7% ($1,272) (27%) $40 $4,170 $210 5% $210 5% $210 5% ($1,922) (32%) $50 $5,670 $210 4% $210 4% (252) (4%) ($3,222) (36%) $60 $8,028 $1,068 15% $1,476 6% (304) (4%) ($3,664) (31%) $75 $12,228 $1,444 13% $1,256 11% $281 2% ($3,918) (24%) $100 $19,228 $1,444 8% $1,444 8% $1,152 6% ($4,668) (19%) ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source: CRS McDermott Amendment Changes the Structural Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses: Dollar and Percentage Amounts by which Joint Income Tax Liabilities Exceed those of Two Singles (Marriage Tax Bonus Shown in Parenthesis) ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Income Levels Joint Income ($000s) Tax Liability 50/50 60/40 70/30 100/0 ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- $20 $960 $0 -- $135 16% $108 13% ($1,020) (52%) $25 $1,710 $0 -- $0 -- $174 11% ($1,020) (37%) $30 $2,460 $0 -- $0 -- $59 2% ($1,020) (29%) $35 $3,210 $0 -- $0 -- $0 -- ($1,482) (32%) $40 $3,960 $0 -- $0 -- $0 -- ($2,132) (35%) $50 $5,460 $0 -- $0 -- ($462) (8%) ($3,432) (39%) $60 $7,636 $676 10% $84 1% ($696) (8%) ($4,058) (35%) $75 $11,836 $1,052 10% $864 8% ($111) (1%) ($4,310) (27%) $100 $18,836 $1,052 6% $1,052 6% $760 4% ($5,060) (21%) ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source: CRS Statement of Hon. Barbara B. Kennelly, a Representative in Congress from the State of Connecticut Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for the opportunity to testify here today. As you well know, I have worked on the marriage penalty for many years. In fact, CBO recently completed an excellent report on the topic for me. For those of you who may not have seen it, it is entitled ``For Better or for Worse: Marriage and the Federal Income Tax.'' I commend it to your attention. Copies are available by calling CBO or my office. First, let me briefly summarize the problem. According to CBO, based on sheer numbers of returns, an estimated 42% of couples incurred marriage penalties in 1996, 51% received bonuses, and 6% paid taxes unaffected by their marital status. That distribution varies markedly across the income distribution. Only 12% of couples with incomes below $20,000 sustained penalties and 63% received bonuses. Couples with incomes between $20,000 and $50,000 were somewhat more likely to receive bonuses than to incur penalties, whereas couples with incomes above $50,000 were somewhat more likely to incur penalties than to receive bonuses. Couples with just one earner never incur a marriage penalty and receive a bonus at all but the lowest income levels. Three factors have the greatest influence on whether a couple bears a marriage penalty or receives a marriage bonus: the couple's total income, the division of the income between husband and wife, and the presence and number of children that determine the filing status of unmarried individuals and qualify taxpayers for the EITC and personal exemption. The largest bonuses, measured as a percentage of income, occur in two cases. First, two-earner couples with one child and very low incomes split equally between spouses receive a larger EITC as the credit phases in and thus receive a bonus of up to 13% of their income. Second, low-income single-earner couples in which each spouse has one child, and for whom combining children into one tax unit increases the size of the EITC, receive bonuses of up to 11% of income. The largest bonuses in dollar terms--more than $5,600--go to childless one- earner couples with incomes between $180,000 and $190,000. The largest penalties, measured as a percentage of income, are greatest for low-income couples who have several children and an equal division of income between spouses; the loss of EITC on joint returns can cost such families up to 18% of income. In dollar terms, the penalty resulting from difference in tax brackets, limitations on itemized deductions, and the phaseout of personal exemptions combine to impose the maximum penalty--more than $21, 599--on couples whose income is equally divided between spouses and whose taxable income exceeds $527,500. Although the prevalence of marriage penalties and bonuses indicates that the tax code fails to provide marriage neutrality, it more successful in achieving equal treatment of married couples with similar incomes. If couples were required to file individual tax returns, those with one earner would face substantially higher tax rates than those with two earners who have roughly equal incomes. Because the tax code generally requires couples to file jointly, those with different divisions of earnings between spouses incur more nearly equal tax rates. Marriage penalties and bonuses arise from this equalization of tax rates for couples with different divisions of earnings. Marriage penalties and bonuses are not deliberately intended to reward or punish marriage. Rather, they are the result of a delicate balance of disparate goals of the federal income tax system. The principal goals are equal treatment of married couples, marriage neutrality and progressive taxation and they are in fundamental conflict. Nonetheless, as two-earner couples become more prevalent, more and more Americans will incur marriage penalties. For this reason, I think it is important that we move to provide more equitable treatment for these working couples, consistent of course, with our other goals. Therefore, I am pleased to be here today with my friend and colleague, Representative Herger and support H.R. 2593. This bill would simply restore the pre-1986 law--the two-earner deduction. It would allow couples a 10% deduction for up to $30,000 of the lower-earning spouse's income. I offered a version of this as an amendment in Committee during the markup of the Republican Contract with America. I think it is a reasonable solution to a very difficult problem and would urge my colleagues to support H.R. 2593. Thank you. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.001 Chairman Archer. We are fortunate to have with us today Members of our own body, Mr. Weller, Mr. McIntosh, and Mr. Herger. We are happy to have you here. We would be pleased to hear your testimony. I have already spoken about Sharon Mallory and Darryl Pierce, who are coming with Congressman McIntosh. You might wish to further introduce them. We'll be pleased to receive their testimony. But first, Mr. Weller, we would be happy to have your testimony. STATEMENT OF HON. JERRY WELLER, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF ILLINOIS Mr. Weller. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First, I want to commend you and this Committee for conducting these hearings on inequities in the Tax Code, and thank you for inviting our colleagues to testify on clearly what is arguably our Tax Code's most unfair provision, the marriage tax penalty. I know from my conversations with you, Mr. Chairman, this has been an area of great concern to you over the years. I really appreciate your leadership in working on this issue. Last night, President Clinton gave his State of the Union address outlining many of the things he wants to do with the budget surplus. The surplus provided by the bipartisan budget agreement which cut waste, put America's fiscal house in order, and held Washington's feet to the fire to balance the budget for the first time in 28 years. While President Clinton paraded a long list of new spending items totalling at least $46 to $48 billion in 30 new programs and proposals, we believe that a top priority should be returning the budget surplus to America's families as additional middle-class tax relief. This Congress has given more tax relief to the middle class and the working poor than any Congress in the last half century. I think the issue of the marriage tax penalty can best be framed by asking these questions. Do Americans feel it's fair that our Tax Code imposes a higher tax penalty on marriage? Do Americans feel it's fair that the average married working couple pays almost $1,400 more in taxes than a couple with almost identical income living together outside of marriage? Is it right that our Tax Code provides an incentive to get divorced? In fact, today the only form one can file to avoid the marriage tax penalty is paperwork for divorce. That's just wrong. Since 1969, our tax laws have punished married couples when both spouses work. For no other reason than the decision to be joined in holy matrimony, more than 21 million couples a year are penalized. They pay more in taxes than they would if they were single. Not only is the marriage tax penalty unfair, it's wrong that our Tax Code punishes society's most basic institution. The marriage tax penalty exacts a disproportionate toll on working women and low-income couples with children. In many cases, it's a working woman's issue. Let me give you an example, and there's a chart to my right, an example of how the marriage tax penalty unfairly affects middle-class, married, working couples. For example, in my district, I'll use an example of a machinist at the local Caterpillar manufacturing plant in Joliet, who makes $30,500 a year in salary. His wife is a tenured elementary schoolteacher, also bringing home an identical income of $30,500 a year in salary. If they both filed their taxes as singles, after standard deductions and exemptions, as individuals they would pay in the 15 percent tax bracket. But if they choose to live their lives in holy matrimony and now file jointly, their combined income is $61,000, and pushes them into a higher tax bracket of 28 percent, producing a marriage tax penalty of $1,400 in higher taxes. On average, America's married working couples pay $1,400 more a year in taxes than individuals with the same incomes. That's serious money. Every day we get closer to April 15, more married, working couples will be realizing that they are suffering the marriage tax penalty, and will be looking to us to do something about it. Why? Because if you think of it in terms that mean something to the folks back home, $1,400 is a downpayment on a house, several months worth of car payments, 1 year's tuition at a local community college, or several months worth of quality childcare at a local daycare center. To that end, Congressman David McIntosh and I have authored the Marriage Tax Elimination Act. It would allow married couples a choice in filing their income taxes, either jointly or as individuals, whichever way lets them keep more of their money. Our bill already has the bipartisan cosponsorship of 232 Members of the House, and a similar bill in the Senate also enjoys widespread support. It isn't enough for President Clinton to suggest tax breaks for childcare. The President's childcare proposal would help a working couple afford on average 3 weeks of daycare. Elimination of the marriage tax penalty would give the same couple the choice of paying for 3 months of childcare or addressing other family priorities. After all, parents know best, in fact better than Washington what their family needs. We fondly remember the 1996 State of the Union address when the President declared emphatically that ``the era of big government is over.'' We must stick to our guns and stay the course. There never was an American appetite for big government, but there certainly is for reforming the way the existing way government does business. What better way to show the American people that our government will continue along the path to reform prosperity than by eliminating the marriage tax penalty. Ladies and gentlemen, we are on the verge of running a surplus. It's basic math. It means Americans are already paying more than is needed for government to do the job we expect of it. What better way to give back than to give mom and dad and the American family, the backbone of our society, what they have earned. We ask President Clinton to join with Congress and make elimination of the marriage tax penalty a bipartisan priority. Of all the challenges facing married couples today in providing home and hearth for America's children, the U.S. Tax Code should not be one of them. Let's eliminate the marriage tax penalty, and do it now. Again, thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Jerry Weller, a Representative in Congress from the State of Illinois Mr. Chairman: I want to commend you for holding these hearings on inequities in the tax code and thank you for inviting my colleagues and I to testify on what is arguably the most immoral provision in our tax code...the marriage tax penalty Last night, President Clinton gave his State of the Union Address outlining many of the things he wants to do with the budget surplus. A surplus provided by the bipartisan budget agreement which: cut waste, put America's fiscal house in order, and held Washington's feet to the fire to balance the budget. While President Clinton paraded a long list of new spending proposals--without mentioning the accompanying increase in bureaucracy and red tape--we believe that a top priority should be returning the budget surplus to America's families as additional middle-class tax relief. This Congress has given more tax relief to the middle class and working poor than any Congress of the last half century. I think the issue of the marriage tax penalty can best be framed by asking these questions: Do Americans feel its fair that our tax code imposes a higher tax penalty on marriage? Do Americans feel its fair that the average married working couple pays almost $1,400 more in taxes than a couple with almost identical income living together outside of marriage--is it right that our tax code provides an incentive to get divorced? In fact, today the only form one can file to avoid the marriage tax penalty is paperwork for divorce. Since 1969, our tax laws have punished married couples when both spouses work. For no other reason than the decision to be joined in holy matrimony, more than 21 million couples a year are penalized. They pay more in taxes than they would if they were single. Not only is the marriage penalty unfair, it's immoral that our tax code punishes society's most basic institution. The marriage tax penalty exacts a disproportionate toll on working women and lower income couples with children. Let me give you an example of how the marriage tax penalty unfairly affects middle class married working couples. For example, a machinist, at a Caterpillar manufacturing plant in my home district of Joliet, makes $30,500 a year in salary. His wife is a tenured elementary school teacher, also bringing home $30,500 a year in salary. If they would both file their taxes as singles, as individuals, they would pay 15%. But if they chose to live their lives in holy matrimony, and now file jointly, their combined income of $61,000 pushes them into a higher tax bracket of 28 percent, producing a tax penalty of $1400 in higher taxes. On average, America's married working couples pay $1,400 more a year in taxes than individuals with the same incomes. That's serious money. Particularly if you think of it in terms of: a down payment on a house or a car, one years tuition at a local community college, or several months worth of quality child care at a local day care center. To that end, Congressman David McIntosh and I have authored the Marriage Tax Elimination Act. It would allow married couples a choice in filing their income taxes, either jointly or as individuals--which ever way lets them keep more of their own money. Our bill already has the support of 232 Members of the House and a similar bill in the Senate also enjoys widespread support. It isn't enough for President Clinton to suggest tax breaks for child care. The President's child care proposal would help a working couple afford, on average, three to four weeks of day care. Elimination of the marriage tax penalty would give the same couple the choice of paying for three to four months of child care--or addressing other family priorities. After all, parents know better than Washington what their family needs. We fondly remember the 1996 State of the Union address when the President declared emphatically that, quote ``the era of big government is over.'' We must stick to our guns, and stay the course. There never was an American appetite for big government. But there certainly is for reforming the existing way government does business. And what better way to show the American people that our government will continue along the path to reform and prosperity than by eliminating the marriage tax penalty. Ladies and Gentleman, we are on the verge of running a surplus. It's basic math. It means Americans are already paying more than is needed for government to do the job we expect of it. What better way to give back than to begin with mom and dad and the American family--the backbone of our society. We ask that President Clinton join with Congress and make elimination of the marriage tax penalty... a bipartisan priority. Of all the challenges married couples face in providing home and hearth to America's children, the U.S. tax code should not be one of them. Lets eliminate The Marriage Tax Penalty and do it now! Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Congressman Weller. Now, Congressman Wally Herger. STATEMENT OF HON. WALLY HERGER, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA Mr. Herger. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee for the opportunity to testify today about a serious inequity in the Tax Code. When a couple stands at the altar and says ``I do,'' they are not agreeing to higher taxes. Yet under our current tax law, that is precisely what is happening to millions of married couples each year. According to a recent report by the Congressional Budget Office, an estimated 42 percent of all married couples, some 21 million couples nationwide, incurred marriage penalties in 1996. The average marriage penalty that year approached an astonishing $1,400. I believe that addressing this inequity in our tax law should be a top priority for this Committee as we work to provide the American people further tax relief in 1998. Mr. Chairman, as financial pressures push more and more nonworking spouses into the labor force, an increasing number of families will fall prey to this marriage tax. A major reason why so many of these joint filers face this added tax burden is that the very first dollar earned by the low-earning spouse is taxed at the marginal rate of the high-earning spouse, not necessarily at the lower 15-percent rate faced by single filers. This problem was exacerbated in 1993 when the number of tax brackets was increased from three to five. That change created even more opportunities for dual-income, married couples to be bumped into higher brackets, and to face even larger marriage penalties. To address this problem, I have introduced legislation along with Mrs. Kennelly to restore the two-earner deduction. As many of you may remember, between 1982 and 1986, dual-income couples were entitled to a significant tax benefit to help offset the marriage penalties built into the Internal Revenue Code. The two-earner deduction, once fully phased in, entitled married couples to a 10-percent deduction on up to $30,000 of the low-earning spouse's income. However, for a variety of reasons, Congress eliminated this tax benefit in 1986. My bill, H.R. 2593, the Marriage Penalty Relief Act, would simply restore the two-earner deduction. I am pleased to report that this legislation has attracted a broad bipartisan group of 155 cosponsors in the House so far, including 35 Democrats. I am particularly gratified that 27 Members of this Committee, 21 Republicans and 6 Democrats, have thus far signed onto this legislation. I should make it clear for the record, Mr. Chairman, that I strongly support a complete elimination of the marriage penalty. I am an original cosponsor to the bill introduced by Mr. Weller and Mr. McIntosh. I am encouraged to learn that the Congressional Budget Office is now projecting a $660 billion surplus over the next 10 years. I sincerely hope that this fiscal dividend can be used in part to ensure that our Tax Code no longer punishes married couples. However, I also recognize that Members of this body and of this Committee have a variety of ideas about where to dedicate this projected surplus. If budgetary and political conditions prevent us from completely eliminating the marriage penalty in this year's tax bill, I would certainly hope that we can at least take a significant step toward achieving that objective. Mr. Chairman, restoring the two-earner deduction would enable us to make meaningful progress toward that goal in a way that provides targeted relief to those couples who are particularly hard hit by this inequity. When a couple stands at the altar and says ``I do,'' they are not agreeing to higher taxes. Congress should act this year to address the fact that in too many cases, they will be paying higher taxes. I want to again thank Chairman Archer for the opportunity to testify. I look forward to working with all interested Members on this issue as the Committee works to provide the American people further tax relief this year. I would also like to ask that Mrs. Kennelly's statement in support of my legislation, which she had hoped to deliver today in person, be included in the record following my testimony. Thank you. [The prepared statements follow:] Statement of Hon. Wally Herger, a Representative in Congress from the State of California Thank you Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee for the opportunity to testify today about a serious inequity in the tax code. When a couple stands at the altar and says ``I do,'' they are not agreeing to higher taxes. Yet under our current tax law, that is precisely what is happening to millions of married couples each year. According to a recent report by the Congressional Budget Office, an estimated 42 percent of all married couples--some 21 million couples nationwide--incurred marriage penalties in 1996. The average marriage penalty that year approached an astonishing $1,400. I believe that addressing this inequity in our tax law should be a top priority for this Committee as we work to provide the American people further tax relief in 1998. Mr. Chairman, as financial pressures push more and more non-working spouses into the labor force, an increasing number of families fall prey to this marriage tax. A major reason why so many of these joint filers face this added tax burden is that the very first dollar earned by the lower-earning spouse is taxed at the marginal rate of the higher-earning spouse, not necessarily at the lower 15-percent rate faced by single filers. This problem was exacerbated in 1993 when the number of tax brackets was increased from three to five. That change created even more opportunities for dual-income married couples to be bumped into higher brackets and to face even larger marriage penalties. To address this problem, I have introduced legislation-- along with Mrs. Kennelly--to restore the two-earner deduction. As many of you may remember, between 1982 and 1986, dual-income couples were entitled to a significant tax benefit to help offset the marriage penalties built into the Internal Revenue Code. The two-earner deduction, once fully phased in, entitled married couples to a 10-percent deduction on up to $30,000 of the lower-earning spouse's income. However, for a variety of reasons, Congress eliminated this tax benefit in 1986. My bill, H.R. 2593--``The Marriage Penalty Relief Act''-- would simply restore the two-earner deduction. I am pleased to report that this legislation has attracted a broad, bipartisan group of 155 cosponsors in the House so far, including 35 Democrats. I am particularly gratified that 27 members of this Committee--21 Republicans and 6 Democrats--have thus far signed on to this legislation. I should make it clear for the record, Mr. Chairman, that I strongly support a complete elimination of the marriage penalty and am an original cosponsor of the bill introduced by Mr. Weller and Mr. McIntosh. I am encouraged to learn that the Congressional Budget Office is now projecting a $660 billion surplus over the next 10 years, and I sincerely hope that this fiscal dividend can be used, in part, to insure that our tax code no longer punishes married couples. However, I also recognize that members of this body--and of this Committee--have a variety of ideas about where to dedicate this projected surplus. If budgetary and political conditions prevent us from completely eliminating the marriage penalty in this year's tax bill, I would certainly hope that we can at least take a significant step toward achieving that objective. Mr. Chairman, restoring the two-earner deduction would enable us to make meaningful progress toward that goal in a way that provides targeted relief to those couples who are particularly hard-hit by this inequity. When a couple stands at the altar and says ``I do,'' they are not agreeing to higher taxes. Congress should act this year to address the fact that in too many cases, they will be paying higher taxes. I want to again thank Chairman Archer for the opportunity to testify today, and I look forward to working with all interested members on this issue as the Committee works to provide the American people further tax relief this year. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.002 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Congressman Herger. Congressman McIntosh, you may proceed in any way you see fit. If you wish to give a statement and then introduce Ms. Mallory and Mr. Pierce, that's fine. If you want them to speak first, that's fine. The floor is yours. You may proceed. STATEMENT OF HON. DAVID M. MCINTOSH, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF INDIANA Mr. McIntosh. Thank you, Chairman Archer, Mr. Chairman, excuse me. I want to say I appreciate the Committee hearing this issue today, and more importantly, the spotlight that you are able to shed on this important issue. Let me first introduce Sharon and Darryl. The Committee can hear from them directly. Then I would like to add a statement about the importance of this issue. Sharon and Darryl are two constituents of mine. Sharon wrote me a letter last February that really moved me to find out what is at stake in this marriage penalty issue. She explained that she and Darryl both work at the Ford Motor plant in Connersville. They live in a small rural community in my district, make about $10 an hour. Darryl does a little farming on the side. They wanted to get married. They went to H&R Block to find out what would be the consequences, if they got married, on their tax form. Well, as Sharon put it in her letter, not only would she have to give up her $900 refund, she found out that together they would pay $2,800 in taxes. Quite frankly, they couldn't afford it, Mr. Chairman, and wrote to me that they can't afford to get married, and wanted Congress to do something about this unfair marriage penalty in the Tax Code. It broke their hearts. Well, it broke my heart when I heard their story. They have been kind enough to tell their story to others and to come here today. So why don't I now turn it over to Sharon Mallory. Sharon and Darryl, if you want to share your thoughts about this penalty and how it affects you, and then I'll have a statement at the end of that, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF SHARON MALLORY AND DARRYL PIERCE, STRAUGHN, INDIANA Ms. Mallory. My name is Sharon Mallory, of Straughn, Indiana. Mr. Thomas. Sharon, excuse me. These microphones are horrible today, worse than usual. If you speak directly into it, you might have a better chance. We do want to hear your message. Thank you. Ms. Mallory. My boyfriend Darryl Pierce and I are constituents of Congressman David McIntosh. Darryl and I love each other very much and want to be married, but the IRS won't let us. We are victims of the marriage penalty. We traveled here from Indiana today to tell the Committee how the marriage penalty affects us, and to urge the Committee to adopt legislation introduced by Congressman David McIntosh and Congressman Jerry Weller to eliminate the marriage penalty. Darryl and I both work at the former Ford Electronics Plant in Connersville, southeast of Indianapolis near the Indiana/ Ohio border. We make less than $10 and work overtime whenever it is available. Darryl does some farming on the side to supplement our income. Last year Darryl and I decided we wanted to get married. However, when we went to our accountant in an H&R Block office in New Castle, Indiana, she said that not only would I forfeit my $900 refund, but that we would also have to write a check to the IRS for $2,800. To us, this is real money. It's food on our table and clothes on our backs. For Darryl and me, the marriage penalty was large enough that we were forced to put off our marriage. Last February, I wrote to Congressman McIntosh about our situation. In my letter, I wrote, ``Darryl and I would very much like to be married. I must say it broke our hearts when we found out we can't afford it. We hope some day the government will allow us to get married by not penalizing us.'' I know that Congress and the President wouldn't purposely single out married couples for higher taxes, but that is the effect of this tax. I understand the Committee and the Congress may have different ideas about how to cut people's taxes this year. Let me urge you to include eliminating the marriage penalty on the top of your list. It is too important an issue for too many families to ignore. According to the Congressional Budget Office, 21 million families pay an average of $1,400 more in Federal taxes just because they are married. This cannot be allowed to continue. Strong families are the backbones of strong communities and the heart of a strong country. I don't know how many other couples postpone or cancel their marriages because of the marriage penalty, but one family is one too many. By approving legislation to eliminate the marriage penalty, this Congress can do something that will help millions of families in a real and tangible way. I urge you to approve this legislation as soon as possible. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Sharon Mallory and Darryl Pierce, Straughn, Indiana My name is Sharon Mallory of Straughn, Indiana. My boyfriend, Darryl Pierce, and I are constituents of Congressman David McIntosh. Darryl and I love each other and very much want to be married. But the IRS won't let us. We're are victims of the marriage penalty. We traveled here from Indiana today to tell the committee how the marriage penalty affects us--and to urge the committee to adopt legislation introduced by Congressmen David McIntosh and Congressman Jerry Weller to eliminate the marriage penalty. Darryl and I both work at the former Ford Electronics plant in Connersville, southwest of Indianapolis near the Indiana- Ohio border. We make less than $10 and work overtime whenever it is available. Darryl does some farming on the side to supplement our income. Last year, Darryl and I decided we wanted to get married. However, when we went to our accountant in an H & R Block office in New Castle, Indiana, she said that not only would I forfeit my $900 refund but that we also would have to write a check to the IRS for $2800. To us, this is real money. It's food on our table and clothes on our children's backs. For Darryl and me, the marriage penalty was large enough that we were forced to put off our marriage. Last February I wrote to Congressman McIntosh about our situation. In my letter, I wrote: ``Darryl and I would very much like to be married and I must say it broke our hearts when we found out we can't afford it. We hope someday the government will allow us to get married by not penalizing us.'' I know that Congress and the President wouldn't purposefully single out married couples for higher taxes. But that's the effect of this tax. I understand that the committee and the Congress may have different ideas about how to cut people's taxes this year. Let me urge you to include eliminating the marriage penalty at the top of your list. It's too important an issue for too many families to ignore. According to the Congressional Budget Office, 21 million families pay on average $1,400 more in federal taxes just because they're married. This cannot be allowed to continue. Strong families are the backbones of strong communities--and the heart of a strong country. I don't know how many other couples postpone or cancel their marriages because of the marriage penalty. But one family is too many. By approving legislation to eliminate the marriage penalty, this Congress can do something that will help millions of families in a real and tangible way. I urge you to approve this legislation as soon as possible. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Ms. Mallory. Mr. McIntosh. Mr. Chairman, is there still time available for my statement or do you need to move on? Chairman Archer. If you can make it as brief as possible, yes. Your entire written statement, without objection, will be inserted in the record. Mr. McIntosh. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would also ask, Jerry and I have received numerous correspondence and e-mails from people like Sharon and Darryl about the marriage penalty, if we could also ask permission to submit those as part of the record as well. Chairman Archer. Without objection. Mr. McIntosh. I would just make two points to the Committee. One, this marriage penalty disproportionately discriminates against women. When the Tax Code was written in the sixties with the married filing jointly, most families in this country had one wage earner, traditionally the husband. Today, that has changed. Seventy-five percent of the families have both spouses working. When the wife decides to go to work, perhaps she has been out of the job force raising children and goes back to finish her career, she gets hit with all of that penalty, as much as a 50 percent marginal tax on her income. So some have said that Jerry Weller and David McIntosh's bill would be the Working Women's Tax Relief Act of 1998, because they are hit disproportionately and unfairly by this marriage penalty. The second point that has come out in research recently by a professor at the University of Cincinnati Law School, is that minority families are also disproportionately discriminated against by this penalty. That is because oftentimes the woman's income in those families is of a greater percentage than traditional families in the whole of the population in the United States. Therefore, they suffer a larger penalty when you look at minority families as compared to typical families in the United States. That's because oftentimes they have to have two people working in order to earn enough money to get ahead and have a chance to survive in our economy. So this bill to eliminate the marriage penalty not only would strengthen families, but it would eliminate a policy that discriminates against women and discriminates against minorities as well. I wanted to make sure that that point was in the record, and will submit my testimony, the complete testimony for the Committee. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, very much. I know you care a great deal about this issue. I appreciate this hearing. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of Hon. David M. McIntosh, a Representative in Congress from the State of Indiana Mr. Chairman, fellow members of the Committee, I want to thank you for inviting here before this prestigious body to speak about the Marriage Penalty, but much more importantly, you have my profound gratitude for shining the public spotlight on this insidious tax. As Sharon and Darryl's testimony makes so heart-breakingly clear, the marriage tax is immoral. There's no more adequate way to describe a designed government policy which undermines the traditional institution of the family and, most tellingly, discriminates against women and minorities. The marriage penalty entered our tax code thirty years ago and has systematically undermined the family ever since. The trend in our nation has seen a decrease in marriage and increase in divorce. Many people, like Sharon and Darryl, want to marry but cannot afford it. Divorce is reaching epidemic levels. There are twice as many single parent households in America today since the marriage penalty came into effect.\1\ The terrible financial strain caused by the marriage penalty contributes to this. Simply put, the marriage penalty is doing great harm to our society by frustrating family cohesion. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ The Statistical Abstract of the United States, Department of Commerce, Table No. 146, ``Marriages and Divorces,'' p. 104: 1996. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- The devastating consequences of divorce on parents and children are well documented. When parents divorce, they are likely to die earlier, their general health is worse, and sadly, many divorced adults, particularly young mothers, are thrown into poverty.\2\ The effects on children are no less devastating. The National Fatherhood Initiative has shown that where there is a divorce, the children are more prone to violence, illegal drugs, suicide, and drop out of school. Over Ninety percent, Ninety percent!, of children on welfare are from homes with only one parent.\3\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \2\ Dr. Wade Horn, The National Fatherhood Initiative, ``Father Facts 2,'' p.10: 1997. \3\ Ibid. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- And by the way, don't interpret these facts as an attack on single mothers. I was raised by a single mom. I know the sacrifices she made for us. Single moms are heroes born out of necessity. Let us simply get rid of the government penalties that push these moms toward divorce and illegitimacy. Big government in Washington and its marriage penalty tax have become the number one enemy of the American family and its affects on working women and minorities are particularly devastating. The marriage penalty could equally be known as ``The Tax on Working Women.'' When the marriage penalty was proposed America was a far different place and large numbers of women were not yet in the workforce. Today, 75 percent of married couples have two incomes.\4\ The marriage penalty almost always hits the second-earner the hardest. Therefore, this tax clearly discriminates against women who may chose to enter the workforce to provide a better life for their family. These women can be taxed at an astounding 50% marginal rate.\5\ The Weller-McIntosh Tax on Working Women Elimination Act is the ultimate piece of legislation in the women's liberation movement. If our bill passes, women--and men--will have much greater freedom to choose to work without having to worry about the taxman. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \4\ The Congressional Budget Office, ``For Better of for Worse: Marriage and the Federal Income Tax,'' (June 1997), Table 10, p.39. \5\ The Greater Washington Societies of Certified Public Accountants, Sept. 1997 --------------------------------------------------------------------------- African-Americans are particularly devastated by the marriage tax. The marriage penalty occurs when both spouses work and make roughly the same income and black women historically have entered the workforce in larger numbers and make comparatively more money than whites. 73% of married back women are breadwinners and black women contribute approximately 40% of their household's income.\6\ Our legislation brings fairness back into the tax code so that African-American women and families can keep more of their hard earned money to provide for their children. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \6\ Dorothy Brown, ``The Marriage Bonus/Penalty in Black and White,'' University of Cincinnati Law Review (Spring 1997), p.5. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- I know you agree with me that we must completely rid our tax code of this bill that hurts families, working women, and minorities. Therefore, I categorically reject those who have said that the federal government can't afford it. No one in Congress asked married people if they could afford it when they passed it. It's time for the federal government to tighten its belt to help families. I say we cannot afford to allow it to continue because of its pernicious effects on families. I will work with this committee to ensure adequate funding to eliminate the marriage penalty is included in the budget resolution. To guarantee support from those who favor eliminating the marriage penalty, the budget resolution must include enough resources to abolish the marriage penalty. Mr. Chairman, we in Congress must be held accountable for failing to respond to the American people when we defy the traditional values of the American people. We have a choice. We can continue down the path of destroying the family, penalizing marriage in our tax code, the path of high crime, drug use, divorce, and children being brought up without knowing the difference between right and wrong. Or we can choose a different path: a path based on the firm conviction that the family must be the foundation of our society. We can choose a path where families are lifted up--not punished by government. It is the way by which young people like Sharon and Darryl can find happiness and finally be married. I believe most strongly that for our nations' future, we must choose to lift up the family. I joined Jerry Weller in introducing legislation to eliminate the marriage penalty and remove one more obstacle in the recovery of the family. Even if some in Washington scoff at this idea, the American people have a special wisdom in these matters. They will support our efforts to succeed in this effort to eliminate the marriage penalty. It is crucial that we succeed because the success of the family and the success of America are inseparable. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would ask that I could submit a speech I gave on the marriage penalty as well as a marriage penalty paper prepared by my office for the record. TO RENEW THE AMERICAN FAMILY by David McIntosh, R-IN Speech to Christian Coalition, September 13, 1997 Some say that it takes a village to raise a child. No! It takes a family and it will take a family to rebuild our nation and once again make it the guiding moral light for this world. These are two competing visions for America's future. One is right. One is wrong. Putting the family first, builds a great nation. But putting the village--that is the government--first, tears down the family and the nation crumbles. We, as a nation, must learn from history that societies which rely on government, instead of families,to solve their problems never prosper. 500 years before Christ, the prophet Nehemiah returned to Jerusalem, the city of his forefathers and found it in ruins. The City wall had broken down and thieves and marauders preyed upon the people. Even worse, the Bible says that the Israelites were forced to pay excessively high taxes, to a remote government in a far off capital. Families had to sell their property and give up on their inheritance just to pay what the King of Persia's tax collectors extorted from them. We know Nehemiah set about rebuilding the walls of Jerusalem using the strength of the family. He assigned each family a piece of the wall to rebuild. When his enemies threaten to kill the Israelites, Nehemiah mounted a family defense. ``Don't be afraid. Remember the Lord, who is great and awesome, and fight for your brothers, your sons and your daughters, your wives and your homes.'' With each family defending a portion of the wall, Nehemiah defeated his enemies. 500 years before Christ the people of Israel followed God's plan, employed a family defense, rebuilt the walls of a new Jerusalem, and were blessed with a society that was moral and just. History repeats itself. Let us fast forward to today, nearly 2000 years after the death of Christ, and ask ourselves: What is happening in America? America that for 200 years was founded on the principle that God has blessed every man and woman in this nation with certain inalienable rights, among them, life, liberty, and the pursuit of happiness. America that has become for most of the world a shinning city on the hill in which truth, justice, and freedom are hallmarks of everything we do. For the last thirty-years, America has turned away from the commandment to entrust the family with the well-being of our society. Indeed, America's government has begun to systematically punish the family. Starting in 1969, America has taxed married couples more than if they are divorced or single. That is the year the marriage penalty entered into our tax code. Today, 21 million couples in America suffer and strain under a marriage penalty tax. The average cost to the family is $1,400 a year. Here is how the marriage penalty works. First, when a young couple decide to get married they pay higher rates and lose some of their deductions. Second, when the couple has children they are penalized once again. Under the budget we passed, many families only receive a portion of the $500 tax child credit because they are married and earn too much money. Third, when their children go to college the family is punished by paying higher taxes on savings they use to pay tuition. Fourth, when they retire, they are penalized in Social Security and Veterans benefits, if they remarry. The worst part of the marriage penalty is that it discriminates against women who, when their children are old enough, want to go back into the workforce to provide an even better life for their family. These women can be taxed at an astounding 50% marginal rate. This is wrong. Washington should not punish families that need two incomes to make ends meet. A constituent of mine, Sharon Mallory, wrote me an anguished letter about how this marriage tax hurt her. Let me read to you from her letter. ``Dear Congressman McIntosh, My boyfriend, Darryl Pierce, and I would very much like to get married....We both work at Ford Electronics and make less than $10.00 an hour; however, we do work overtime whenever it is available....I can't tell you how disgusted we both are over this tax issue....If we get married not only would I forfeit my $900 refund check, we would be writing a check to the IRS for $2,800....Darryl and I would very much like to be married and I must say it broke our hearts when we found out we can't afford it.'' Sadly, Darryl and Sharon's story is not unique. One of my staff in Muncie, Indiana told me of a young couple, who asked not to be named, that has a terrible problem in their family. They were driving home one evening and were struck by an on- coming car. The couple's 6 year-old daughter suffered severe brain damage. She is now having to learn to walk and talk all over again. Our government, out of compassion for people like this, has programs to assist families and allow them to pay for their medical bills. This family went to a government case- worker to seek help for their little girl's therapy. The devastated parents were told that the husband makes 10 dollars more a year than the government will allow in order to qualify for any assistance. What did the case worker say to the family? That they have two choices. One, the father can quit his job and go on welfare. And if that's not bad enough, The second choice was that they can get a divorce! The mother can take the child and qualify for government assistance. Once again, I say this tax is wrong and immoral. Our government should not force 21 million families to choose between divorce and economic prosperity, on the one hand, or staying married and financial hardship, on the other. In the Gospel of St. Matthew, Christ said about the family ``What therefore God hath joined together, let not man put asunder.'' Our government has ignored this warning. What are the consequences of such folly? Look at what has happened to America during these last thirty years? Each of us, as we look around in our neighborhoods and our streets and our cities, know that the family is under assault. In Hollywood, on the Internet, and in Washington, the family is a favorite and familiar target. This barrage has weakened the family as the foundation of our society. In our inner cities, in our small towns across America, and in our neighborhoods, the walls of our communities, built up by the American family, are crumbling. We face a crisis in our country. In the last thirty years, since the marriage penalty began, 9 million couples decided not to get married in the United States. Many of these young people are like Sharon and Darryl who want to marry but cannot afford it. 2 million more marriages ended in divorce, And there are twice as many single parent households. What does this breakdown of the family mean for mothers and fathers, and most importantly, for the children of broken families? Studies show that when parents divorce, they are four times as likely to die early,e more respiratory and digestive illnesses. And sadly, many divorced adults, particularly young mothers, are thrown into poverty. The effects on children are no less devastating. The National Fatherhood Initiative has shown that where there is a divorce, the children are prone to violence. 72 percent of juvenile murderers and 60 percent of America's rapists grew up in homes without fathers. They are 4 times more likely to use illegal drugs; 3 times more likely to commit suicide, and twice as likely to drop out of school. When they join the workforce, their pay is lower, with less of a chance to be promoted. These poor children, who are not responsible for their fate, are even more likely to be trapped in a cycle of poverty. Over Ninety percent, Ninety percent!, of children on welfare are from homes with only one parent. And by the way, don't interpret these facts as an attack on single mothers. I was raised by a single mom. I know the sacrifices she made for us. Single moms are heroes born out of necessity. Let us simply get rid of the government penalties that push these moms toward divorce and illegitimacy. Big government in Washington and its marriage penalty tax have become the number one enemy of the American family. My friends, we cannot let this stand. We must pass a bill that Jerry Weller and I have introduced into Congress that eliminates the marriage penalty from the tax code. Our bill is simple--It says families may choose. If they pay less taxes filing jointly as a normal couple, they may do so. If they pay lower taxes by filing as individuals, they may choose to do that instead of having to file for a divorce to get this tax break. The prophet Jeremiah says: ``Stand at the crossroads and look. Ask for the ancient paths. Ask where the good way is. And walk in it.'' My friends, as the 20th century draws to an end,America indeed stands at a crossroad. We have a choice. We can continue down the path of destroying the family, penalizing marriage in our tax code, the path of high crime, drug use, divorce, and children being brought up without knowing the difference between right and wrong. Or we can choose a different path: a path that is based on the ancient ways of Nehemiah where we recognize that the family must be the foundation of our society. We can choose a path where families are lifted up--not punished by government. It is the way by which young people like Sharon and Darryl can find happiness and finally be married. It is the path that allows Americans to provide for their children without the government pressuring them to divorce. Again, the choice is ours. For the sake of America, and freedom, and the young boys and girls who are our nations' future, we must choose to lift up the family. I feel it is my personal calling to begin by fighting with every ounce of my being to end the marriage penalty tax once and for all. I ask you in the Christian Coalition to join me in this calling. Let us act boldly, with the courage of our convictions, to link arm and arm and march to Washington with the goal of unconditional surrender. Let us never stop praying that our nation's leaders will understand that the laws of this land must not try to ``put asunder what God has brought together.'' let us call on our nation's leaders, our leaders in Congress, and the President to: Demand that families are put at the head of our national agenda. Demand that America once again has a government that respects the sanctity of marriage. We will be silent no longer. Tonight, we say to Sharon and Darryl and to all those facing marriage penalties: No more broken promises. No more broken hearts. In our crusade, I urge you to: Support your leaders here in the Christian Coalition--Pat Robertson, Don Hodell, Randy Tate--as they fight across this great land on behalf of the American family. As they fight in Washington to rid our tax code of the penalties against marriage and the family. If the Christian Coalition makes repeal of the marriage penalty tax your number one priority, we cannot fail. This is crucial because the success of the family and the success of America are inseparable. I am confident, that with the help of God, we will succeed. And when we do, America will once again be on the path of righteousness. And when we have restored the family, we can re- fortify the walls of this great country with the building blocks of freedom, faith, and virtue. Then, and only then, as we enter the 21st century, will America be that shining city on the hill. Thank you, God bless you and God bless America. Congressman David M. McIntosh, Second District, Indiana Do you pay more in taxes just because you're married? What is the marriage penalty? The IRS punishes millions of married couples who file their income taxes jointly by pushing them into higher tax brackets. The marriage penalty taxes the income of a family's second wage earner--often the wife's salary--at a much higher rate than if that salary were taxed only as an individual. For example, consider a couple whose husband and wife each earn $30,500 for a total household income of $61,000. Subtracting their personal exemptions and standard deductions of $11,800, this couple's taxable income is $49,200. At this income level, the couple is taxed at the 28 percent marginal rate for a total tax bill of $8,563. However, if this couple were divorced or living together but not married, they would get a better tax break from Uncle Sam. For example, with each earning $30,500 and subtracting their individual exemptions and deductions of $6,550 each, their taxable income would be $23,950 each. That means their incomes would each be taxed at the lower 15 percent marginal rate for a tax bill of $3,592 each. So the married couple pays more in taxes just because they're married. That's a marriage penalty of $1,378. Overall, according to a recent report by the Congressional Budget Office, more than 21 million couples suffer a marriage penalty averaging $1,400. ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Marriage Penalty Example Individual Individual Couple ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Adjusted gross income:.......................................... 430,500 430,500 461,000 Minus personal exemption and standard deduction:................ 46,550 46,550 411,800 Taxable income:................................................. 423,950 423,950 449,200 Tax liability:.................................................. 43,592 43,592 48,563 Marriage Penalty:............................................... .............. .............. 41,378 ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Incidentally, there's also a marriage penalty for the personal exemption and standard deduction. In the above example, the exemptions and deductions for an individual total $6,550. Common sense says that for a married couple the exemptions and deductions should be double that of an individual, or $13,100. Unfortunately, common sense doesn't apply to the IRS. The family's personal exemptions and standard deductions total $11,800--that's $1,300 less that what two individuals living together receive. Consequences of marriage penalty? Families today are under assault. Broken homes. Fatherless children. Single moms struggling to raise their children while also ensuring there's food on the table. When Washington taxes couples more just because they're married that hurts working families who are playing by the rules. Rather than helping families stay together, the marriage penalty contributes to the breakdown of the family. What does this breakdown mean for mothers and fathers? Studies show that when parents divorce, they are four times as likely to die at an earlier age,\1\ their health is worse \2\ and sadly many divorced adults, particularly young mothers, are thrown into poverty.\3\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ Joseph E. Schwartz. ``Sociodemographic and Physchosocial Factors in Childhood as Predictors of Adult Mortality.'' American Journal of Public Health 85 (1995):1237-1245. \2\ L. Remez. ``Children who Don't Live with Both Parents Face Behavioral Problems.'' Family Planning Perspectives. (January/February 1992). \3\ Jeanne Woodward. ``Housing America's Children in 1991.'' U.S. Bureau of the Census, Current Housing Reports H121/93-6. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1993. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- The effects on children are also devastating: 72 percent of juvenile murders \4\ and 60 percent of rapists \5\ grew up in broken homes. They are more likely to use drugs, more likely to commit suicide and more likely to drop out of school.\6\ And today 75 percent of children living in single-parent families will experience poverty before they turn 11 years old.\7\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \4\ Dewey Cornell. ``Characteristics of Adolescents Charged with Homicide.'' Behavioral Sciences and the Law 5 (1987):11-23. \5\ Nicholas Davidson. ``Life Without Father.'' Policy Review (1990); see also Karl Zinsmeister. ``Crime is Terrorizing Our Nation's Kids.'' Citizen (August 20, 199): 12. \6\ Wade F. Horn. ``The National Fatherhood Initiative.'' Father Facts II. \7\ National Commission on Children. ``Just the Facts: A Summary of Recent Information on America's Children and Their Families.'' Washington, D.C., 1993. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- What's the solution to the marriage penalty? In September Reps. David McIntosh, R-Ind., and Jerry Weller, R-Ill. introduced H.R. 2456, the ``Marriage Tax Elimination Act of 1997.'' The bill would benefit married couples regardless of whether they have children. Its idea is simple: It allows families to decide how they file their income taxes--either individually or jointly, whichever gives them the greatest tax benefit. Ending the marriage penalty will allow 21 million families to keep more of the money they earn, rather than paying more in taxes to Uncle Sam. In Congress who supports the Marriage Tax Elimination Act? Over 226 House co-sponsors--including Speaker Newt Gingrich, Majority Leader Dick Armey, Majority Whip Tom DeLay, Conference Chairman John Boehner, Conference Vice Chairman Jennifer Dunn and Conference Secretary Deborah Pryce. Who else supports McIntosh's bill? ``Government, by taxing married couples at higher rates than singles, has for too long been a part of the problem. At a time when family breakups are so common, Congress should pass legislation to encourage marriage and ease the burden of families trying to form and stay together. This legislation places government on the side of families.'' The Christian Coalition, Don Hodel, president ``David McIntosh has touched a nerve--his bill to eliminate the marriage penalty will help put an end to Washington's punishment of families. Washington should be supporting families, not undermining them. McIntosh's bill is a bold step in the right direction to make the tax code more family- friendly.'' Americans for Hope, Growth and Opportunity, Steve Forbes, chairman ``American's for Tax Reform supports the efforts of the Sophomore Republican Class in leading the march toward tax relief for working American couples. We support efforts to enact the `Marriage Tax Elimination Act' for America's working couples. We would like to thank David McIntosh in particular for his efforts.'' Americans For Tax Reform, Grover Norquist, president ``Current law forces many married Americans to pay a higher tax bill than if they remained single and had the same combined income. Such a double standard is wholly at odds with the American ideal that taxes should not be a primary consideration in any individual's economic or social choices.'' National Taxpayers Union, Al Cors, director ``We welcome the `Marriage Tax Elimination Act' introduced today by representatives Dave McIntosh and Jerry Weller. This bill can be a first step in recognizing in law that the family is the first church, the first school, the first government, the first hospital, the first economy, and the first and most vital mediating institution in our culture. In order to encourage stable two-parent, marriage-bound households we can no longer support a tax code that penalizes them.'' The Catholic Alliance, Keith Fournier, president ``By eliminating the marriage penalty, Congress will send a strong message to couples across America that the institution of marriage is important and that the government should work to strengthen, not weaken it. With the passage of the `Marriage Tax Elimination Act,' couples and families will no longer be robbed of their hard-earned money, and it will enable them to work towards their own financial independence at retirement.'' Traditional Values Coalition, Rev. Louis P. Sheldon, chairman ``We urge Congress to put the tax code where its rhetoric is and eliminate marriage penalties. Serious steps to reform tax laws would mean real liberation for women, those who work and those who may have to in the future.'' National Independent Women's Forum, Barbara Ledeen, executive director [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.003 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.004 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.005 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.006 Chairman Archer. Mr. Pierce, do you have anything to add to what Ms. Mallory said? Mr. Pierce. No. She said it all. Chairman Archer. We are happy to have you before us. You have graphically pointed out to the Committee the unfairness of this marriage penalty in the Code. I will say for myself that when I came on this Committee in January 1973, coming from the State of Texas, our property laws automatically provide that a spouse that is not working has title to 50 percent of everything the spouse that is working earns. I was offended enormously by the marriage penalty because it totally disregards the property rights that are established by each State. This is a little bit different an issue than the one that Ms. Mallory and Mr. Pierce brought up, but it is another part of the inequity in the marriage penalty. I have fought against it my entire career on this Committee. So I welcome your testimony today. I yield to Mr. Rangel for any inquiry that he might like to make. Mr. Rangel. Mr. Chairman, I pass my time. Chairman Archer. Mr. Thomas. Mr. Thomas. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank all of my colleagues, and especially those who came from Indiana. The old saying, love conquers all, apparently doesn't cover the IRS. Although Mr. Pierce, your willingness to defer to Ms. Mallory indicates that you are ready for marriage. [Laughter.] Even though the IRS won't let you. I just found the opening exchange between the Chairman and the Ranking Member interesting since in the 103d Congress the Chairman of the Ways and Means Committee, Mr. Gibbons, and then in the 104th, the Ranking Member of the Committee, Mr. Gibbons, has long been an advocate for a system different than the current system, and went so far before he retired to actually write a bill to produce just such a different system. I am just a little surprised perhaps that there appears to be a newness to the subject of fundamentally reforming the tax system. Mr. Rangel. Will the gentleman yield? I assume you are referring to me. Mr. Thomas. Very briefly. Mr. Rangel. I am very anxious to see what document is coming out. I have just as much interest as Sam Gibbons or anyone else on this Committee. But we can't just keep educating people. We need a bill before us. Thank you. Mr. Thomas. I thought the road to a bill was education. I guess we're supposed to put the old cart before the horse. Let me say that I'm a cosponsor of legislation dealing with this. I commend all of you for trying to get at the problem, although I believe the Chairman's comment, that as long as we have the current system, it's going to be a continual chase through the system. I don't think this is partisan. I do not think it's a vestigial remain from a previous era. Just let me make one point to illustrate that. We just passed a tax package in the Balanced Budget Act. Because the administration insisted that we limit people's access to the new so-called Roth IRA, we in fact have perpetuated, reinforced and ingrained the marriage penalty in the Tax Code as recently as last year. If you are single, you can deal with an income up to $100,000 and a rollover into the new IRA. But if you are married, that married couple is limited to the $100,000, regardless of their income. It is something that is very difficult to root out, given the way in which the tax structure is created. I commend you for your efforts. We will support your efforts. But I think what we need to do is look fundamentally at repealing those sections that create limits, that produce choices such as we see here before us. There should be no penalty in the Code for marriage. I, for one, think I'm going to introduce legislation to repeal the cap, for example, on the Roth IRA, as my indication that at some point we have to say you can't play games with the numbers. You simply have to eliminate any reason for treating two people who happen to be married differently than two people who do not. So I compliment you. I support your effort. Frankly, what we need to do, and Mr. McIntosh you indicated this creates a little bit of publicity on this issue. There are an awful lot of people who know about it. What we need to do is sensitize our Members to move on it. Thank you very much. Chairman Archer. Ms. Dunn. Ms. Dunn. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I have a couple of questions. One I'll ask you, members of the panel. Have you had the scoring done on your two plans? Could I get the numbers if you have? Mr. Herger. The latest Congressional Budget Office number that I am aware of, Congresswoman Dunn, is about $9 billion a year on my approach, and about $29 billion for complete elimination. Ms. Dunn. Is that over 5 years or is that over 1 year? Mr. Herger. That is per year, based on figures from 1996. Mr. Weller. If I might respond, Ms. Dunn. While the Marriage Tax Elimination Act, which allows a married working couple to choose to file jointly or as two singles has not been officially scored by Joint Tax yet this year, a similar bill in a previous Congress 2 years ago was scored roughly at about $18 billion in revenue loss to the Federal Government. But there is also a different way to say that. That is, that's an $18 billion tax on marriage that should not be being collected today. Ms. Dunn. Thank you very much. I think we need to start with some background. I think this is a superb idea. I think I am on both your pieces of legislation. If I'm not, I certainly ought to be on your legislation because I think the points that were made, particularly by Mr. Weller and Mr. McIntosh about how working women are very concerned about this penalty that they are paying when they are married. It's not fair to them that this money is going to the IRS. We all know that it's not spent as well by the Federal Government as it would be by people who are able to keep this money in their pockets and decide where they want to put this money. Mr. Chairman, my second question is one that I would like to ask you or somebody. I am wondering what the reason was for doing away with this obviously important part of the Tax Code in 1986. Is there justification that we ought to know as we are moving back into this area? Chairman Archer. We'll be happy to have a presentation or a briefing on that for the Members of the Committee. I am reluctant to try to take the time now to explain what I know historically happened. But the marriage penalty has been in the Code beginning back in 1969. It was exacerbated to a degree in 1986, but it's been with us a very long time. It occurred initially because of the political pressure of the singles who came before this Committee and said ``it's cheaper for two people to live together than it is to live separately. Therefore, it is unfair to us to have everybody treated the same.'' That political pressure welled up and caused the Committee and the Congress to insert what we now term the marriage penalty. But that was the genesis of it originally. Ms. Dunn. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I suspect that the number of dollars included must have been very tempting for those people who believed the Federal Government's role should be expanded. These dollars certainly have been going the last few years until just recently to pay for lots of big government programs. I think it's time to turn that around. Mr. Weller. Will the gentlelady yield? You asked the question on the impact on the Federal Government if they lose the revenue that's currently collected with the marriage tax penalty. But if you think about what $1,400 means to a married working couple in Washington State or in Illinois or Indiana or California, $1,400 is 1 year's tuition at Joliet Junior College in my district. It's 3 months of childcare. In fact, I have a chart over here. You know, the President has a politically attractive idea regarding expanding the childcare tax credit. Well, according to the President's own figures, that $360 that an average couple that would qualify for the President's childcare tax credit would be able to purchase 3 weeks of childcare. But with elimination of the marriage tax penalty, that extra $1,400 that the average married working couple would be able to keep as a result of the Marriage Tax Elimination Act would purchase 3 months. So you have 3 weeks versus 3 months of childcare in comparing the two proposals. Ms. Dunn. And also the right of the parents to choose what they want to do in the area of childcare. Thank you very much. Chairman Archer. Let's see who is here at this time. I guess on the list on the Minority side, Mrs. Thurman is. Mrs. Thurman. Mrs. Thurman. Mr. Chairman, I actually don't have any questions at this time. I am looking forward to the debate as we get into this, and certainly any of the offsets. I know that Mr. McIntosh and I have talked about this on the floor. There are several proposals, I understand, that are being looked at in this area. Hopefully as this day goes on, we will have the opportunity to see how this all unfolds. But my heart does go out to folks that are here testifying before us today. It is unfortunate that we have a penalty in taking what many of us think is a wonderful part of our lives, of being married and having that opportunity. So I certainly think there are things that we need to look at. But let's see what happens as we go on. Chairman Archer. Mr. English. Does any other Member of the Committee wish to inquire? If not, thank you very much. Our next panel is scheduled to be three more of our colleagues. I don't know if they are here. Congressman Kasich, Congressman Salmon, and Congressman Riley. If one or more of those colleagues are here, they are invited to come and take a seat at the witness stand. I see Congressman Riley. Congressman Riley, welcome. Congressman Salmon, welcome. If Congressman Kasich shows up, we'll be happy to receive his testimony also. Congressman Salmon, just briefly, the rules of the Committee are that we would like for you to keep your oral testimony within 5 minutes. Without objection, your entire written statement will be inserted in the record. If you are ready, we are happy to have you here. You may proceed. STATEMENT OF HON. MATT SALMON, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF ARIZONA Mr. Salmon. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate the opportunity to testify before the Ways and Means Committee in support of the Riley-Salmon Marriage Protection and Fairness Act. The Taxpayer Relief Act, now law, provided Americans with the first significant tax cut in almost a generation, but our work is not done. Mr. Chairman, as you so aptly pointed out, Americans were taxed at the post-World War II record of 19.9 percent of the Gross Domestic Product last year. Lawmakers from both sides of the aisle have called for the next round of tax cuts, to revise the Tax Code as it pertains to married couples. One of the most indefensible aspects of our current Tax Code is that over 40 percent of married couples pay more in taxes filing jointly than they would if the husband and wife each filed individually. That's a crime. This marriage penalty has been criticized by President Bill Clinton, Speaker Newt Gingrich, and Majority Leader Trent Lott. To ensure that the tax law would not punish married Americans, Representative Jerry Weller and Dave McIntosh introduced a bill, which I have cosponsored, and would eliminate the marriage penalty for some 40 percent for the 40-some odd percent of couples who pay tax filings jointly, pay more taxes filing jointly than they would as unmarried individuals. However, it would upset the principle embedded in our current law, that different families with the same total income should be treated equally for tax purposes. Consequently, it would place most couples in which both spouses work full time in a more favorable tax position than families in which one spouse remains at home or works part time. Jerry Weller and Dave McIntosh have put this issue on the map. For that, we are deeply indebted. Taxpayers owe them a big debt of gratitude. I applaud their leadership on this issue. But income-splitting offers a better fix to this important problem. The Riley-Salmon bill would permit married couples to use income-splitting on their tax returns and would increase the standard deduction for married couples. These changes would offer almost all married couples a tax cut, would eliminate the tax penalty on marriage that exists under current law, and would continue the current policy that different families with the same total income should be treated equally for tax purposes. Senator Lauch Faircloth has introduced virtually the same bill in the Senate, that's S. 1285. Most importantly, the income-splitting legislation we have introduced treats equitably those families in which one parent stays at home. As the New York Post has editorialized, this approach would end the marriage penalty and benefit hard- pressed, one-income married families. Another attractive feature Maggie Gallagher noted in a Washington Times column on the marriage penalty, that income splitting would keep government from taking sides on the mommy wars. Indeed, as the Congress and President contemplate proposals to improve daycare for young children, including the President's proposal to pour billions of dollars into daycare centers, while ignoring parents that raise their kids or have relatives who participate in child rearing, pursuing a marriage penalty fix that does not assist spouses who choose to stay at home or work part time should cause us to pause. Profamily organizations such as the Family Research Council, Eagle Forum, and tax reform groups such as National Taxpayers Union, are aligning behind our approach because it benefits all married couples. Some will undoubtedly criticize our proposal as too difficult to achieve, given budgetary limitations. Indeed, the bill would likely require Washington to run on $30 billion less of tax money from America's families. But the preservation of security of the cornerstone of America, the smallest most important unit of government, the family, is too important to short-change with more economical but less effective proposals. Additionally, Chairman Archer, you recently unveiled a proposal that would cap Federal taxation at 19 percent of Gross Domestic Product, which if enacted, could amount to an annual tax cut of up to $75 billion. A comprehensive marriage penalty fix would represent less than half of this amount. I know that when we talk about the budget and numbers and the fact that this is probably double what the proposal from McIntosh and Weller is offering, I know it makes us a little bit queazy. But who would have ever thought 3 years ago that we would be where we are today in terms of balancing the budget. We are within a stone's throw of doing it. I have a belief that if the American people can get energized about something, and if we representing them get energized about something, all things are possible to he that believes it. Let's go get it done. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Matt Salmon, a Representative in Congress from the State of Arizona I appreciate the opportunity to testify before the Ways and Means Committee in support of the ``Riley-Salmon Marriage Protection and Fairness Act.'' The Taxpayer Relief Act (now law) provided Americans with the first significant tax cut in almost a generation. But our work is not done. As Chairman Bill Archer has pointed out, Americans were taxed at a post World War II record (19.9) percentage of Gross Domestic Product last year. Lawmakers from both sides of the aisle have called for the next round of tax cuts to revise the tax code as it pertains to married couples. One of the most indefensible aspects of our current tax code is that over 40 percent of married couples pay more in taxes filing jointly than they would if husband and wife each filed individually. This ``marriage penalty'' has been criticized by President Bill Clinton, Speaker Newt Gingrich, and Majority Leader Trent Lott. To ensure that tax law would not punish married Americans, Representatives Jerry Weller and Dave McIntosh introduced a bill, which I have cosponsored, that would eliminate the ``marriage penalty'' for the 40 some-odd percent of couples who pay more taxes filing jointly than they would if each spouse filed as an unmarried individual. However, it would upset the principle embedded in current law that different families with the same total income should be treated equally for tax purposes. Consequently, it would place most couples in which both spouses work full time in a more favorable tax position than families in which one spouse remains at home or works part time. Jerry Weller and Dave McIntosh have put this issue on the map. Taxpayers owe them a debt of gratitude, and I applaud their leadership on this issue. But ``income splitting'' offers a better fix to this important problem. The Riley-Salmon bill would permit married couples to use ``income splitting'' on their tax returns, and would increase the standard deduction for married couples. These changes would offer almost all married couples a tax cut, would eliminate the tax penalty on marriage that exists under current law, and would continue the current policy that different families with the same total income should be treated equally for tax purposes. Senator Lauch Faircloth has introduced virtually the same bill in the Senate (S. 1285). Most importantly, the income-splitting legislation we have introduced treats equitably those families in which one parent stays at home. As the New York Post has editorialized, this approach would end the marriage penalty and benefit ``hard- pressed one-income married families.'' Another attractive feature: Maggie Gallagher noted in a Washington Times column on the marriage penalty that income-splitting would keep ``the government from taking sides in the mommy wars.'' Indeed, as the Congress and President contemplate proposals to improve day care for young children--including the President's proposal to pour billions of dollars into day care centers, while ignoring parents that raise their kids or have relatives who participate in child-rearing--pursuing a marriage penalty fix that does not assist spouses who choose to remain at home or work part-time should cause us to pause. Pro-family organizations such as the Family Research Council and Eagle Forum, and tax reform groups such as National Taxpayers Union are aligning behind our approach because it benefits all married couples. Some will undoubtedly criticize our proposal as too difficult to achieve given budgetary limitations. Indeed, the bill would likely require Washington to run on $30 billion less of tax money from America's families. But the preservation and security of the cornerstone of America, the smallest, yet most important unit of government--the family--is too important to shortchange with more economical, but less effective proposals. Additionally, Chairman Archer recently unveiled a proposal that would cap federal taxation at 19 percent of Gross Domestic Product, which if enacted, could amount to an annual tax cut of up to $75 billion. A comprehensive marriage penalty fix would represent less than half of this amount. I look forward to working with the Committee on passing a marriage tax relief bill that benefits all families. Chairman Archer. Thank you for your testimony. Congressman Riley, we would be happy to receive your testimony. Again, your entire written statement, without objection, will be inserted in the record. You are recognized to proceed on your oral testimony. STATEMENT OF HON. BOB RILEY, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF ALABAMA Mr. Riley. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, I want to thank you for holding this important hearing today. I appreciate the opportunity to come and speak before the Committee about the marriage tax penalty. I think that we can all agree that the marriage tax penalty is unfair and is misguided. According to the Joint Tax Committee in 1996, more than 21 million married couples paid a marriage penalty costing more than $28 billion a year. But as simply the average American couple will pay $1,400 more in income taxes simply because they are married. In my opinion, it is difficult to comprehend the devastating effect that the marriage penalty has had on our society. Instead of encouraging and helping families to stay together, our current Tax Code is forcing them apart. Unfortunately, President Clinton's 1993 tax increase made the marriage penalty even more painful for married couples. For example, according to the National Center for Policy Analysis, the marriage penalty for couples earning $50,000 is $1,326 if they have no children. However, if they have two children, the marriage penalty would be $4,348, a penalty of $1,500 per child. Yesterday, I introduced the Marriage Protection and Fairness Act, that will once and for all eliminate this penalty. My proposal is unique because it allows couples to effectively split their combined incomes for tax purposes. That means that taxes for married couples would be figured by adding up the income of both spouses and dividing by two. Each would be taxed on half of their own total income. Furthermore, the bill also increases the basic standard deduction for married couples to twice the standard deduction. This would lower the tax burden for all families and would lower it regardless of how many children they have. Moreover, it would neutralize the tax incentive for two versus one income. Mr. Chairman, there are many good marriage penalty relief proposals before Congress today. Like many of our colleagues, I am a cosponsor of the Weller-McIntosh Marriage Tax Elimination Act. But suppose one spouse earns $30,000 a year, and the family needs more income. If the other spouse takes a paid job, then the couple will benefit from the Weller-McIntosh proposal. But if the first spouse works harder to increase his own earnings by working overtime, by taking a second job, or by getting a promotion, the couple gets no benefit at all. Essentially, this means that two couples with the same family income, would pay a different Federal income tax. The couple where one spouse is a full-time homemaker would pay a higher tax than a couple in which both spouses work. That is why I introduced the Marriage Protection and Fairness Act. I believe that my proposal is the fairest way to eliminate the marriage tax penalty. It is the one that makes the most sense. It will help millions of working couples who are simply trying to make ends meet, and will allow them to keep more of what they earn. Under this proposal, the tax burden would be the same if one spouse earned all the family income, or if both contributed to the family's earnings. It would allow millions of Americans to make a choice on how many breadwinners there should be, without incurring any penalties for that choice. It will also create incentives for families, that will allow one parent to stay at home to take care of and raise their children. Mr. Chairman, we in Congress have a moral obligation to promote the family. If we are serious about giving working American families tax relief, if we are serious about reducing juvenile crime rates and keeping our children off drugs, if we are serious about solving our Nation's many other social problems, then we must promote legislation that promotes the family. I can think of no other more important profamily initiative that we in Congress can initiate than the repeal of the marriage tax. Mr. Chairman, my bill is the same legislation that has been introduced by Senator Faircloth, Senator Hutchinson, and Senator Mack in the other body. Our proposal is not a revolutionary concept. In fact, it was the law until 1969. I urge this Committee to strongly consider the merits of the Marriage Protection and Fairness Act in its efforts to repeal the marriage penalty tax. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.007 Statement of Hon. Bob Riley, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama Mr. Chairman, I want to thank you for holding this important hearing today. I appreciate this opportunity to speak before the Committee about the marriage tax penalty. I think we can all agree that the marriage tax penalty is unfair and misguided. According to the Joint Tax Committee, in 1996, more than 21 million married couples paid a marriage penalty, costing them an extra $28 billion a year in taxes. To put it simply, the average American couple will pay $1,400 more in income taxes simply because they are married. In my opinion, it is difficult to comprehend the devastating effect the marriage penalty has had on our society. Instead of encouraging and helping families to stay together, our current tax code is forcing them apart. Unfortunately, President Clinton's 1993 tax increase made the marriage penalty even more painful for married couples with children. For example, according to the National Center for Policy Analysis, the marriage penalty for couples earning $50,000 is $1,326 if they have no children. However, if they have two children, the marriage penalty would be $4,348--a penalty of $1,511 per child. Yesterday, I introduced the Riley-Faircloth Marriage Protection and Fairness Act that will once and for all eliminate the marriage tax penalty. My proposal is unique because it allows couples to effectively split their combined incomes for tax purposes. That means that taxes for married couples would be figured by adding up the income of both spouses and dividing by two. Each would be taxed on half of the total income. Furthermore, the bill also increases the basic standard deduction for married couples to twice the standard deduction of single filers (totaling $8,300 for 1997). This would lower the tax burden for all families, regardless of how many children they have. Moreover, it would neutralize the tax incentives for two versus one income. Mr. Chairman, there are many good marriage penalty relief proposals before Congress today. And like many of my colleagues, I am a cosponsor of the Weller-McIntosh Marriage Tax Elimination Act. But, suppose one spouse earns $30,000 and the family needs more income. If the other spouse takes a paid job, then the couple will benefit from the Weller-McIntosh proposal. But if the first spouse works harder to increase his own earnings by working overtime, by taking a second job, or by getting a promotion, the couple gets no benefit at all. Essentially, this means that two couples with the same family income would pay a different federal income tax--the couple where one spouse is a full-time homemaker would pay a higher tax than a couple in which both spouses work. That is why I introduced the Marriage Protection and Fairness Act. I believe that my proposal is the fairest way to eliminate the marriage tax penalty, and it is the one that makes the most sense. It will help millions of working couples--who are simply trying to make ends meet--and will allow them to keep more of what they earn. Under this proposal, the tax burden would be the same if one spouse earned all of the family income, or if both contributed to the family's earnings. It will allow millions of American families to make a choice on how many breadwinners there should be, without incurring any penalties for that choice. It will also create incentives for families that will allow one parent to stay at home to take care of and raise their children. Mr. Chairman, we in Congress have a moral obligation to promote the family. If we are serious about giving working American families tax relief, if we are serious about reducing juvenile crime rates and keeping our children off drugs, if we are serious about solving our nation's many other social problems and living up to our obligations, then we must promote legislation that promotes the family. I can think of no more important pro-family initiative that we in Congress can initiate than the repeal of the marriage tax penalty. This debate over the marriage tax penalty is about the survival of the American family. It's about correcting unintended consequences. And if, under my proposal, 1,000, 10,000, or 100,000 American families are able to keep one parent at home to care of the children, then I believe our nation will be better off. I cannot think of a more noble goal. Mr. Chairman, this committee has the opportunity to once again reduce the tax burden on the American people. And like many of our colleagues, your work and the work of this committee is to be commended. As you begin preparing a tax relief package, I urge you to include the Marriage Protection and Fairness Act. The time to pass this legislation is now. Working American families simply cannot wait any longer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.008 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.009 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.010 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.011 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.012 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Riley. You and Congressman Salmon are appearing together. Is there any difference in the proposals that each of you would make or are you basically behind the same proposal? Mr. Salmon. It's the same bill, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Riley. Exactly. Chairman Archer. That's very, very helpful. I must say that your approach is very appealing to me because again, coming from a community property State, the property laws require exactly what you are proposing. Half of each spouse's earnings belong legally to the other spouse. Mr. Riley. Yes, sir. That's exactly. What we can't do, Mr. Chairman, is codify into law something that differentiates between two working couples with the same income. That essentially is what the former proposal does. I want to compliment Congressman Weller for all the work and the attention that he has brought to it, but I think we do need to take it one step further. I think we need to go back and never penalize any spouse for making the decision to stay home and raise their family. Essentially, that's what we do. That is one thing that I don't believe this Congress believes in. I know it's certainly not something that I believe in. Mr. Salmon. You know, Mr. Chairman, every politician just about that's here, when they get up, they talk about family values. I think it would be a real mixed message out of Congress that we would send if we are saying basically you mothers that decide to stay home or work part time so you can spend more time with your children, we are going to penalize you or continue the penalty for doing such. I think it sends the wrong message out of Congress. Some say ``Can we afford to do it?'' I say, ``Can we afford not to do it?'' I think that at a time when the message is and has been for parents to be more involved in their children's education, for parents to be more involved in raising their children, for parents to be more involved to make sure that their kids are off the streets, not causing mischief. When a couple decides the best way for them to address that issue is to have either mom or dad at home, I think it really sends a poor message from Congress that we disagree with you, that doesn't really add value. Chairman Archer. Having said what I did, I also have to be a realist about the amount of revenue that we are going to be able to put into a tax package this year. We certainly will make an effort to move in the direction of ameliorating the negative impact of the marriage penalty. But how far we can go will depend upon how much revenue we will be able to put into the tax bill. Does any other Member wish to inquire? Mr. Shaw. Mr. Shaw. Mr. Chairman, just very briefly I would like to compliment all the witnesses, and this panel particularly, who testified on the marriage penalty tax. It's certainly something that we should take down. We partially took down the barrier to marriage in the welfare reform bill, in which we paid people not to work, not to get married and to have kids. We have to take this last one down in the tax bill. It's absolutely ridiculous that it's this way. To share with you an anecdote that we had in our own office. A young lady who works for me on my staff had a New Years Eve wedding. They waited for their license to be dated on the first of the year in order to avoid a marriage penalty. This is absolutely ridiculous, that we penalize people for being married. I compliment you for your work in this area, and am very hopeful that this will be the top priority of the Ways and Means Committee, to get rid of this unfair tax. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Does anyone else wish to inquire? Mr. Weller. Mr. Weller. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to commend my friends, Mr. Riley and Mr. Salmon, for their interest in this issue. I have enjoyed talking with them and working with them. Of course whatever idea is the best idea, the bottom line is we want to eliminate the marriage tax penalty. A couple questions I have. The Congressional Budget Office study highlighted not only the marriage tax penalty, but they also mentioned the so-called marriage bonus. In studying the CBO study, they pointed out that the single earner family, where one individual, the husband or wife works and the other one might stay at home or is not a wage earner, I was wondering, how does your legislation impact the so-called marriage bonus? Does that marriage bonus still exist or does it eliminate the marriage bonus for a married couple with one source of income? Mr. Riley. Congressman, it essentially does the same thing that your legislation does. It allows them an option to figure their tax liability in any one of three different forms, choose the lowest of the three and that's what they would do. If there is a bonus, I'm not too sure that that is a bad idea. If anything, I wish that we could encourage more spouses to stay home and raise their children. If that is an unintended asset to this bill, then I think it's one that I would encourage. Mr. Weller. Of course I am one who believes the bonus is a good thing. We certainly don't want to jeopardize that. But let me ask this. I was asked this question regarding our legislation. Have you had the legislation scored yet? Do you know the revenue impact? Mr. Riley. No. We haven't. We filed it yesterday. It is being scored. I think as Congressman Salmon said a moment ago, it's going to be more expensive. We know that going in. Probably by $8 to $10 billion. That is no menial figure. But again, when you talk about codifying into law something that discriminates against a homemaker, I do not believe that we can allow that to happen in this country. Even though it may be another $8 or $10 billion, I think it is going to be well worth the price that we pay. Mr. Salmon. If I might address that too. It will be significantly higher on an annual basis than the other one, even though as Congressman Riley mentioned, it hasn't been scored yet. But I would like to go back to what we have seen, Congressman Weller, since we have been in the Congress. The projections on revenues have vastly exceeded what we ever anticipated. There is a possibility in this next budget, we will already see a surplus. I believe that it simply gets down to priorities. If this is our number one priority for the Congress, we can make it happen. We can figure out a way to make it happen and really not have any other aspect of government suffer for it. Mr. Weller. Thank you. I look forward to working with you. I share your goal, the number one must do as we look at this year's budget negotiations when it comes to the tax provision is eliminating the marriage tax penalty. So again, thank you. Mr. Riley. Let both of us compliment you on your leadership on this. We really appreciate it. Mr. Salmon. If it wasn't for you, Congressman Weller, I don't think any of us would be here today. So we must both compliment you. I am a cosponsor of your bill as well. Mr. Riley. So am I. Chairman Archer. Mr. Hayworth. Mr. Hayworth. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have no real question other than just a commendation to my colleagues. Along with my seatmate here, the gentleman from Illinois, I am very pleased to see my colleague from Arizona, from the first district. I think this is intriguing. And one of the newcomers to the House of Representatives, the gentleman from Alabama. Thank you for bringing sound, logical thinking and a good dose of common sense here to the District of Columbia. I think you are both to be commended. This is a very intriguing proposal. We'll continue to study this as we also study the proposal by our colleagues from Illinois and Indiana. I just want to thank you again for your input into this debate and your solution. Chairman Archer. Has the gentleman completed his inquiry. Mr. Hayworth. Yes, sir. I know it's hard to believe. Chairman Archer. Are there any other Members who wish to inquire? If not, thank you very much. I appreciate your input. Our next panel is Michael Graetz, Daniel Feenberg, David Lifson, and Bruce Bartlett. Will you please come to the witness table? If you gentlemen, when recognized, will state where you are employed and what you do for the record, and then proceed into your testimony. And, as I mentioned earlier, we would appreciate it if each of you would keep your oral presentation within 5 minutes, and your entire written statement, without objection, will be inserted in the record. Mr. Graetz, we are delighted to have you back before the Committee. You're no stranger to the Committee over the years, and you go back to when the first marriage penalty was really inserted into the law. So we are really pleased to have you back before the Committee. And, again, if you'll tell the other Members what you are doing now, and whom, if anybody, you represent, we'd be pleased to hear your testimony. STATEMENT OF MICHAEL J. GRAETZ, PROFESSOR OF LAW, YALE LAW SCHOOL, NEW HAVEN, CONNECTICUT Mr. Graetz. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am currently a professor of law at the Yale Law School, and represent only myself, I fear. I thank you for inviting me to testify. The last time I testified before this Committee on this subject was in May 1972 when we were considering the impact of legislation that had been enacted in 1969. Here we are 25 years later on the same topic. I attached to my statement a chapter from my recently published book, ``The Decline (and Fall?) of the Income Tax,'' which I've made available to the Members and to the staff. I can, therefore, just summarize a few of the key points I would like to make. As you know, Mr. Chairman, in 1969 and shortly thereafter, the marriage penalty affected very few people. In 1972, when Treasury testified, it said that only 15 percent of married couples suffered a marriage penalty, while 85 percent received a bonus. In the last 25 years, the scale and scope of the marriage penalty have expanded dramatically. I think today somewhere between one-half and two-thirds of all married couples face a penalty because of some provisions that were omitted from the numbers that you have discussed earlier. There are two causes of this vast expansion: one is the transformation of the Nation's work force and, in particular, the entry of married women into the labor market, as has been discussed earlier. The median income of those families is 40 percent greater than that of families with only 1 earner. Second, while the composition of the Nation's work force was changing so dramatically, Congress after 1969, was adding to the Tax Code a number of new marriage penalties. The earned income tax credit provisions have a very large marriage penalty in them, in some cases the tax can be as high as one-fourth of a combined couple's income. The 1993 changes requested by President Clinton and accepted by Congress added whopping marriage penalties at the top of the income scale and for Social Security recipients. These new tax penalties on marriage, in my opinion, Mr. Chairman, have resulted from efforts by Congress to fit tax measures into straightjackets imposed by budgetary revenue constraints coupled with the desire to make distributional tables come out right. The fact that Congress now routinely enacts sizeable penalties on marriage for the sole purpose of conforming to distribution tables demonstrates the dangers of subordinating important tax and public policy goals to such constraints. Second, because marriage penalties have been introduced to the Code through specific provisions as well as in the tax rates schedules, finding a solution to this problem is going to be extremely difficult. There are two general approaches before the Committee today, as you have heard, neither one of which, in my view, is entirely satisfactory. The first is to try and focus on specific tax penalties and to root them out wherever they appear; allowing deductions or credits for a portion of wages of the low-earning spouses, for example, would be such an approach. It would not affect, for example, Social Security recipients. And it's not clear to me why tax penalties for marriage are more important for citizens at one part of the income scale rather than at the other, or for workers rather than retirees. The second approach, exemplified by Congressman Weller's bill and some others is to allow a married couple to file tax returns as if they were unmarried. As you pointed out, Mr. Chairman, this reintroduces distinctions between community property and common-law States and creates incentives to shift the ownership of assets. I think ultimately you have to base such an approach on the aggregate income of the couple in order to make it work. In my book, I suggest that the marriage penalty is one of the major reasons the American public is now so dissatisfied with the income tax. It is one reason to take seriously restructuring of the tax system. To be sure, we've seen today people who have not married, and we know there are couples who have divorced because of this tax penalty on marriage. It is routine for couples to hold marriages in January rather than in December and put their families and friends to a bizarre inconvenience. No one would design a tax system that penalized marriage. No broad reform of the tax system before the Congress should retain any tax penalty on marriage. The marriage penalty should be removed from our system, but I am, frankly, Mr. Chairman, skeptical about whether that can be done while retaining the current income tax in place. When a tax system departs fundamentally from the values of the people it taxes, it cannot sustain public support. When people lose respect for a tax law, they will not obey it. Arbitrary and unfair tax distinctions of this sort instill disdain for the law and disrespect for those who write and enforce it. Let me just end with this quote from an exchange between Senator Robert Dole--I report this in my book--and between a couple, Angela and David Boyter, in a Senate Finance Committee hearing in 1980 on this subject. Senator Dole says, ``You are divorced now?'' Mr. Boyter: ``We are divorced now and have been for several years.'' Senator Dole: ``You live together though.'' Mr. Boyter: ``That is right. The IRS told us that that was preferable to getting remarried every year and then divorced.'' Mrs. Boyter: ``My mother did not think so, but the IRS did.'' Now is the time to conform the tax system to the values of America's mothers. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement and attachment follow:] Statement of Michael J. Graetz, Professor of Law, Yale Law School, New Haven, Connecticut Mr. Chairman, and members of the Committee-- Thank you for inviting me to testify on this important issue. I first sat at this table at a hearing on this subject more than twenty five years ago in May, 1972, when I was serving at the Treasury Department. My views on this issue are set forth in Chapter Two of my recently published book, The Decline (and Fall?) of the Income Tax, which I have attached to this statement. That chapter also reviews the history of the taxation of married and single persons under the income tax. Its history makes clear that this issue is no simple or straightforward matter. In this brief statement, I shall merely emphasize a few major points: 1. From the inception of the income tax in 1913 until 1969, there was no tax penalty for marriage. The marriage penalty originated in 1969 as a by-product of a well-intentioned Congressional effort to improve income tax equity for single people. In 1972, the Treasury Department testified that fewer than 15% of married couples faced any marriage penalty, while more than 85% of married couples enjoyed a tax reduction by filing joint returns. At that time, the marriage penalty affected only this relatively small number of upper-middle- income couples. It had virtually no impact at the bottom or top of the income scale. In the past twenty five years, both the scale and scope of income tax penalties on marriage have grown dramatically so that today, somewhere between one half and two thirds of all married couples pay greater income taxes solely because they are married. 2. There are two causes of this great expansion of income tax marriage penalties. The first is the transformation of the nation's workforce, in particular, the entry of married women into the labor market. Today, nearly three quarters of married women under age 55 are in the labor force. The median income of these families is 40% greater than families with only one wage earner. Second, while the composition of America's labor force was changing so dramatically, Congress was adding to the tax code a variety of new marriage penalties. By so doing, incentives for divorce or for remaining unmarried were created for wide segments of the population that previously had been unaffected. The earned income tax credit provisions, which first came into the Internal Revenue Code in the mid-1970s and have been greatly expanded since, frequently impose a very large marriage penalty on low income workers. In some cases, the additional tax can be as much as one fourth of two low income workers' combined incomes. The 1993 changes in the tax rate schedule requested by President Clinton and accepted by Congress, added whopping marriage penalties for high-income taxpayers, in some cases as much as $15,000 of additional taxes a year. Income tax penalties on marriage now appear throughout the tax code, in the provisions taxing Social Security, for example, and in provisions such as last year's tax legislation's phase-outs of certian new benefits for families with children, and for education or retirement savings. These recent new tax penalties on marriage have resulted from efforts by Congress to fit tax measures into a straightjacket imposed by budgetary revenue constraints coupled with a desire to make the distributional tables ``look right.'' The fact that Congress now routinely enacts sizable penalties on marriage for the sole purpose of conforming to a specific combination of revenue and distributional targets demonstrates the dangers of subordinating important tax and public policy goals to such constraints. 3. Because marriage tax penalties have entered the code in recent years both through the tax rate schedule and through new penalties being added here and there within specific provisions, finding a clean and complete solution to this problem is not easy. There are two general approaches--both of which are represented in bills before this committee today-- neither one of which is entirely satisfactory. The first line of attack is to focus on specific marriage tax penalties and try to root them out whenever they seem important. This, of course, requires establishing priorities, which are inevitably controversial. For example, allowing a deduction for a portion of the wages of the lower-earning spouse, as was in the law prior to 1986 and has been re- proposed here today, reduces marriage penalties for taxpayers who can use the deduction, but does nothing to alleviate marriage penalties, for example, due to the workings of the earned income tax credit or the way Social Security benefits are taxed. It is not clear to me, why tax barriers to marriage are more important for higher-income citizens than for lower- income citizens or even for workers rather than retirees. The second approach--exemplified by Congressman Weller's bill--is to allow a married couple to file tax returns as if they were unmarried. This is an expensive and potentially complex solution. It also reintroduces distinctions between married couples who live in community property states and common law states--a distinction which has long plagued the income tax--and creates opportunities for tax savings by shifting the ownership of investment assets within a family. I am inclined to think that if a general solution to this problem is to be attempted in the current income tax, it should be based on the aggregate income of the married couple, not on their individual incomes. For example, a married couple might be allowed to fill out their joint return, but to treat half of the income as earned by each spouse and file as single persons. This would avoid some of the potential problems of Congressman Weller's approach, but would also represent a comprehensive attack on the income tax penalties on marriage. I doubt if this alternative would be significantly less costly in terms of revenues than Congressman Weller's bill. The approach I have just described also would not solve the problem, which has been emphasized by some analysts, of taxing a married woman who enters the labor force at a marginal income tax rate that depends on her spouse's income. In other words, while this kind of approach could eliminate tax penalties solely due to marriage, it would not eliminate certain tax disincentives for married women to work. This does not trouble me, because I regard the marriage tax problem as a problem of an income tax system endorsing and incorporating the wrong values; I am far less concerned with its behavioral effects. 4. In my book, I suggest that the marriage tax penalty is one of the major reasons the American people have become so dissatisfied with the income tax, one of several reasons to take seriously the task of restructuring the nation's tax system. This penalty, to be sure, has induced some people to remain single who otherwise might have married, or to divorce, and no doubt has induced many more couples who do marry to postpone their weddings from December to January to save at least one year's marriage penalty. They and their families and friends all rightly hold Congress responsible for such an absurdity. No one would design a tax system in a way that penalized marriage. No broad reform of the tax system recently introduced in the Congress--whether a restructuring of the income tax as Congressman Gephardt has proposed, or elimination of the income tax in favor of some form of consumption tax as others have proposed--should retain any tax penalty on marriage. The marriage penalty must be removed from our tax system. I am, however, somewhat skeptical about whether that can be done while retaining in place the current income tax with its many complexities and barnacles. When a tax system departs dramatically from the fundamental values of the people it taxes, it cannot sustain public support. When people lose respect for a law, they will not obey it. Arbitrary and unfair tax distinctions--such as those based on marital status--instill disdain for the law and disrespect for those who write and enforce it. The voluntary compliance of private citizens which is essential to enforce any tax statute will diminish. Consider this quote from an exchange reported in my book between Angela and David Boyter and Senator Robert Dole at an August, 1980 hearing of the Senate Finance Committee on this subject: Senator Dole: ``You are divorced now?'' Mr. Boyter: ``We are divorced now and have been for several years.'' Senator Dole: ``You live together, though?'' Mr. Boyter: ``That is right. The IRS told us that that was preferable to getting remarried every year and divorced.'' Mrs. Boyter: ``My mother did not think so, but the IRS did.'' I applaud the Chairman for calling these hearings to demonstrate that Congress has now become serious about responding to the changes in society, in the economy, and in the tax law, that have occurred since the marriage penalty was first introduced in 1969. The absence of a perfect, or even fully satisfactory resolution to this difficult problem should not become an excuse for not acting. The public is properly not indifferent about whether the nation's income tax law encourages marriage or divorce. I hope that this Committee will soon begin to bring the tax system into greater conformity with the values of America's mothers. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.013 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.014 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.015 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.016 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.017 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.018 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.019 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.020 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.021 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.022 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.023 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.024 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.025 Chairman Archer. Mr. Feenberg. STATEMENT OF DANIEL FEENBERG, RESEARCH ASSOCIATE, NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH, CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS Mr. Feenberg. I work at the National Bureau of Economic Research in Cambridge, Massachusetts. I represent only myself. Marriage penalties can be quite significant. For working couples with modest income, penalties of $1,000 or $2,000 are typical. For successful professionals, the increase can be $10,000 or $20,000. More significantly, for two working-poor parents near the EIC maximum, the penalty could be several thousand dollars. While the available statistical evidence does not support a large effective marriage tax on marriage and divorce rates, the situation is morally troubling, to say the least. Economic analysis of the marriage penalty usually centers on other aspects. First the system may be thought to be unfair because it imposes the same tax burden on married couples with two earners as it does on a one-earner couple with the same income, even though the latter is better off by the value of the additional untaxed home-produced services. This is an important argument because it justifies different tax liabilities for families according to the within-family distribution of income. If this argument is accepted, it is again possible to reduce or eliminate the marriage tax without giving up graduated rates. The second concern that economists generally have is that married women are typically thought to be quite responsive to changes in the aftertax wage rate. This makes it particularly inefficient to tax married women at their husband's marginal rate. In 1995, Martin Feldstein and I analyzed a number of tax reform proposals, including a revival of the second-earner's deduction which allowed the secondary earner to deduct 10 percent of her earnings up to $30,000 from total income. For married women with earnings below $30,000, this represents a 10-percent reduction in the marginal tax rate. With no change in labor supply, we found a cost of $7.2 billion at 1994 levels, but we estimated a net $5.7 billion increase in wage earnings. This would reduce the cost in the individual income tax side of the budget by $1.1 billion. In addition, the increased earnings also increase the payroll taxes by about $0.9 billion, bringing the net loss to $5.2 billion. In this case, the static revenue estimate overstates the actual loss by 38 percent. So the revenue argument against the deduction is substantially moderated by the consideration of behavioral effects. We also simulated the law with a cap set at $50,000 rather than $30,000. This is a better match to the 1981 law after an allowance for inflation. The surprising feature of this analysis is that the more generous plan dominates the original. More specifically, the higher deduction limit raises the static revenue loss by about $700 million, but induces an additional $1.7 billion in earnings. While the personal income tax still falls by $200 million, this is offset by greater payroll tax revenues. At the price, the secondary earner's deduction is an especially attractive plan because it reduces marriage penalties by about a third or more without much increasing marriage bonuses and with very little complication to the tax form. I note that the secondary earner's deduction has no phaseout range, and I applaud that. A phaseout of the benefit would just aggravate the marriage tax at some higher income level. H.R. 2456 creates a new filing status called a combined return similar to optional separate filing but with deductions apportioned by formula and using the schedule for single taxpayers. My personal view is that combined return of the form contemplated is highly problematic from the tax administration complexity perspective. The plan adds at least 40 boxes to the form 1040 and doubles the number of supporting schedules that couples with separate property would have to attach. Even taxpayers not benefiting from the new provisions might spend substantial time confirming that disappointing fact, and few will understand the justice for their disappointment. We did simulate a number of plans which allowed the secondary earner to file a separate return for wage income only and with all deductions and exemptions on the couple's primary return. While quite costly, these plans did well on a deadweight loss per dollar of revenue basis and would be worth considering. With only one form of income separately taxed, the additional lines on the form are few and the additional complexity is minimized. There are a number of provisions in the law, including the earned income tax credit, the phaseout of personal exemptions, limitations on itemized deductions, and the thresholds for taxation of Social Security that aggravate the marriage tax. The apparent rationale for these phaseouts is that not only should the Tax Code be progressive overall, but that each provision of the Tax Code should be progressive on its own. This is not attractive logically. Progressivity should be a feature of the entire Tax Code, and not of the individual paragraphs of the Tax Code. Perhaps we could have fewer of these carbuncles on the Code if, like the British, we called them clawbacks instead of phaseouts. Finally, separate filing provides a dramatic example of the role that graduated rates play in generating tax complexity. It is often alleged that taxes need not be flat to be simple since the effort of looking up the tax liability in the table is independent of the number of brackets that were used to create the table. But those 40 additional boxes on the 1040 that would be required by the combined return are due to the fact that with graduated rates the amount of tax depends upon exactly who has earned the income. It is the individual's specific marginal tax rate that means the tax cannot be simple unless it is also flat. My last remark would be to point out that neither of the proposed bills do anything to ameliorate the marriage tax generated by the EIC phaseouts. This is very unfortunate because it is at these lowest income levels that the tax is the greatest in proportion to income and where the effects on marital status might be expected. Thank you for your attention. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Daniel Feenberg, Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts With graduated rates, higher income taxpayers pay a greater percentage of their income in taxes. But there is no obviously correct way to compare individuals and couples. The individual with 50K of annual income pays a higher average tax rate than the individual with 25K of income. But what rate should the couple with 50K of income pay? Are they like the individual with the same income, and should they pay the higher rate? Or like two single taxpayers each with half that of income, and be subject to a lower average rate set for the less well off? Does it matter if both are working at a low wage, or just one at a high wage? And should couples with the same income pay the same tax, anyway? It isn't a question that can be answered scientifically by investigation into whether two can live as cheaply as one. As you know, single and married people face different tax schedules under current law, with the tax liability of married individuals based on the couple's joint income. Consequently, tax burdens change with marital status, although whether up or down depends upon the closeness of the incomes of the spouses. The more equal the incomes, the greater the tendency for tax liabilities to increase upon marriage. The marriage penalty is no mere technical problem, and marriage non-neutrality is inevitable in a tax system with income splitting and graduate rates. From 1982 to 1986 the law departed from pure income splitting by the introduction of the secondary earner's deduction. That substantially ameliorated the marriage penalty but was dropped when TRA87 provided an even greater relief from the marriage penalties through lower marginal rates. Recent increases in statutory marginal rates have aggravated the marriage penalty again, as has the introduction of taxable social security benefits. The 1997 Taxpayer Relief Act includes a child credit which adds a potential marriage tax of $500 per child to those couples where both husband and wife earn between $65,000 and $75,000. Their income together puts them above the phaseout range for a couple, but apart they would receive the full benefit. Under current law the magnitude of the marriage penalty can be quite significant. For working couples with modest incomes, penalties of one or two thousand dollars are typical. For two very successful professionals, the increase could be ten or twenty thousand dollars. More significantly, for two working poor parents near the EIC maximum, the penalty could be several thousand dollars, perhaps 15% of income. Of course a similar number of couples receive a marriage bonus. It may hard to reduce the tax without increasing the bonus, or we may consider the bonus to be desirable. While the available statistical evidence does not support a large effect of marriage taxes on marriage and divorce rates, the situation is morally troubling, to say the least. Economic analysis of the marriage penalty usually centers on other aspects. First, the system may be thought to be unfair because it imposes the same tax burden on a married couple with two earners as it does on a one earner couple with the same income, even though the later is better off by the value of the additional untaxed home produced services. This is an important argument, because it justifies different tax liabilities for families according to the within family distribution of earnings. If this argument is accepted, it is again possible to reduce or eliminate the marriage tax without giving up graduated rates. The second concern is that while the labor supply response of married men to the after-tax wage is still controversial, most economists in both parties believe that women are quite responsive to changes in the after-tax wage rate. This makes it particularly inefficient to tax married women at their husband's marginal rate. In fact, currently the typical married woman's marginal rate is even higher than her husband's rate, once social security tax and benefit rules are accounted for. Reducing the marginal rate faced by the more elastic earner will improve efficiency. In 1995 Martin Feldstein \1\ and I analyzed a number of tax reform proposals including a revival of the secondary earner's deduction. This was a feature of the tax law from 1982 to 1986, and as with HR 2593, it allowed the secondary earner to deduct 10% of her earnings from total income. For married women with earning below $30,000 this represents a 10% reduction in the marginal tax rate. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ Feldstein, Martin, and Daniel Feenberg, ``The Taxation of Two- Earner Families'' in Martin Feldstein and James Poterba, editors, Empirical Foundations of Household Taxation, University of Chicago Press, 1996. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- In our analysis we forecast the revenue effect after accounting for the change in labor supply induced by the higher after tax wage rate and lower tax liability. We take the elasticity of hours with respect to the net of tax share to be .45. With no change in labor supply, we found a cost of 7.2 billion dollars at 1994 levels. But we estimated a net 5.7 billion dollar increase in wage earnings. This would reduce the cost on the individual income tax side of the budget by 1.1 billion to 6.1. In addition, the increased earnings also increase the payroll taxes that these women and their employers pay by about .9 billion, bringing the net loss to 5.2 billion. In this case the static revenue estimate overstates the loss by 38 percent. So the revenue argument against the deduction is substantially moderated by the consideration of behavioral effects. We also simulated the law with a cap set at $50,000 rather than $30,000. That is a better match to the 1981 law after an inflation correction. The surprising feature of this analysis is that the more generous plan dominates the original. This occurs because the $30,000 cap provides no favorable effect on the incentives of secondary earners with initial earnings above $30,000, while nevertheless reducing the tax that they pay. More specifically, the higher deduction limit raises the static revenue loss by approximately $700 million, but induces an additional $1.7 billion in earnings. Although the personal income tax still falls by $200 million, this is offset by greater payroll tax revenues. At the price, the secondary earner's deduction is an especially attractive plan because it reduces the marry about a third or more, without much increasing marriage bonuses, and with very little complication to the tax form. I note that the secondary earner's deduction has no phaseout range, and I applaud that. A phaseout of the benefit would just aggravate the marriage tax at some higher income level. HR 2456 creates a new filing status called a ``combined return'', similar to optional separate filing but with deductions apportioned by formula and using the schedule for single taxpayers. We did not do an analysis for any form of optional separate filing, perhaps because the revenue cost seemed too great at the time, but I would expect that the importance of accounting for behavioral effects would be as or more important than for a secondary earner's deduction. Anyone doing such an estimate for separate filing must face the problem that even if one knew the current distribution of property within the family, that distribution might be affected by tax-avoidance measures induced by the availability of the new filing status. With no simulations, I have no quantitative evaluation of HR 2456. My personal view is that a combined return of the form contemplated by HR 2456 is highly problematic from the tax administration and complexity perspective. The plan adds at least 40 boxes to the Form 1040, and doubles the number of supporting schedules that couples with separate property would have to attach. Even taxpayers not benefiting from the new provisions might spend substantial time confirming that disappointing fact, and few will understand the justice of that disappointment. We did simulate a number of plans which allowed for the secondary earner to file a separate return for wage income only, with all deductions and exemptions on the couples primary return. While quite costly, these plans did well on a``deadweight loss per dollar of foregone revenue'' basis and would be worth considering. With only one form of income separately taxed, the additional lines are few, and the additional complexity minimized. Finally, separate filing provides a dramatic example of the role that graduated rates play in generating tax complexity. It is often alleged that taxes need not be flat to be simple, since the effort of looking up the tax liability in the tax table is independent of the number of brackets. But those 40 additional boxes on the 1040 would be required under separate taxation with graduated rates because the amount of tax would depend upon exactly whose income is whose. Neither HR 2456 nor HR 2593 do anything to ameliorate the marriage tax generated by the EIC phaseouts. This is unfortunate because it is at the lowest income levels that the tax is the greatest proportion of income and where effects on marital status might be expected. Thank you for your attention. Daniel Feenberg is Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA. The views expressed here are those of the author, and not of any institution. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Feenberg. Our next witness is David Lifson. Mr. Lifson, you may proceed. STATEMENT OF DAVID LIFSON, VICE CHAIR, TAX EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE, AMERICAN INSTITUTE OF CERTIFIED PUBLIC ACCOUNTANTS Mr. Lifson. Mr. Chairman, and Members of this distinguished Committee: I am David Lifson, vice chair of the Tax Executive Committee at the American Institute of CPAs--the national professional organization of CPAs with more than 330,000 members. Many of our members are tax practitioners who, collectively, prepare income tax returns for millions of Americans. We appreciate this opportunity to testify today on the marriage penalty. The AICPA urges that the tax system be modified to eliminate or reduce the marriage penalty. The tax system should be marriage neutral. Both simplification and equity must also be considered. This issue involves tax, social, and economic policy decisions that must be coordinated to maximize the benefit of any change. We want to help and we can be very helpful. Your background studies confirm that under the current tax system, a marriage penalty, or a marriage bonus, exists. The bonus is intentional often, and is the result of prior tax policy. The penalty is often unintentional. There are currently at least 63 provisions in the Internal Revenue Code where tax liability depends on whether a taxpayer is married or single. In 1996, when the GAO released their report on this topic, there were only 59 reasons. Then, there were 59 reasons to leave your spouse. Now, with the 1997 tax act, there are 63 reasons, representing nearly a 7-percent increase in only 1 year. [Laughter.] The marriage penalty results from two root causes: stacking of joint income against progressive tax rates, and phaseouts of credits, deductions, and exemptions often designed to prevent abuses or to produce targeted benefits. We recommend that at a minimum Congress should consider adopting standard phaseouts for three income levels--low-income, middle-income, and high- income taxpayers--rather than the 20 current levels; and adopt one standard phaseout method for all. Note that the phaseout ranges would eliminate many of the 63 penalties since the joint amounts would be twice the single ranges, and the phaseout ranges applicable to married-filing-separate taxpayers would be the same as those for single taxpayers. We have provided you a table to study our proposal further. In one careful step, you could go a long way to attack two of the most talked about issues today in taxes: complexity, and the marriage penalty. In addition, there are related tax problems that arise because of marriage and joint liability. We urge this Committee to give these matters their due consideration. For example, the innocent spouse rules need modifications, as do the treatment of carryover tax attributes, and NOL computations in the 50 percent of our marriages that end in divorce. Further, we suggest that Congress provide for allocated liability instead of joint and several liability on joint tax returns. And perhaps most importantly, further consideration of separate returns or separate liability calculations must be considered as an option. Again, we have provided you with background material in this area. It's with our materials. The AICPA has been studying this area, including H.R. 2593 providing a limited two-earner deduction, and H.R. 2456 allowing limited combined returns. These and other bills included in the discussions today need to go further and need to be coordinated into a single rational improvement. You should consider all possible approaches--provide for the separate calculations; provide for something like a two- earner deduction; provide a tax credit; adjust or broaden the current rate bracket schedules so that there is less marriage penalty; or, as I said earlier, you can adopt a standard phaseout for the three income levels, eliminating many of the 63 marriage penalties. In conclusion, the AICPA urges that the tax system be modified to eliminate or reduce the marriage penalty or bonus. We have discussed a number of possible approaches to address this problem. However, each of these provisions needs to be thoroughly analyzed in order to provide the intended economic, tax, and social benefits. Standard phaseouts could go a long way. All alternatives should be considered. American families, American workers, and all American taxpayers deserve everyone's careful analysis and consideration. The AICPA thanks you for listening. [The prepared statement and attachments follow. Appendices are being retained in the Committee files.] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.026 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.027 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.028 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.029 Chairman Archer. Thank you for your testimony and your input. Mr. Bartlett. We'd be happy to have your testimony. STATEMENT OF BRUCE R. BARTLETT, SENIOR FELLOW, NATIONAL CENTER FOR POLICY ANALYSIS Mr. Bartlett. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I'm a senior fellow with the National Center for Policy Analysis, which is a think tank based in Dallas, Texas. First, I would like to say that I associate myself completely with all the statements previously made. I agree with everything that the other three witnesses have said, and in particular, I think that Mr. Graetz is right to point to the pernicious effect of the domination of income distribution tables in the tax policy process, because that's what has given us all these crazy phaseouts that are so well detailed in the previous testimony. What I would like to concentrate on is the notion that anything short of fundamental tax reform is very unlikely to completely get rid of the marriage penalty. I support all of the legislation that has been offered, and I think that in the end it will probably be revenue constraints that determine how much or how little is ultimately able to be done in terms of the marriage penalty. I would just hope that whatever approach to alleviating the marriage penalty that Congress adopts be done with some vision of tax reform in mind. Personally, I think the flat tax is the best way that we should go, but going to a consumption tax, such as a national retail sales tax, would also get rid of the marriage penalty. I think that either of these approaches ought to be in the mind of the Congress as they adopt incremental changes to the Tax Code, whether it be in terms of the marriage penalty or in other legislation. I would like to call attention to the discussion in the Joint Committee's pamphlet, which points out, quite correctly, that the Congress cannot simultaneously do three things. You cannot have progressive tax rates, you cannot have equal treatment of couples with equal incomes and be marriage neutral. Historically, the Congress has accepted the first premise--the first principle--and the second principle, and abandoned the third. And we are now here to try to redress this problem. But, anything we do to redress the marriage penalty in terms of the legislation that is under discussion is going to violate the second principle. You are going to have a situation in which married couples with the same gross income are going to be paying quite different taxes depending solely on how that income is earned; whether it's earned by a single earner or two earners, and what is the split of income between those two, because the marriage penalty is exacerbated, or it's worst, when a married couple each have approximately equal income. So, I think that you need to be aware that you may be leaving one minefield for another, and that we'll be back here in a couple of years to try to fix another problem. And, as you know very well, Mr. Chairman, this whole problem came about because in 1969 the single earners were all complaining that they were overtaxed relative to married couples, and you changed the tax brackets to alleviate that problem and created another one. So, I would emphasize the need to go to fundamental tax reform. And, as the Joint Committee's pamphlet correctly points out, a pure flat rate tax system does eliminate the marriage penalty; and also having a consumption tax would do the same thing. But that would require abandoning the first principle, which is the principle of progressivity in our tax system. I agree with Professor Feenberg that you don't necessarily have to have progressive rate structure to have a progressive tax system. You can do a lot of things with the personal exemption, with things like the earned-income tax credit to achieve pretty much any degree of progressivity you wish to have in the overall tax system without the necessity of having progressive tax rates. And, I believe that there is now a growing consensus, at least among economists, and among some tax theorists as well, that maybe progressivity of the rate structure is not necessarily something that we ought to accept without question. Of course, the other approach you can take is to simply abandon the family as the fundamental tax unit and go to a pure individual filing system such as we had before 1948. There is a growing agreement, I think, among many tax theorists who are cited in my testimony to this regard as well. Certainly going to something like the choice system in the Weller-McIntosh bill moves us a long way in that direction, but it might be worth at least considering the possibility of going to a mandatory individual filing system. I'll just stop there and take your questions. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Bruce R. Bartlett, Senior Fellow, National Center for Policy Analysis A marriage penalty results when a married couple pay more taxes by filing jointly than they would pay if each spouse could file as a single. Marriage penalties only result when both spouses have earned income. Single earner couples never pay a penalty and in fact always get a bonus from the Tax Code. A marriage bonus results when a couple pay less taxes than they would pay as singles. The marriage penalty fundamentally results from progressivity of the Tax Code.\1\ Marginal income tax rates rise from 15 percent to 39.6 percent. This causes a marriage penalty because the earnings of the secondary worker (the lower paid spouse) in effect come on top of the primary earner's. Thus, a secondary worker may find his or her income taxed at a marginal rate higher than they would pay if taxed as a single. To see how this works, consider a husband with taxable income of $25,000 per year. Under both the single and joint tax schedules he would pay 15 percent tax on that income. If his wife also makes $25,000, however, only the first $17,350 of her income would be taxed at 15 percent. The remaining $7,650 of her income will be taxed at 28 percent, because it puts the couple's total income above the $42,350 ceiling for the 15 percent bracket. Thus she will pay 13 percent more tax on that income (the difference between 15 percent and 28 percent) than she would pay if she were taxed as a single. In this case, that would make the marriage penalty $994 per year. On the same total income, a couple may either get a tax bonus or pay a tax penalty depending on what the income split is between husband and wife. The couple in the earlier example paid the maximum marriage penalty on their $50,000 joint income because each spouse earned half the income. However, if one spouse earned substantially less than the other, the marriage penalty would have become a marriage bonus. If the husband earned $40,000 per year while the wife earned $10,000, instead of paying a penalty of $994 per year, they would have received a bonus of $910. That is, they would pay $910 less in taxes as a couple filing jointly than they would pay if each were taxed as a single. The marriage penalty is most likely to strike couples whose incomes are roughly equal. No couple with equal incomes or those within 10 percent of each other receive a marriage bonus and most receive penalties. As noted earlier, no single earner couples pay a marriage penalty and virtually all, regardless of income, receive a bonus. To get an idea of how marriage penalties and bonuses affect real people, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) looked at Internal Revenue Service and Census data. The CBO found that the highest proportion of marriage penalties occurred when the higher earning spouse made between $20,000 and $75,000 per year. Couples with incomes above and below these levels were more likely to receive a tax bonus for being married. Thus we see that marriage penalties are most likely to impact on couples with middle incomes whose incomes are roughly equal. In an interesting article, Professor Dorothy Brown of the University of Cincinnati College of Law has argued that these two factors mean that blacks are more likely to suffer a marriage penalty, while whites are more likely to receive a marriage bonus from the Tax Code.\2\ The reason is because among married couples, black women are more likely to work than white women. Furthermore, working black women on average provide a higher percentage of the couple's total income than working white women. According to a 1990 study by the U.S. Commission on Civil Rights, 75 percent of black women work full-time, whereas only 62 percent of white women do. And working black women contribute 40 percent family earnings, while working white women contribute just 29 percent.\3\ Although the marriage penalty is inherent in the nature of progressive tax rates, its magnitude has gone up and down with changes in the tax law. When the income tax was established in 1913, there was no distinction between married and unmarried taxpayers. There was a single rate schedule that applied to both. The tax problems related to working women were much less in those days because only a small number of married women worked outside the home. In the census of 1900, there were only 769,000 married women in the labor force, out of a total of 27,640,000 workers. Even single women were unlikely to hold a paying job at that time. The female labor force participation rate was just 20 percent in 1900, compared to 86 percent for men.\4\ In the 1920s, however, a number of couples in community property states began filing separate tax returns, with each spouse claiming half the couple's total income.\5\ This was justified on the grounds that under community property each spouse is deemed to own half the couple's joint earnings, regardless of who earned them. By contrast, in common law states, the earnings of a spouse generally belonged to that spouse. Among the states with community property laws at that time were Texas, Arizona, Idaho, Louisiana, Nevada, New Mexico, Washington and California. Initially, the Attorney General of the United States ruled that couples in community property states could split their income for tax purposes. This had the effect of reducing taxes for most couples. For example, if a husband had $20,000 of earnings and his wife had none, they would be taxed as if each earned $10,000. This generally put them in a lower tax bracket and lowered their joint tax liability. Had this state of affairs been allowed to continue, it would have led states to adopt community property laws just to give their citizens a cut in their federal income taxes. Congress and the Treasury Department attempted to thwart the use of income splitting through legislation and regulations. Eventually, a case reached the Supreme Court on the question of income splitting. In Poe v. Seaborn (1930), the Court ruled that state community property laws did allow couples to split their incomes for federal income tax purposes. And as expected, it did indeed lead several states to change from common law to community property in order to give their citizens a tax cut at no expense to the state. This trend accelerated when tax rates shot up during World War II. By 1948, Oregon, Nebraska, Michigan and Oklahoma had changed their laws to become community property states.\6\ Obviously, this situation led to a great deal of unfairness, with citizens of some states paying significantly lower federal income taxes than citizens of other states with the same income. The magnitude of the marriage penalty for couples in common law states in 1947 was quite high. Some couples in common law states were paying 40 percent more in federal income taxes than they would have paid in a community property state. A couple with a joint income of $25,000, for example, would have paid $9,082 in federal income taxes in a common law state, but only $6,460 in a community property state.\7\ As Professor Michael Graetz of Yale recently noted, ``this absurd situation did not engender great respect for the integrity of the income tax.'' \8\ Congress finally resolved this problem in the Revenue Act of 1948, which extended the principle of income splitting to all married couples.\9\ This constituted a significant tax cut for most married couples. The bulk of the benefits accrued to couples with middle incomes.\10\ More significantly, almost every married couple saw a sharp reduction in their marginal tax rate--the tax that applies to the last dollar earned. A couple earning $51,000, for example, saw their marginal rate drop from 75 percent to 59 percent between 1947 and 1948. Again, those in the middle brackets, not the rich, were the principal beneficiaries. In practice, the impact of lower tax rates was mainly on women. Since a married woman's earnings came on top of her husband's, she was in effect taxed at her husband's marginal tax rate on the first dollar of her earnings. With marginal tax rates going as high as 90 percent after World War II, this very strongly discouraged married women from working. Although the institution of income splitting was highly beneficial to most married couples, it created a problem for single taxpayers. As a result of income splitting, a married couple mow paid significantly less tax than a single earner with the same income. Congress tried to address this inequity in 1951 by creating a new tax rate schedule for single heads of households, which roughly split the difference between the married and single tax schedules. Singles, however, continued to agitate for tax relief. By 1969, some single taxpayers were paying 42 percent more federal taxes than a married couple with the same income. That year Congress created a new tax schedule for singles that was designed to keep the tax burden on singles and married couples with the same income within 20 percent of each other. This legislation created a significant marriage penalty for the first time.\11\ As a result, some married couples now paid more taxes by filing jointly than they would have paid if both filed as individuals.\12\ Further contributing to the rise of the marriage penalty was the steep rise in the number of women in the labor force. The number of women in the labor force increased by about 50 percent between the late 1940s and the early 1970s. The labor force participation rate for women has continued to rise since and in 1997 was almost double the rate of 1947. This is important because a marriage penalty only occurs when a husband and wife both have earned income. With women working in greater and greater numbers, this means that the likelihood of a couple suffering a marriage penalty rose concomitantly. As knowledge of the marriage penalty grew, increasing numbers of couples began to take matters into their own hands by getting divorced for tax reasons. One couple, David and Angela Boyter, received national publicity for getting divorced each December, allowing each to file as single for the year, and then getting remarried in January.\13\ Eventually the IRS cracked down on this charade, but not before moving Congress to action.\14\ By 1981, there was strong political pressure to redress the marriage penalty problem. A variety of proposals were put forward to accomplish this goal.\15\ In the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981, Congress attempted to redress the marriage penalty by giving the lower paid spouse a 10 percent tax deduction on income up to $30,000, for a maximum deduction of $3,000. While this provision did not eliminate the marriage penalty, it did redress the problem substantially for most married taxpayers.\16\ The secondary earner deduction did not live long, however, and was eliminated by the Tax Reform Act of 1986. But because the Tax Reform Act sharply reduced tax rates for most taxpayers, the net effect was to reduce the number of couples suffering a marriage penalty and the magnitude of the penalty.\17\ Nevertheless, some couples were worse off.\18\ The most recent tax legislation with a major impact on the marriage penalty is the 1993 tax bill.\19\ Interestingly, the provision of the legislation that exacerbated the marriage penalty was not the increase in tax rates, but the expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC). The EITC is a refundable income tax credit for workers with low earnings. It creates marriage penalties because it is phased-out as incomes rise and because it is maximized for workers with two children.\20\ No additional credit is available for three or more children in a single qualifying family. Depending on their income, therefore, a two-earner couple might significantly increase their joint EITC benefit by divorcing. And if they have more than two children, the benefits of divorce can be enormous. In 1996, for example, a two-earner couple with four children and each earning $11,000 would have increased their EITC payment from $1,375 to $7,120 by getting divorced, with each spouse claiming two children.\21\ As noted earlier, the principal effect of the marriage penalty has been on wives, because they generally earn less than their husbands and thus are in effect taxed at their husbands' marginal tax rate. This means that wives generally receive less aftertax income on each dollar they earn than their husbands do. This alone is sufficient to significantly discourage work effort among married women. There is a considerable amount of economic research clearly demonstrating that high marginal tax rates reduce labor supply, especially for married women.\22\ The disincentive effects of high marginal tax rates on married women are aggravated by their looser attachment to the labor force than men and their child-rearing responsibilities.\23\ Although most married women who work do so because of financial necessity, many do not. Their income is not essential for maintaining a couple's standard of living. Such women may work for a variety of reasons, including the simple joy of doing so. But the consequence is that they are more easily driven from the labor force by tax disincentives than married men are. For this reason, economic theory suggests that married women should be taxed less than married men.\24\ Thus it should come as no surprise that tax policies affecting the marriage penalty have had a significant impact on female labor supply. The institution of income splitting in 1948 and the effective reduction in marginal tax rates had a significant effect on women's work decisions. Between 1947 and 1950 the labor force participation rate for married women shot up, raising their share of the female labor force from 46.2 percent to 52.1 percent. Those with a husband present, those most likely to be affected by income splitting, increased their labor force participation most, increasing their share of the female labor force from 40.9 percent to 48 percent. By contrast, single, widowed or divorced women, who gained nothing from income splitting, saw their labor force participation stay flat or decline. The labor force participation rate for men was also unchanged over this period. A study of the 1981 tax act, which reduced the marriage penalty by instituting a secondary earner deduction, shows that married women's work expanded by almost enough to pay for the deduction's revenue loss.\25\ Analysis of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, which lowered the top marginal tax rate from 50 percent to 28 percent, shows that married women responded more strongly to the increased work incentive than men did.\26\ Another study estimated that if the marriage penalties remaining after the Tax Reform Act were eliminated, the average married woman would increase her hours worked by 46 hours per year. High-income and low-income women would respond even more strongly, increasing their work hours by 100 hours per year.\27\ The latest estimates by Martin Feldstein and Daniel Feenberg suggest that the labor supply response of married women to reduction of the marriage penalty could be quite large. Sharply cutting the tax rate on secondary workers could lead to an increase in earnings by such workers of as much as $66 billion per year.\28\ In addition to effects on labor supply, the marriage penalty also impacts the marriage/divorce decision. There is certainly no question that over time the number of couples living together without marriage has sharply increased. The Census Bureau reports that 523,000 adults of the opposite sex were living together in 1970. By 1996, this figure had risen to 3,958,000. In 1970, unmarried couples represented just 0.5 percent of the married couples in the United States. By 1996, this percentage had risen to 7.2 percent. At least some of this is undoubtedly due to tax considerations. Several studies have looked at this question. They find that the marriage penalty has a small but significant impact on couples' decision to marry. When the marriage penalty rises aggregate marriage rates fall. There is a much greater impact on the timing of marriage, with couples often delaying marriage late in the year to minimize their marriage penalty.\29\ Finally, there is some evidence that taxes encourage divorce, especially on the part of women who are affected most by the marriage penalty.\30\ As noted earlier, from 1913 to 1948 Congress adopted an approach to taxation that did not differentiate between married and unmarried persons. There was only one tax schedule and everyone paid the same rates. A single person and a married couple with the same income paid the same tax. Congress did not willingly adopt income splitting in 1948. It was forced to do so out of necessity resulting from the consequences of a Supreme Court case. Nevertheless, the effect was to replace the individual with the family as the fundamental unit for taxation. It has long been known that a tax system cannot simultaneously do three things: (1) have progressive tax rates, (2) have equal tax treatment of couples with the same income, and (3) be marriage-neutral.\31\ The last point means that marital status would have no effect on an individual's tax liability. If the first point is accepted, one must choose between the second and third. In 1948, Congress chose the first and second and abandoned the third. In recent years, a number of tax theorists have questioned Congress's decision. Progressivity is no longer assumed to be a primary criterion of our tax system. Increasingly, tax theorists question whether it is fair to penalize those with higher incomes, while economists produce more and more data on the economic cost of progressivity. At the same time, others question the assumption of family-based taxation. They argue that a system of individual filing would be fairer, simpler and more efficient. The notion of progressivity has been under attack for many years. Tax experts have long known that exemptions, deductions and exclusions in the Tax Code can easily erode the nominal progressivity of the rate structure. They have also known that progressivity breeds complexity, evasion and imposes a large deadweight cost on the economy. But the idea that ``fairness'' demanded higher tax rates on those with upper incomes was too widespread to challenge.\32\ By the 1980s, however, opinion had shifted sufficiently that there was now serious support for the idea of a flat tax, one with a single tax rate for all taxpayers regardless of income. So popular was the idea that in 1986 Congress went a long way toward a flat tax by creating a two-rate tax system, with a top rate of just 28 percent. Eventually, even academic tax theorists began to come around to the idea. Now it is common to read criticism of progressivity in leading law journals, where earlier it would have been unthinkable.\33\ At the same time, economists have increasingly come to see the cost of progressivity as extremely high. One study put it this way: Even a mild degree of progressivity in the income tax system (as measured by the steepness of the marginal rate schedule) imposes a very large efficiency cost. For example, in comparison with an equal revenue proportional income tax, a progressive income tax with average tax rates varying over the life cycle between .23 and .32 and marginal rates ranging from .23 to .43 imposes an efficiency cost greater than 6 percent of full lifetime resources.\34\ Since that study appeared, many others have come to similar conclusions about the overall welfare cost of progressivity in the U.S. tax system.\35\ As a result, a recent president of the American Economic Association has said, ``Today, it is fair to say that many, if not most, economists favor the expenditure tax or flat rate income tax. This group has joined the opponents of progressive taxation in the attack on the income tax.'' \36\ Just as progressivity increasingly has become questioned as a norm of taxation, so too many tax theorists now question whether the family should be the fundamental unit of taxation. They suggest that the individual, rather than the family, is the most appropriate unit of taxation. Such a move would eliminate the marriage penalty completely, but would also eliminate marriage bonuses. Such bonuses, however, may be inappropriate because there is no particular reason why couples should receive special treatment from the Tax Code merely because they are married. To the extent that we wish to aid children, we could target tax deductions or credits directly to the children, rather than families in general.\37\ Individual taxation may also be better suited to changing societal mores. In 1948, relatively few women worked, few headed households, and most couples had a single earner. Now women work in almost the same percentages as men, female-headed households are common, and families represent a decreasing share of households. Indeed, growth of the marriage penalty is as much due to demographic changes as changes in the tax law.\38\ According to the Census Bureau, nonfamily households have risen from 18.8 percent of all households in 1970 to 30.1 percent in 1996.\39\ It is also worth noting that most major industrialized countries use the individual as the basic unit of taxation.\40\ It is not necessary to completely abandon the family as the basic unit of taxation in order to eliminate the marriage penalty. It would only be necessary to allow couples the choice of filing as singles or jointly. This would preserve marriage bonuses for single-earner couples, but eliminate the marriage penalty for two-earner couples. However, Congress would also have to pass rules about dividing joint income, such as interest and dividends, and allocating itemized deductions, such as for mortgage interest and dependents.\41\ The major objections to the choice approach are complexity, cost and abandonment of the principle that couples with the same income should pay similar taxes. It would be complex because many couples would, in effect, have to do their taxes twice: first jointly and then as singles to see which way they would come out ahead. Also, whatever rules are adopted for allocating joint income and deductions are bound to be complicated. Allowing couples to choose their filing status would also be costly. According to the CBO, it would have reduced federal revenues by $29 billion in 1996.\42\ It will also lead to situations in which certain couples will pay less total taxes than others with the same income. This could create pressure in future years for further tax measures to redress this perceived imbalance. Congress certainly needs to be wary about adding additional complexity to an already overly complicated Tax Code. However, in recent years Congress has enacted a number of very complicated provisions to the tax law involving phase-outs for various tax benefits that also have the effect of worsening the marriage penalty for some couples. For example, the child credit is phased-out for couples with incomes over $110,000 and over $75,000 for singles. This means that a couple making $75,000 each would qualify for the full $500 per child credit if they divorce, but receive nothing if married.\43\ Almost any solution to the marriage penalty is likely to increase complexity and raise questions about cost and fairness.\44\ Short of going all the way to an individual filing system, other options for redressing the marriage penalty include restoration of the second-earner deduction, such as that included in the 1981 tax bill, widening tax brackets and modifying provisions such as the EITC that create marriage penalties.\45\ Given the cost of full elimination of the marriage penalty and budgetary realities, in the end Congress will probably be forced to choose among these more limited options if it decides to address the issue at all. A better solution to further tinkering with the Tax Code would be to move toward a flat rate income or consumption tax. By eliminating progressivity, it gets at the root cause of the marriage penalty.\46\ Although there are many other arguments for a flat tax, this one may prove most persuasive to two- earner couples. Endnotes 1. Other factors contributing to the marriage penalty are the standard deduction, personal exemptions, the Earned Income Tax Credit, phase-outs for personal exemptions, and the limitation on itemized deductions. See Congressional Budget Office (CBO), For Better or for Worse: Marriage and the Federal Income Tax (Washington: USGPO, 1997), pp. 15-25. 2. Dorothy A. Brown, ``The Marriage Bonus/Penalty in Black and White,'' University of Cincinnati Law Review, vol. 65, no. 3 (Spring 1997), pp. 787-798. 3. U.S. Commission on Civil Rights, The Economic Status of Black Women: An Exploratory Investigation (Washington: USGPO, 1990), pp. 100, 105. 4. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970, 2 parts (Washington: USGPO, 1975), pt 1, pp. 132-33. 5. The following discussion draws heavily on Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT), The Income Tax Treatment of Married Couples and Single Persons, Joint Committee Print JCS-17-80 (Washington: USGPO, 1980), pp. 19-25. 6. For a discussion of the spread of community property laws and other means by which people attempted to exploit the opportunity to split incomes, see Carolyn C. Jones, ``Split Income and Separate Spheres: Tax Law and Gender Roles in the 1940s,'' Law and History Review, vol. 6, no. 2 (Fall 1988), pp. 259-310. 7. House Report 1274, 80th Congress, 2nd session (1948), p. 22. 8. Michael J. Graetz, The Decline (and Fall?) of the Income Tax (New York: W.W. Norton, 1997), p. 31. 9. For details, see Stanley Surrey, ``Federal Taxation of the Family--The Revenue Act of 1948,'' Harvard Law Review, vol. 61, no. 7 (July 1948), pp. 1097-1164. 10. House Ways and Means Committee, Reduction of Individual Income Taxes, 80th Congress, 2nd session (Washington: USGPO, 1948), p. 28. 11. For evidence that small marriage penalties existed for some taxpayers before 1969, see John Brozovsky and A.J. Cataldo, II, ``A Historical Analysis of the `Marriage Tax Penalty,''' Accounting Historians Journal, vol. 21, no. 1 (June 1994), pp. 163-187. 12. Grace Blumberg, ``Sexism in the Code: A Comparative Study of Income Taxation of Working Wives and Mothers,'' Buffalo Law Review, vol. 21, no. 1 (Fall 1971), pp. 49-98; Joyce Nussbaum, ``The Tax Structure and Discrimination Against Working Wives,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 25, no. 2 (June 1972), pp. 183-191. 13. The reason this worked is because for tax purposes a couple are regarded as married for the full year if married on December 31, and they are considered separated for the full year if divorced on that day. For these and other complications regarding whether a couple is or is not married for tax purposes, see Toni Robinson and Mary Moers Wenig, ``Marry in Haste, Repent at Tax Time: Marital Status as a Tax Determinant,'' Virginia Tax Review, vol. 8, no. 4 (Spring 1989), pp. 788-819. 14. Graetz, Decline of the Income Tax, pp. 35-38. 15. Lynda S. Moerschbaecher, ``The Marriage Penalty and the Divorce Bonus: A Comparative Examination of the Current Legislative Proposals,'' Review of Taxation of Individuals, vol. 5, no. 2 (Spring 1981), pp. 133-146. 16. Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 (Washington: USGPO, 1981), p. 35. 17. Harvey S. Rosen, ``The Marriage Penalty Is Down But Not Out,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 40, no. 4 (December 1987), pp. 567-575; Douglas W. Mitchell, ``The Marriage Tax Penalty and Subsidy Under Tax Reform,'' Eastern Economic Journal, vol. 12, no. 2 (April-June 1989), pp. 113-116. 18. Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (Washington: USGPO, 1987), p. 19. 19. Daniel Feenberg and Harvey S. Rosen, ``Recent Developments in the Marriage Tax,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 48, no. 1 (March 1995), pp. 91-101; Gregg A. Eisenwein, ``Marriage Tax Penalties After the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993,'' CRS Report for Congress, 93-1000E (November 19, 1993). 20. Anne L. Alstott, ``The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Limitations of Tax-Based Welfare Reform,'' Harvard Law Review, vol. 108, no. 3 (January 1995), pp. 559-564; Edward McCaffery, ``Taxation and the Family: A Fresh Look at Behavioral Biases in the Code,'' UCLA Law Review, vol. 40, no. 4 (April 1993), pp. 1014-1020. 21. Janet Novack, ``The Worm in the Apple,'' Forbes (November 7, 1994), p. 98. 22. The most recent research is summarized in Congressional Budget Office, ``Labor Supply and Taxes,'' CBO Memorandum (January 1996); and Robert K. Triest, ``The Effect of Income Taxation on Labor Supply in the United States,'' Journal of Human Resources, vol. 25, no. 3 (Summer 1990), pp. 491-516. 23. Jerry Hausman, ``Taxes and Labor Supply,'' in Alan J. Auerbach and Martin Feldstein, eds., Handbook of Public Economics (New York: North-Holland, 1985), pp. 247-249. 24. Michael J. Boskin and Eytan Sheshinski, ``Optimal Tax Treatment of the Family: Married Couples,'' Journal of Public Economics, vol. 20, no. 3 (April 1983), pp. 281-297. 25. Daniel Feenberg, ``The Tax Treatment of Married Couples and the 1981 Tax Law,'' NBER Working Paper No. 872 (April 1982). 26. Nada Eissa, ``Taxation and Labor Supply of Married Women: The Tax Reform Act of 1986 as a Natural Experiment,'' National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5023 (February 1995); idem, ``Tax Reforms and Labor Supply,'' in James M. Poterba, ed., Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 10 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996), pp. 119-151. 27. Deenie K. Neff, ``Married Women's Labor Supply and the Marriage Penalty,'' Public Finance Quarterly, vol. 18, no. 4 (October 1990), pp. 420-432. 28. Martin Feldstein and Daniel Feenberg, ``The Taxation of Two Earner Families,'' NBER Working Paper No. 5155 (June 1995). 29. James Alm and Leslie A. Whittington, ``Income Taxes and the Marriage Decision,'' Applied Economics, vol. 27, no. 1 (January 1995), pp. 25-31; idem, ``Does the Income Tax Affect Marital Decisions?'' National Tax Journal, vol. 48, no. 4 (December 1995), pp. 565-572; idem, ``Income Taxes and the Timing of Marital Decisions,'' Journal of Public Economics, vol. 64, no. 2 (May 1997), pp. 219-240; David L. Sjoquist and Mary Beth Walker, ``The Marriage Tax and the Rate and Timing of Marriage,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 48, no. 4 (December 1995), pp. 547-548; Alexander Gelardi, ``The Influence of Tax Law Changes on the Timing of Marriages: A Two-Country Analysis,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 49, no. 1 (March 1996), pp. 17-30. 30. Leslie A. Whittington and James Alm, ``'Til Death or Taxes Do Us Part: The Effect of Income Taxation on Divorce,'' Journal of Human Resources, vol. 32, no. 2 (Spring 1997), pp. 388-412. 31. Boris I. Bittker, ``Federal Income Taxation and the Family,'' Stanford Law Review, vol. 27, no. 6 (July 1975), pp. 1395-96; Jane M. Fraser, ``The Marriage Tax,'' Management Science, vol. 32, no. 7 (July 1986), pp. 831-840; Marvin Chirelstein, Federal Income Taxation, 7th ed. (Westbury, NY: Foundation Press, 1994), p. 219. 32. See Walter J. Blum and Harry Kalven Jr., The Uneasy Case for Progressive Taxation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953). 33. See, for example, Richard L. Doernberg, ``A Workable Flat Rate Consumption Tax,'' Iowa Law Review, vol. 70, no. 2 (January 1985), pp. 425-485; Charles R. O'Kelley, Jr., ``Tax Policy for Post-Liberal Society: A Flat-Tax-Inspired Redefinition of the Purpose and Ideal Structure of a Progressive Income Tax,'' Southern California Law Review, vol. 58, no. 3 (March 1985), pp. 727-776; Curtis J. Berger, ``In Behalf of a Single-Rate Flat Tax,'' St. Louis University Law Journal, vol. 29, no. 4 (June 1985), pp. 993-1027; Richard A. Epstein, ``Taxation in a Lockean World,'' Social Philosophy and Policy, vol. 4, no. 1 (Autumn 1986), pp. 49-74; Joseph Bankman and Thomas Griffith, ``Social Welfare and the Rate Structure: A New Look at Progressive Taxation,'' California Law Review, vol. 75, no. 6 (December 1987), pp. 1905-1967; Jay M. Howard, ``When Two Tax Theories Collide: A Look at the History and Future of Progressive and Proportionate Personal Income Taxation,'' Washburn Law Journal, vol. 32, no. 1 (Fall 1992), pp. 43- 76; Jeffrey A. Schoenblum, ``Tax Fairness or Unfairness? A Consideration of the Philosophical Bases for Unequal Taxation of Individuals,'' American Journal of Tax Policy, vol. 12, no. 2 (Fall 1995), pp. 221-271 34. Alan J. Auerbach, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and Jonathan Skinner, ``The Efficiency Gains from Dynamic Tax Reform,'' International Economic Review, vol. 24, no. 1 (February 1983), pp. 81-100. 35. Charles Stuart, ``Welfare Costs per Dollar of Additional Tax Revenue in the United States,'' American Economic Review, vol. 74, no. 3 (June 1984), pp. 352-362; Charles L. Ballard, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley, ``General Equilibrium Computations of the Marginal Welfare Costs of Taxes in the United States,'' American Economic Review, vol. 75, no. 1 (March 1985), pp. 128-138; idem, ``The Total Welfare Cost of the United States Tax System: A General Equilibrium Approach,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 38, no. 2 (June 1985), pp. 125- 140; Dale W. Jorgenson and Kun-Young Yun, ``Tax Reform and U.S. Economic Growth,'' Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no. 5, pt. 2 (October 1990), pp. S151-S193; idem, ``The Excess Burden of Taxation in the United States,'' Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, vol. 6, no. 4 (Fall 1991), pp. 487-508. 36. Joseph A. Pechman, ``The Future of the Income Tax,'' American Economic Review, vol. 80, no. 1 (March 1990), p. 1. 37. Harvey Rosen, ``Is It Time to Abandon Joint Filing?'' National Tax Journal, vol. 30, no. 4 (December 1977), pp. 423-428; Alicia Munnell, ``The Couple versus the Individual under the Federal Personal Income Tax,'' in Henry J. Aaron and Michael J. Boskin, eds., The Economics of Taxation (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1980), pp. 247-278; Pamela B. Gann, ``Abandoning Marital Status as a Factor in Allocating Income Tax Burdens,'' Texas Law Review, vol. 59, no. 1 (December 1980), pp. 1-69; Laura Ann Davis, ``A Feminist Justification for the Adoption of an Individual Filing System,'' Southern California Law Review, vol. 62, no. 1 (November 1988), pp. 197-252; Marjorie E. Kornhauser, ``Love, Money, and the IRS: Family, Income-Sharing, and the Joint Income Tax Return,'' Hastings Law Journal, vol. 45, no. 1 (November 1993); Edward J. McCaffery, Taxing Women (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997). 38. James Alm and Leslie Whittington, ``The Rise and Fall and Rise...of the Marriage Tax,'' National Tax Journal, vol. 49, no. 4 (December 1996), pp. 571-589. 39. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1997 (Washington: USGPO, 1998), p. 59. 40. CBO, For Better or Worse, p. 60. 41. JCT, Income Tax Treatment, pp. 38-46. 42. CBO, For Better or Worse, p. 55. 43. For a discussion of other provisions of recent tax laws that exacerbate the marriage penalty for some couples, see David J. Roberts and Mark J. Sullivan, ``The Federal Income Tax: Where Are the Family Values?'' Tax Notes (October 26, 1992), pp. 547-550; Albert B. Crenshaw, ``For Two-Income Couples, More Reasons Not to Get Tied,'' Washington Post (August 24, 1997); Janet Novak and Laura Saunders, ``Torture By Taxation,'' Forbes (August 25, 1997), pp. 42-44; Diana Furchtgott-Roth and Kevin Hassett, ``The Skyline Tax,'' The Weekly Standard (September 29, 1997), pp. 13-14; Janet Novak, ``The Old Shell Game,'' Forbes (December 29, 1997), pp. 76-81. 44. Opponents of eliminating the marriage penalty have already made this point. See Jonathan Chait, ``Penalty Box: The Folly of Fighting the Marriage Tax,'' The New Republic (October 20, 1997), pp. 14, 16. 45. CBO, For Better or Worse, pp. 47-56; Jonathan Barry Forman, ``What Can Be Done About Marriage Penalties?'' Family Law Quarterly, vol. 30, no. 1 (Spring 1996), pp. 1-22. 46. CBO, For Better or Worse, p. 56; Joint Committee on Taxation, Impact on Individuals and Families of Replacing the Federal Income Tax, JCS-8-97 (Washington: USGPO, 1997), p. 103. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Bartlett. And my compliments to all of you because you have given us some excellent testimony, and I can assure you that the Committee is going to consider what you've said very seriously before we act. Do all four of you basically agree on a particular approach which is appropriate to solve this problem? We have a problem; we know that. But the solution to the problem is what we have to focus on. Now, do you think all four of you could come together on the appropriate solution? Mr. Graetz. Mr. Chairman, I think that there are two difficulties here in our coming together. One is the revenue that you are prepared to devote to this issue. If you give us unlimited revenue, I suppose we could reach a solution as quickly as the Committee could, but we all know that that's not the current reality. And so the question would be setting priorities about where you would first relieve the marriage penalty, and we might have different priorities. I think that we probably would come fairly close to a solution once you told us how much revenue we had to spend on it. We could probably come to some agreement; although, I want to be clear that my differences with Mr. Feenberg are important. He is focused on the behavioral effects of this marriage penalty on people entering the labor market, and I'm focused on what taxing marriage does in terms of the signal it sends to the American people about how the Congress and the American people's values line up. I think this is a very serious issue. This was, as Congressman Thomas said earlier, it was a huge issue during the welfare debate, and it seems to me it's an extremely important issue now concerning values and how the tax system reflects values. So there is a difference between us. I wouldn't put as much weight on incentives as Mr. Feenberg. I also want to compliment Mr. Lifson on the phaseout point. That is clearly something that I think we could all endorse in some fashion: to move to his phaseout solution. And this is the first time I've heard that idea. As we said, Mr. Chairman, I've heard most of them over the past 25 years. Chairman Archer. Mr. Feenberg, since your name was mentioned would you like to comment? Mr. Feenberg. There's no disagreement in values between me and Professor Graetz. I'm testifying to the things that I know most about. That doesn't mean that I disagree with what he testified about--other, no doubt, more important things. Chairman Archer. Well, let me comment on that. Before, it seemed like we always talked about what is the economic impact of everything that we do here. Now I've begun to focus on what is the moral and social impact of how we tax. I believe we're going to have to talk more about that, and think more about that, because it has a dramatic effect on our society, both morally and socially. But, of course that's my own view which I expressed right in this room a week ago in the press conference that I held. There was one reason for my asking you that question, beyond what we've discussed, and it is because I have reached the point of believing you will never fix the income tax; that the income tax is, in effect, an attractive nuisance, which is a very specific legal term meaning that it draws all kinds of bad things into it over time. I will say that I used to be for the flat tax, Mr. Bartlett, back in 1985, until I went through the 1985-1986 reform effort, and after that I became convinced you'll never fix the income tax. Though we shrank the amount of deductions, we did reduce the number of tax rates to two-- statutorily at least. By 1990, we were already back to 3 rates, and by 1993 we were back to the 5 rates we have now. The empirical data prove that what we seem to learn from history is that we never seem to learn from history. Now you tell me how we're going to keep an income tax, which inherently is an attractive nuisance, simple. I don't believe it's possible. I don't believe this body will pass a flat income tax without a deduction for charitable contributions and home mortgage interest. Nor do I believe that it will be able, politically, to pass a flat income tax without taxing dividends, rent, royalties, and what we call--I think inappropriately, but nevertheless--unearned income. It will not happen. And so you are off to the races again. You planted the seed again, replanted the income tax--the roots are there and the tree is spouting even before you get out of this Committee. Inevitably you are back into all of the ramifications about how we solve this problem. That's why I asked you the question, because there is not unanimity among you as to how we solve it, and we will always have to redefine income. It is an uncertain term, and we will forever be creating inequities as we solve an inequity, and then we will have to patch that. So, I personally believe that the right way to do this is to let people pay their taxes when they spend their money and then you have no problem with a marriage penalty. But, that's my own personal view which has been developed over the years. Now, let me ask you all this--there are several things that are specific to this marriage penalty, and I want to ask you: under any proposal that you might be comfortable with, would there be a marriage bonus? And if so, what would it be? And would that, over time, be perceived as being equitable? Mr. Bartlett. Well, speaking for myself, I think a case can be made for getting rid of the bonuses. I don't really see any reason as a matter of public policy why a man and a women without children who simply happen to be married should pay substantially less taxes than they would pay as singles. You'd get rid of that by going to an individual filing system. I think when we talk about families, what we really mean are families with children, and I think you should target the tax relief to the children directly and not to the institution of marriage per se. Obviously, that's a somewhat controversial point, but I think that that's the way we ought to think about going. And I think that certainly the Weller-McIntosh bill moves a long way in that direction. But, I think it is worth noting that if you got rid of the bonuses, it's about the same in the aggregate as the penalties, so that if you went to a pure individual filing system it wouldn't really cost the treasury anything. Chairman Archer. Before I move on to you, Mr. Graetz, I ask Mr. Bartlett: will the flat tax proposal that you endorse completely eliminate the marriage penalty insofar as doubling the exclusion for two people who are married compared to a single? Mr. Bartlett. It could easily be designed to do that. Chairman Archer. No. But, let's take the Armey-Forbes approach, is it double the exclusion for a married couple compared to a single? Mr. Bartlett. No, I think it's more. Chairman Archer. So it still has a marriage penalty. You cited that a flat tax gets rid of the marriage penalty, but their proposal does not get rid of it. Mr. Bartlett. Well, I would point out also that the sales tax proposal--the Schaefer-Tauzin bill, for example--also has a marriage penalty, because it has the rebate mechanism that is based on family size, based on the Census Bureau---- Chairman Archer. Well, of course, that is one proposal that is out there---- Mr. Bartlett. I'm just saying that there are many marriage penalties, and you can design---- Chairman Archer. But certainly where all income is treated equally and you pay your taxes when you spend your money, you have no marriage penalty. All income is treated equally. You don't have to get into the definition of income. Mr. Bartlett. I'm just saying the rebate mechanism does, or can, create a marriage penalty, that's all. Chairman Archer. But, the point I wanted to make is that there will not be an automatic elimination of the marriage penalty if you go to a flat income tax. Mr. Graetz. Mr. Graetz. Mr. Chairman, I just wanted to say a word about individual filing on a mandatory basis. That was the law before 1948. And, as you know well, what happened during the period of 1941 until 1948--which is the period when the income tax was extended to the masses because of the Second World War--is that a number of common-law States started moving to community property. A number of States started to reverse their marital property laws which had been in place historically depending primarily on whether they had adopted the British property system or a continental system--as Texas did. You cannot have an individual filing that would not reintroduce the problem of community property and common-law States that caused such havoc in the forties. You also would introduce the prospect of tax planning by shifting the ownership of property to the low- income spouse. That is to say, if you just move some stock to the low-income spouse, then the dividends on that stock would be taxed at a lower rate than if the stock is owned by the high-income spouse. The reason that we have a marriage bonus is that Congress decided in 1948 that the way to solve this problem under a progressive rate schedule was to give married couples the best possible split of income, which in a progressive system is to treat them as if the income came equally from each partner. I have to say, I think that marriage bonuses are much more benign than marriage penalties. But I think that moving back toward an individual filing system is going to add complexity, in the filing of tax returns, and also in terms of family arrangements. You're going to hear from different couples than you heard from today, but I suspect you'll hear from some. Chairman Archer. Well, don't you have to continue to define income and who earns the income? Now, I happen to believe that in a marriage, half of a married couple's income is earned by each spouse legally. Why should our tax laws not accept that? But then you have different laws within the States on property and you get all fouled up with the beginning point, which is who earns this income legally. That is a very difficult question to answer, and you never get away from it with an income tax. Well, do either one of the other two of you want to comment on my initial question? Mr. Lifson. Well, I would say that we could agree to a method, and I would say that we could agree to a baseline. What we would have a hard time agreeing on is not elimination of the penalty, but who gets the bonus, if anybody. But I would say as an accountant, I have listened to many enraged other accountants, quite enraged about who should get these bonuses. But I think that my fellow panelist said, it's a much more benign argument about who should receive a bonus than who should pay a penalty. The true issue is creating an equitable base line, and arguably looking at the concept about whether once you are married two of you are taxed jointly, because of your marriage, or whether you are allowed to remain an independent economic unit as so many marriages would like to remain. You can still respect and report your income jointly. And you can still tax it as if each person earns half. All of these are modest mechanical considerations that I think can be worked out. How to spend the bonus is beyond what I think we could work out. Chairman Archer. Well, that's why I asked the question about the bonus. Because that is an inherent part of whatever we ultimately do. Mr. Bartlett. Could I just say one thing? I think that while it is very important that we have some idea of ultimately where we would like to go in terms of dealing with this problem, you can't overlook the budgetary constraints. And I just think that in the end you are going to be faced with a dilemma. You're going to have a certain pot of money, and you are going to have many competing interests, and at the end of the day you are going to have whatever: $5 billion, $10 billion, however many billion, to devote to this one problem, and you'll simply have to shoehorn some proposal that fits the numbers into it. But I would like to suggest that when the time comes that you look very carefully at the incentive effects because, as you know, the Joint Committee now has the authority to do some modified behavioral responses in terms of dynamic scoring, and it may very well make the difference between going with one approach or another that may have the same static cost but they may have quite different dynamic costs. Chairman Archer. Well, I think you are absolutely correct in everything that you said. I want to highlight the end of it because when we took over as a Congressional majority 3 years ago, I pushed very hard for the Joint Committee on Taxation to begin to take into account behavioral response; they do that now, contrary to what an awful lot of people write out there. They do take into account behavioral response. What they do not, and cannot, take into account is microeconomic feedback because that is determined by CBO. The Joint Committee has really updated and modernized their estimating process, I think, to become more accurate. Let me ask one last question. The Committee has indulged me and I apologize to the Members. The term targeting is now used more in the arena politically. You heard the President use it in his speech last night, that all tax relief should be targeted. Now, doesn't targeting, in effect, impact in a bad way on the marriage penalty? Mr. Graetz. Mr. Chairman, this is a particularly complicated question because many of the new marriage penalties in the Code--and I mean the ones that are there because they have been added subsequent to the 1969 change in the rate schedule--are due to targeted provisions. For example, the reason that a married couple who are retired will pay more taxes in many instances than an unmarried couple who are retired is because of the way in which the income taxation of Social Security works. The reason that low-income workers--and I have to say, listening to the couple that was here today and the magnitude of the marriage penalties they were describing, I suspect--I don't know this because I haven't seen their returns, but I suspect--that part of the marriage tax they are talking about is because of the way the earned income tax credit works in its phaseouts. They said they made less than $10 an hour and it sounded to me like they might be in that targeted group. And here the problem, Mr. Chairman, is that many of these penalties--many of the largest of these penalties--now exist in specific provisions of the Code. The AICPA again is to be complimented in looking for a general approach to some of these phaseouts. I have to say, I dread the thought of teaching the 1997 phaseout rules to my basic income tax class, and I have the luxury of having Yale Law students to try and master them. Chairman Archer. Well, in effect, I would synthesize what you said by saying that targeting can become a code word for greater marriage penalties and much higher complications in a Code that we say we want to simplify. All of you are nodding your heads, and the record should show that. I thank you very much for your testimony. Any inquiry by other Members? Mr. Weller. Mr. Weller. Again, thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your leadership by conducting this hearing. I think as we raise the profile of this issue every day we get closer to April 15, more of these 21 million married working couples are going to realize that they are paying this marriage penalty and they are going to be looking to the President and Congress to work together in a bipartisan way to solve it. And I have a question that I would like to address to Mr. Lifson. And of course, I like your suggestion of working to make the Tax Code marriage neutral. And I appreciate your identifying 63 areas in the Tax Code where the marriage penalty exists beyond just the joint combined income situation. As we worked on the Marriage Tax Elimination Act, and in consulting with many of your members who happen to reside in Illinois in my district and throughout the country--and of course many of them had their ideas and suggestions which produced the legislation that we have in the Marriage Tax Elimination Act--I remember one of them said--and that was just recently, in fact, I was just talking to one just this past week--he said, you know, I have a couple before me right now-- we were on the telephone--and he says, this couple, I just informed them that had they stayed single, they each would have received a tax refund. But because they chose to get married, they are going to owe taxes. Clearly illustrating the problem in the marriage tax penalty. Just from your perspective as representing a lot of the tax preparers across the country, which do you think is a higher priority: addressing the problem that comes from filing jointly with a combined income pushing you into a higher tax bracket, or eliminating those 63 targeted tax provisions, which creates 63 additional marriage tax penalties? Mr. Lifson. I think that in most of our discussions the easiest target, if you'll excuse the term, the easiest target for simplification is going to a single table, that is, one table for all. It has the greatest appearance of both simplification and equity to it. And neutrality, everybody pays according to one table. I think to simply look at 1 of the 63 items is a naive approach and that you have to dig in deeper if you really want to solve the problem rather than the initial appearance of the problem. It won't take the American taxpayers long to come into my office and find out that just because it is advertised that there is now only 1 table that there aren't 60 more problems for them to think about. I think that you have to do both. Mr. Weller. Well, thank you. Again, thank you, Mr. Chairman, for conducting this hearing because it does raise a very important issue that affects 21 million married, working couples across the country. And when you think about it, $1,400 on average for each of these couples is a drop in the bucket here in Washington, but for a couple back in Illinois, or any of our communities we represent, that's a year's tuition to a local community college, 3 month's worth of child care at a local daycare center, several month's worth of car payments. It means a lot. And the bottom line is we need to be working to eliminate this penalty. Again, thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your leadership in conducting this hearing. Mr. Herger [presiding]. Thank you. Mr. Feenberg, you mentioned in your testimony that you had done research on the labor market effects of restoring the two- earner deduction. I wonder if you could elaborate, that on how you feel that proposal would affect tax revenues. Mr. Feenberg. Our conclusion was just that the proposal would be cheaper than it looks because it lowers the marginal tax rate on a group that has relatively elastic response-- elastic attachment to the labor force. There would be additional earnings from secondary earners and that would come back into the income tax and into the Social Security taxes which is just as important. And so that in the end the thing turns out to be cheaper than might look at first glance. And in particular, if you put a higher cap--$50,000 instead of $30,000--there are more people who are still at the margin, rather than receiving the capped amount, and so there is still more labor supply and that makes it even cheaper so that it dominates. That is it has a lower foregone revenue but it is better from a utility perspective from each taxpayer's point of view. So, it's not really a statement about whether it's a good thing or a bad thing, it's just a statement that if you follow through all the effects on labor supply, it's likely to be cheaper than it looks at first glance. Mr. Herger. Thank you very much. I think that certainly is an important point to bring out. I appreciate your doing so in your testimony. Mr. Hulshof will inquire. Mr. Hulshof. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just briefly, and I think each of you has mentioned in your own words that any time we talk about targeted tax relief, we are subject to budgetary constraints. Mr. Bartlett, I think you said it most forcefully at the end. And I think each of these particular provisions, whether it's Mr. Weller, Mr. McIntosh's bill; Mr. Riley, Mr. Salmon's bill, indeed even the freshmen class has a tax bill. And in our efforts to at least address the marriage tax penalty, we simply raised the deduction to twice that of what it would be for individuals. And one of the complaints of that, we understand, is for those that itemize, they would not then get that targeted tax break; even though 75 percent of the Americans in this country don't itemize. But again, budgetary constraints being such that they are, we're looking at about $4 to $5 billion a year for that simple--and I emphasize simple--solution. Mr. Lifson, I've had several CPAs in my district who have thanked me on behalf of their industry for what we have done with the Taxpayer Relief Act as far as job security and some of the complicating factors. And Mr. Feenberg, this question goes to you because in your testimony you actually began to address, for example, how many additional lines it would be on certain forms because, quite frankly, even beyond the experts in the field, Mr. Lifson, from the CPAs, one of the concerns, slash complaints, I heard from constituents over the holiday was: thanks for the tax relief, but where was the simplification. So taking into account all of the measures here, Mr. Feenberg, are there certain proposals that you have considered that actually do promote simplification? I think in addition to more across the board relief for the American people, we need to look constantly at ways to simplify our present Tax Code. Which of these proposals, Mr. Feenberg, have you looked at that may be better than others as far as simplification. Mr. Feenberg. First of all let me say, the source for the information on how many boxes might be added to the form came from looking at State tax forms that do allow for this. And Iowa was the one I remember that had about 50 additional boxes for that; others were fewer. There is really no way around that kind of complexity, I think, if you allow for some sort of separate filing. With respect to simplification as a way of reducing the marriage tax: Well the 63 phaseouts all go with 63 special provisions and the only way to get simplicity is to look at those provisions and see if you can do without them. We got very good results in terms of deadweight loss per dollar of foregone revenue from a relatively simple thing like the secondary earner's deduction. It doesn't devastate the law, but it's not going in the right direction, obviously, it's a small step in the wrong direction for simplification. Mr. Graetz. Mr. Hulshof. If I could just add---- Mr. Hulshof. Mr. Graetz, yes. Mr. Graetz. Any time you increase the standard deduction, which as I understand it is the way you are approaching this problem, you will move people who otherwise would itemize, on to the standard deduction. And historically, this has been a very sound way of simplifying the tax law. That is, to the extent that more people don't have to keep records, and don't have to itemize their deductions, this does increase simplicity. So, I think on simplicity grounds your suggestion should get high marks. Mr. Hulshof. Any one else? Mr. Bartlett. Mr. Bartlett. I would just say that responding to Chairman Archer's point as he was leaving about targeting, is that I think targeting is a dirty word, contrary to what the President says. I think it has given us all these pernicious problems that we're dealing with here to a very large extent. And I would emphasize what I said earlier that you should look at this whole problem with the obsession with distribution of taxation to the exclusion of every other provision. And that is basically what happened last year, as you know better than I do, is you can't give a tax cut to the rich, so we've got to put in a phaseout, and that creates additional problems and it just multiplies to the point where it becomes utterly absurd. And I would endorse Professor Graetz's proposal that you not produce income distribution tables during the deliberation process. I realize that's probably politically impossible, but I would suggest it anyway. Mr. Hulshof. Well, Mr. Bartlett, let me say as my concluding thought that as a freshman Member in this body and certainly on this Committee, I probably personally have learned more in this past year than any year in my lifetime, other than the year after I got married. And it has been astounding to me in our debate on tax relief that somehow families, married couples who are successful, are demonized to some extent in the political argument and they should not be entitled to the same good policy decisions that those making less, or who aren't quite as successful. And that has been an interesting lesson to learn as a new Member. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back whatever time I have remaining. Mr. Herger. Thank you very much, Mr. Hulshof. And I want to thank our distinguished panel for their testimony. And with that we'll move to our next panel on death taxes. And Congressman Jim McCrery, a Member of our own Committee, will be first to testify. Mr. McCrery. STATEMENT OF HON. JIM MCCRERY, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF LOUISIANA Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. If Chairman Archer were here, I would also thank him for the leadership that he exhibited last year in taking significant steps to lessen the burden of the estate tax, sometimes called the death tax. And while we did some good work last year, I think there is more needed to reduce this unfair tax, especially burdensome, I think, on small businesses and family farms owned by hard working families. And eventually, Mr. Chairman, in my opinion, the estate tax should be abolished. We should not have an estate tax, and I think there are some sound reasons for that conclusion. Number one, as I said earlier, it's unfair. Number two, it discourages savings and investment. It destroys small businesses and family farms. It double taxes income. And, it doesn't provide much revenue to the Federal Government; less than 1 percent of our revenues are derived from this tax. So, it ought to be done away with. But if we decide, for budget scoring reasons, as we did last year, that we cannot abolish the estate tax, then we ought to look at some more tinkering this year that would reduce the burden. And I think there are some ways that we can do that. I want to suggest three ways, and I'll do these in order of priority. Number one, the family business exemption that we created last year should be increased. Simply by increasing that family business, family farm exemption, we do the most in the most efficient way to save family farms and businesses from extinction. Number two, we should consider making the unified credit a true exemption so that the lowest rate of 18 percent applies to the first dollar of value in a person's estate upon which they actually pay the tax. As you know, Mr. Chairman, now because of the unified credit the first tax rate that is applied in a taxable estate is 37 percent, when we have an 18- percent rate on the books. So, that's the second thing that we ought to look at, making that a true exemption. Third, we should consider raising the unified credit. Mr. Chairman, those options are less attractive to me than abolition of the estate tax but, short of a proposal that allows us to abolish the estate tax, I think we ought to look at making adjustments in those three areas. Mr. Chairman, my full testimony is in writing, it has been presented to the Committee, and I would appreciate it submitted for the record. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Jim McCrery, a Representative in Congress from the State of Louisiana Thank you Mr. Chairman for giving me the opportunity again to testify before the Committee on the estate and gift tax. Please also let me congratulate you on the leadership you showed last year in taking significant steps to reduce the burden of this unfair tax. As the author of the H.R. 1299, the Family Business Protection Act, which provided a $1.5 million exemption for family owned business, I am very pleased with the estate tax reduction in the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. Nevertheless, I know that you invited me here today because you understand more is needed to reduce this unfair tax, a tax especially burdensome on small businesses owned by hard working families, and that eventually, it should be eliminated. Mr. Chairman, the death tax should be abolished because it discourages savings and investment, double taxes income, and collects minimal revenue. High estate tax rates serve to discourage savings. While we have several statutory rates for the taxation of estates, the first rate that is actually applied is 37%, then the rates go up to 55%. I doubt that many support rates of such magnitude even on the very wealthy, let alone a small businessperson who has never been guilty of conspicuous consumption, but through sound business practices has managed to build up an estate subject to the federal death tax. The estate tax also has inordinately high compliance costs. Specifically, the National Federation of Independent Business estimated that the government and individuals collectively spend some 65 cents for each dollar of estate and gift tax collected-that's $5 to $6 billion annually-for enforcement and compliance activities. The end result of this process is for the businessperson to spend down their assets in an attempt to avoid the burden of this tax, thus depressing job creation and economic growth. Mr. Chairman, the death tax is unfair because it taxes earnings that have already been subject to federal taxes. After all, business owners already pay income and capital gains taxes, yet when they die, they must pay taxes again. And Mr. Chairman, despite the fact the estate tax only accounts for approximately one percent of federal revenues, eliminating the estate tax would have created salutary effects on the economy. For example, a 1996 study by the Heritage Foundation found that a repeal of the death tax would have positive effects on the American economy over a nine year period. It found that the nation's economy would average as much as $11 billion per year in extra output, an average of 145,000 additional jobs would be created, household income would rise by an average of $12 billion per year above current projections, and revenues would be recovered due to the growth generated by its abolishment. I would hope all of this evidence would lead us to conclude the death tax belongs only one place--six feet under. Due to our scoring system, we decided abolition of the estate tax was too costly in 1997. Should we again make that determination, I believe we should make further modifications to the estate and gift tax. Many people believe only the wealthy pay estate taxes. While the affluent can afford the costs of attorneys and accountants to avoid or minimize the estate tax, the small businessperson cannot. In fact, the Internal Revenue Service reported that of the 69,772 death tax returns filed in 1995, almost 85% were for estates of $2.5 million or less. Since the unified credit has not been indexed beyond 2006, small businesses will continue to find their assets can easily exceed the threshold for taxation. Therefore, please consider the following proposals. First, the family business exemption should be increased. As the value of the unified credit goes up, the value of the family business credit goes down so that the combined credit does not exceed $1.3 million. By 2006, the family exemption will only be $300,000. Considering the devaluation this credit will experience over the course of ten years, many businesses may decide not to incur the costs of applying for the credit and instead continue to spend down their assets in an attempt to avoid the death tax. Increasing this exemption is the best way to save family farms and businesses from extinction. Second, the outdated tax rate structure must be reformed. Mr. Chairman, while I am flexible in seeking these reforms, let me suggest the model set up in my legislation. According to H.R. 1299, the unified credit will be made a true exemption so that the lowest rate of 18% applies to the first dollar of value in a person's estate upon which they actually pay the tax. The rates would then be graduated, as under current law. Lastly, we should consider raising the unified credit. If the unified credit had been indexed since 1986, it would be worth approximately $840,000 today. The unified credit will not reach that level, however, until 2003 and will continue to be undervalued when it reaches $1 million in 2006. In fact, I estimate the credit should be worth somewhere between $1.2-$1.5 million by that time. Thus, while our committee has made great strides to lower the burden of the estate and gift tax, we could do more to make the unified credit consistent with today's dollars. While these options are not as good as abolition, and some could increase complexity, they are preferable to the status quo. Again, thank you for this opportunity to testify. I will be happy to take any questions at the appropriate time. Mr. Herger. Without objection---- Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Herger [continuing]. We'll do that. Thank you, Mr. McCrery. Mr. Cox, your testimony. STATEMENT OF HON. CHRISTOPHER COX, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA Mr. Cox. I thank the Chairman and I thank the Members for focusing needed attention on this important issue. I want to commend you for your leadership in holding these hearings and I welcome the opportunity to talk about the urgent need to repeal the death tax. We did important reform. We ameliorated, to a certain extent, the awful incidence of the death tax in the last Congress, but this tax, perhaps better than any part of the Internal Revenue Code, begs for elimination because tax simplification is all about making the system both fair, understandable on the one hand, and predictable on the other hand. The death tax is none of these things. In one fell swoop, we could get rid of over 80 pages of the Internal Revenue Code, nearly 300 pages of regulations, were we to eliminate it. But every time we change it, what happens in the real world is that small businesses have to call their lawyers, redo their estate plan, and take a look at the whole thing from key man life insurance to the way the business might be carried on in the event of partial liquidation. It actually raises the costs of tax compliance and one of the very, very serious and pernicious aspects of this tax is not highlighted when economists tell us how much money it raises or what the cost of compliance is and that is what it costs people who are not dead or dying to prepare for that eventuality. I just went to Sonny Bono's memorial service, as a lot of you did. He, tragically, met his death earlier than he'd expected, but we're all going to die. All of us, at some time. And so we all have to prepare for this. That's why we know that even the nominal compliance costs, the ones that economists can keep track off, by some estimates amount to 65 cents on every dollar that we collect. So, not only does this tax get us barely 1 percent to start with but then 65 cents out of every dollar is sucked out of the economy or sucked directly out of Federal revenues because that's what it costs to comply with the tax. As you perhaps know, I've introduced legislation in each of the last three Congresses to kill the death tax and I'm proud to say that support has been growing ever since our colleague, Mr. Gephardt, drew attention to this tax by trying actually to increase it. Support has been growing for getting rid of it altogether. The White House Council on Small Business, which the White House itself gathers together, this is not a partisan thing, I hope, but the President of the United States and the White House, which he controls, are the ones that put the thing together. And they've made a list of over 50 important policy steps that they hope the Congress and the President will take together to protect and expand small business in America. Number four on that list is repealing this tax. Ending it, not mending it. Repealing this tax, number four on a list of over 50 that the White House Council on Small Business says is necessary for their survival. Now, some people are going to tell you that the death tax isn't really a death tax, it's an estate tax. In fact, that's what the legal jargon is, the estate and gift tax. That, basically, this is a tax on the rich and its purpose is redistribution of wealth. It is utterly failed in that it does not redistribute wealth from rich to poor. To the contrary, it's one of the main causes of a conglomeration of wealth in America as multinational corporations, in many cases, acquire what used to be small businesses. It's one of the number one killers of small business in America. And, furthermore, the people who pay the tax are not the rich because they can use an estate plan to either put that tax off forever or avoid it altogether. Rather, the people who pay the tax are not even the people who own small businesses or small ranches, although we hear about them a lot. They're the people who work in those operations. The incidence of this tax is greatest, heaviest, and most serious on low-wage workers in small businesses and on family farms and on ranches. And no economic study that I've seen even attempts to quantify what it means to have a 100 percent tax when you lose your job, when you lose your livelihood. But that's what destroying a small business is all about, that's what a property tax masquerading as an income tax is all about, because that's what this is. Liquidity of the business, liquidity of the ranch, liquidity of the farm has nothing to do with whether the tax is owed. And so, given the steep rates and the fact that it's assessed on aftertax savings, aftertax values, almost always there's got to be litigation about the value of those assets which consumes more wealth and requires liquidation on the part of that business and then further liquidation in the end to satisfy the tax. Because the American people understand how pernicious this tax is, because they understand it's not about redistribution of wealth, except to the extent that it's causing small business to go away and big business to get bigger, they've been voting to get rid of it routinely. In our State, Chairman Herger, you know that we repealed this death tax, we repealed our inheritance taxes by an initiative vote of the people. Now, the Los Angeles Times editorialized that this would be an extremely unpopular thing, that this would be protection for the rich, and so on, and you know what the vote was? You know what the vote of the people was? To eliminate the death tax in California? Sixty-five percent. And they didn't just eliminate the death tax. They said you can never bring this ugly thing back without another initiative of the people. Even the legislature can't do it. I'd just like to close with a personal story about a constituent of mine who is an estate tax lawyer. One would think that perhaps the small lobby in favor of this tax would comprise chiefly people who make money from it, estate tax lawyers. Well, one person at least who is an estate tax lawyer doesn't feel that way. And he told me he could find another way to earn a living as a tax lawyer if we were to do the right thing and get rid of this tax. And he recounted to me an example, one of the reasons that he feels this way. Recently, he said, he was finishing the estate planning for one of his clients and, as he said, occasionally sadly happens in his business, that client became fatally ill. So serious was his problem that he had to go to his house and rush to his bedside. His family were all gathered there because it was clear he was slipping and on that man's last day on Earth, he spent two and a half hours with his estate lawyer who had him sign documents. And the lawyer told me that the effect of signing these documents was that the family could avoid that tax. There was no economic effect in real life, just a tax effect. And if he failed to sign the documents, then there would be a big liability and so he spent the time going over these documents with the man while his family sat outside and they missed those last hours with him because of us, because we imposed this horrible death tax. No one of our constituents, no American, should spend his or her last hours on Earth that way. This is an evil, pernicious, counterproductive assault on small business, thrift, savings, hard work and it deserves to die. I thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Christopher Cox, a Representative in Congress from the State of California Chairman Archer, I want to commend you for your leadership in holding these hearings today, and I welcome the opportunity to talk about the urgent need for repeal of the death tax. Mr. Chairman, this tax raises less than 1% of federal receipts. It is not paid by the rich and those who can afford the fancy lawyers and accounts needed to legally avoid the tax. It is paid by the small businessman and the farmer and by those who work for these individuals who pay a 100% tax when they lose their jobs as businesses are liquidated. Having introduced legislation in each of the last three Congresses to kill the death tax, I am proud to report that support has grown as the American people recognize the danger this most unfair tax poses to them and their families. They realize that the death tax is unfair, confiscatory, and contrary to the values of hard work and saving on which this country built its success. In 1993, when I first introduced the Family Heritage Preservation Act, my bill had only 29 co- sponsors in the House and had not been introduced in the Senate. Today, the same legislation is endorsed by 168 members of the House and 30 members of the Senate. As far back as 1982, the voters of California sent this message to their state legislature when they overwhelming supported Proposition 6, which repealed the California state inheritance tax. Nearly 65% of the voters in the most populous state in the nation repealed their state inheritance tax by popular initiative. Proposition 6 not only repealed these onerous taxes, but it stipulated that the state legislature could not reimpose this state death tax unless another popular initiative of the people instructed it to do so. Mr. Chairman, the people in my state could have tried changing the details of the law, they could have raised exemptions or lowered rates, but instead they wisely chose to do away with state death taxes completely. Numerous states like Iowa have followed California's lead, and many other states like Pennsylvania are beginning to follow suit. Foreign nations like Israel, Australia, and Canada, which are not considered to be low-tax nations, have repealed their death taxes due to the social and economic harm they cause. I have received thousands of petitions that represent just a fraction of the millions of Americans who, like Californians in 1982, are fed up with the death tax. Support for repealing the death tax transcends the usual boundaries that often seem to divide us. Democrat and Republican, rich and poor, white and black, people around the county want to kill the death tax. The death tax is not an issue of class warfare or left-leaning versus right-leaning economists--everyone agrees that the death tax seeks to repeal the most basic of human natures, the desire to provide for one's family and loved ones. We are familiar with the concept of a sin tax, a government levy on goods like cigarettes and alcohol. ``If we have to tax something,'' states the logic behind such taxes, ``why not tax behavior that is damaging to society and individuals?'' The death tax is the opposite of a sin tax--it is a virtue tax. Self-professed liberal scholar Edward McCaffrey labelled the death tax as a tax on virtue because it taxes exactly the kinds of behavior we consider to be virtuous and want to encourage: savings, investment, and most importantly, work. After you have worked to put food on the table, clothes on your back and a roof over your head, the most powerful reason to continue to work is to provide for your family and those you care about. You want to work hard to make life easier for your children. Yet the death tax thwarts this basic human instinct. While you may have worked hard, taken risks, built a business, and paid your taxes, you discover that at the end of the line, Uncle Sam stands between you and your loved ones and demands up to 55% of everything you have left. I will leave it to other witnesses here today to testify about the many economic benefits resulting from repeal of the death tax, but I want to take a moment to highlight a few of these, paying particular attention to the erroneous notion that repeal of the death tax will leave the federal government starved of revenue. When we consider the role death taxes play in tax revenues it is important to keep several points in mind: Death taxes collect approximately 1% of federal receipts, and one study suggests that 65 cents on every dollar is lost through enforcement, compliance and other costs. Instead of being confiscated or used to build elaborate legal devices to avoid the tax, this money would be used in an economically beneficial way by private citizens, expanding opportunity for all Americans, and therefore, the tax base for the federal government. The current discussion of the expected ``budget surplus'' indicates that we have achieved a balanced budget. Assuming this trend continues, it would more than offset any initial loss in revenue from death tax repeal. Repeal of the estate tax will lead to increased federal tax collections from income and payroll taxes. According to a Heritage Foundation study, repealing the death tax in 1997 would have resulted in increased annual economic growth by $11 billion, an additional 145,000 new jobs, and increased annual personal income by $8 billion each year. A retrospective study of the economy over the 20-year period from 1971 to 1991 showed that net annual federal revenues would have been $21 billion higher if the death tax had been repealed 20 years ago. Some have suggested that we should again merely modify the death tax instead of repealing it outright. But this won't change the underlying incentives against hard work; it will simply add yet another layer of bureaucracy and regulation to what is already one of the most litigated and contentious areas in the entire tax code. Last year, in testimony before this Committee, one witness testified that this ``mend it, don't end it'' approach to the death tax would actually add $3 billion in new litigation and accounting costs to the current system as families and businesses try to structure their assets to meet the new standards. We have the opportunity to simplify the tax code, to cut an entire section of the law that punishes savings and investment, punishes hard work, breaks up family businesses, and makes the next generation keep trying to climb the same rung of the economic ladder. The death tax is contrary to our principles, it is contrary to sound economic policy, and it should die. I'd like to close with a story that illustrates that the death tax is not merely destructive but immoral. I was talking with a city council representative in one of the cities in my district. The city council is a part-time job, and this man is an estate tax planner and a tax lawyer in his real life outside politics. He came up to me and he thanked me for my efforts to repeal the death tax and shared with me his experience as a tax lawyer. The day before, he said, he spent several hours with one of his clients on his client's deathbed. The man's family was waiting in the next room, but this dying man was forced to give up some of his last hours on earth to sign forms necessary to avoid the death tax. These papers created no new wealth, they were economically useless, except that they allowed this man's family to keep the wealth he had worked for them to have. So this man signed the papers, but he was deprived of some of his last moments with his family. The government got no money. The tax lawyer got paid, and he came to his Congressman and complained that this is not what the government of the United States of America should do to its citizens during their final moments on Earth. I think that in this we must all agree. The death tax deserves to die, and I thank the Committee for providing me this opportunity to testify. Mr. Herger. Thank you very much, Mr. McCrery, and thank you for your work, Mr. Cox. I thank you both for your past legislation in this area of which I've been a cosponsor in the last several Congresses. Mr. Cox, your story reminds me of an example as well. I'm from an agricultural community just north of Sacramento in Northern California and from an agricultural family. And I remember, in my office, not that many years ago, a family came in to talk to me and to discuss their individual situation in which this lady's father, who had farmed in our area and who I knew, grew up with, and knew all my life, explained to me the frugality of their family, which I already knew, and the fact that he had even saved money up and his ranch was debt-free. He had money, a seemingly substantial amount, in the bank to take care of the death tax. Yet, it was not nearly enough, and they were forced to sell this ranch that had been in the family since about the turn of the century. They were forced to sell it just to pay the death taxes. And, as I know you know and I certainly know, this is just one of many examples, not only on farms but on small businesses. No, you're absolutely right, this is a tax that, in my opinion should be done away with. I thank you very much. Yes, Mr. Collins. Mr. Collins. Thank you, Mr. Herger. Mr. Cox, you made a statement there that you know that a lot of family-owned businesses, small businesses are selling their businesses to conglomerates in order to avoid the death tax. Would you go into a little more depth of why? Mr. Cox. As I alluded to, the death tax which can exceed 50 percent, is imposed irrespective of whether there's any money in the business that is closely held or the farm that is closely held or the ranch that is closely held by the person who died. And so, you have to pay the tax somehow and that means you have to sell off whatever you've got. You might need to sell off the assets of the business but you might also need to sell off your house. I mean, the tax does not care whether it's a personal heirloom. Sell it. There is no quarter given by the death tax. Mr. Collins. Yes, maybe I should just give you an opinion that I have as to why this may be occurring. Simply the tax rates themselves. If you wait and die, your estate is going to pay 55 percent, but if you sell, then you pay on the gain of that sale at a much less or a much lower rate. And, too, oftentimes when a business is passed on due to the death of the principal owner, there is a tendency for that small business to fail because of the tax liability. It will exist because of the value of that estate, which often leads, as you say again, to a sale. But also, when the principal owner dies and money has to be borrowed to either pay the tax or to continue the operation of that business once the tax liability is met, it prevents the heirs from having the same financial status that the principal had; interfering with their ability to borrow funds to continue the operation of that business. So, I think that it is often the cause of the sale of a business. I do know that it is occurring and I do know that there are a lot of small businessmen who carry a tremendous amount of life insurance in hopes that they will be able to meet that liability and continue the operation of that business after it is passed to the next generation. I'm one of them. Thank you. Chairman Archer [presiding]. The Chair would advise the remaining Members in the room that we have a vote on and that we have about 3 minutes left to vote so the Committee will stand in recess until after this vote. Hopefully 15 minutes from now or maybe less we will continue with our next panel. Thank you. [Recess.] Mr. Herger [presiding]. We'll now reconvene our next panel on death taxes. First on the panel will be a brother and sister, Christopher Clements and Kimberly Clements, whom we will allow Mr. Hayworth to introduce in just a minute. Also, Richard Forrestel, Jr., Carl B. Loop, Jr., and Harold I. Apolinsky. Mr. Hayworth, would you like to introduce your constituents? Mr. Hayworth. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Ladies and Gentlemen, I'm very pleased to introduce to my colleagues here on the Ways and Means Committee, Christopher and Kimberly Clements of Tucson, Arizona. Chris and Kim are the children of the last William M. ``Bill'' Clements, the owner of Golden Eagle Distributors, a beer wholesaler based in Tucson. Golden Eagle also has several facilities throughout Arizona's sixth district, including Casa Grande, Globe, Holbrook and Flagstaff. Bill Clements died unexpectedly, following a 2-month battle with cancer, and Chris and Kim will share with the Committee their experience with the death tax upon inheriting and keeping Golden Eagle Distributors. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Herger. Thank you, Mr. Hayworth. Kimberly, would you like to begin? STATEMENT OF CHRISTOPHER AND KIMBERLY CLEMENTS, GOLDEN EAGLE DISTRIBUTORS, INC., TUCSON, ARIZONA; ON BEHALF OF THE NATIONAL BEER WHOLESALERS ASSOCIATION Ms. Kimberly Clements. Thank you, Congressman Hayworth and Mr. Chairman. Ladies and Gentlemen of the Committee, it is an honor for my brother, Christopher, and I to be testifying here today on the Federal estate tax. My name is Kimberly Clements and my brother and I are the third generation owners of Golden Eagle Distributors, Inc., headquartered in Tucson, Arizona. Golden Eagle is an Anheuser-Busch beer wholesalership which just celebrated 50 years of doing business in the State. Unfortunately, this anniversary was not shared with the one who was responsible for the company's success. Three years ago, our father, William M. Clements, passed away after a brief but courageous bout with cancer. This left my mother, Virginia, my brother and I the task and responsibility of continuing our father's work in the community as well as in our industry. If there was one thing that Chris and I learned from our father, it was commitment. In 1976, our tiny company with just a handful of employees was faced with a national brewery strike. Dad made a lot of sacrifices, but he never laid off one employee. Now, 22 years later, Chris and I are directly responsible for over 260 employees and their families. Our company has grown substantially because we have continuously reinvested dollars back into the business by building new warehouses, adding to our fleet, developing new departments, and, most of all, hiring more employees. The most significant contributors in Tucson do not come from multinational corporations. They come from independent family businesses; the restaurants, the corner markets. And Golden Eagle is no exception. These businesses know the value of giving back to the community. These businesses know that value of family and its importance in today's society. In a Congress that is deemed profamily, it has not fully recognized the unique nature of the family business. Golden Eagle Distributors is the core of the Clements family. It is what we have rallied around following the death of our father, knowing that the business is the family legacy. When Dad died, there were so many questions that were asked not only to one another, but by our employees and by members of our community. What will happen to Golden Eagle Distributors? Thankfully, our estate plan was barely completed 6 months prior to his death. If we hadn't been prepared, the financial as well as emotional effects on the family and on our community would have been devastating. Mr. Clements. Mr. Chairman, Ladies and Gentlemen of the Committee, this is the real impact of the Federal estate tax. It devastates families, businesses, and communities. The death tax barely comprises 1 percent of all Federal tax revenue yet its overall effect is much more far reaching. My sister and I, quite frankly, are some of the lucky ones. We had a father who saw fit to plan accordingly to protect his family, his employees, and his community from the greed of the government. I say greed because much of our business has been taxed and over taxed already. The motions and moneys families must endure to protect themselves and their businesses from the government are well-documented. Lawyers, accountants, and open- handed insurance representatives are paid thousands of dollars to set up the trusts, the wills, the funds to pay the death tax. Our father was no exception, but at what cost? Certainly, these moneys could have been used more productively and invested back into our business and its employees. Although this Congress saw fit to raise the death tax exemption levels in this year's budget agreement, it did little to calm the fears and concerns of family businesses. In fact, the current legislation that attempts to give added relief to family businesses does not assist the majority of medium to large family businesses. These new laws are a pittance and fail to address the large amounts of capital the majority of family businesses have invested directly in their buildings, their inventories, their employees, capital that almost certainly would not meet the current or future exemption levels. For example, in the coming year, Golden Eagle plans to invest in its Tucson operations well over $1 million in capital and human resource improvements. These expenditures are necessary in order to remain competitive in an already cutthroat business environment. The death tax exemption levels passed by this Congress would not even account for the inventory in our warehouse. However, the more insulting aspect of the death tax is the fact that the Federal Government offers families the privilege to pay the tax in installments over 14 years and charges them interest to do so, essentially taxing an already unfair tax. Our own Arizona Senator, John Kyl, and his esteemed colleague, Congressman Chris Cox, who you heard from today, have the correct approach to the death tax. Do away with it. Indeed, according to a recent article in Insight magazine, if the death tax were eliminated, the U.S. economy would be producing $79.2 billion more in annual output and creating 228,000 more jobs a year. Obviously, eliminating the death tax is not a completely realistic expectation for this Congress. Therefore, Mr. Chairman, we hope that you and your colleague will consider recognizing the unique nature of the family business, and exempt from the death tax those closely held by 50 percent or more of family members. It is time to lift this incredible burden from the families of America. It is time to recognize America's greatest resources: the entrepreneur, the philanthropist, the risk-taker. A family businessowner is all these things and more. We know. We learned from the best. We thank the Chairman and the Committee for the opportunity to share our views on this vital, comprehensive issue and look forward to progressive steps to alleviate this unfair tax on American family businesses. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement and attachments follow. Attachments are being retained in the Committee files.] Statement of Christopher and Kimberly Clements, Golden Eagle Distributors, Inc., Tucson, Arizona; on behalf of the National Beer Wholesalers Association Mr. Chairman, ladies and gentlemen of the Committee, we are very privileged and honored to address you today for not only ourselves, but also for beer wholesalers across the country who belong to the National Beer Wholesalers Association. We hope we will answer some pressing questions regarding the inequity of the death tax. Why should a person build a business in America? Why should a person sacrifice everything to run the risk of having his or her livelihood taken away from his or her family? It seems a silly question, but it is asked more frequently than many people think. This is the dilemma the American entrepreneur faces today--to invest capital in his or her company and community, and risk its future if anything were to befall him or her. The vision of our Founding Fathers was simple enough--that all Americans should reap the fruits of their labor--that the right to life, liberty, and property is sacred and divined by God. Hundreds of thousands of immigrants come to the United States every year fleeing from the tyranny of non-democratic regimes, from poverty, from terrorism. Whatever the reasons, people come with the thought that the United States will give them the inalienable freedoms of life, liberty, and property. Many start families, begin businesses, work hard, and see their lives grow. However, the thought that the government, over time, could take away all that they have built is unconscionable to many immigrants and, indeed, to many Americans who have been here for generations. Today in America, without ``proper planning''--which usually entails the investment of numerous resources in the guise of accountants, lawyers, and wayward insurance salespeople--a family can see their business and livelihood stripped away by the most destructive tax created--the estate tax (or now commonly known as the death tax. The family entrepreneur, who puts his good name and reputation on the line to create jobs and wealth for his loved ones and his community, is one of America's greatest resources. Yet, if this vital resource fails to protect his family from the government to which he provided countless tax revenues and the creation of innumerable jobs, he may find that upon his passing that his family is forced to sell their life's work to pay the government again. The greatest misperception about death taxes is that they only affect the very rich. However, death and taxes do not discriminate. Death taxes are hardest on the small farmer, the independent shopkeeper, the restauranteur, and the beer wholesaler--small business people with families and strong ties to the communities they serve. In fact, a recent study reported that ``nine out of 10 family businesses that failed within three years of the principal owner's death said that trouble paying estate taxes contributed to their companies' demise.'' Mr. Chairman, our family is one of the lucky ones. We had a father who planned properly and who allocated the appropriate resources to make sure his family, his employees, and his community would be well protected. Yet who would have known? Who would have known that during the Christmas of 1994, our father, William M. ``Bill'' Clements, an entrepreneur and philanthropist, would be driving down the street and suddenly be unable to see? Who would have known that subsequent tests and diagnoses would discover cancer throughout his body? Who would have known that two arduous months later he would leave a wife, two children, a business, and a community wondering...? What is next? To understand the answer to this question, we would like to share with the committee how far our family business has come and where it has yet to go. In 1941, our grandfather, Dudley M. Clements, founded All American Distributing Co., which was a wholesale liquor operation in Phoenix, Arizona. Dudley, a banker by trade, was raised in Casa Grande, Arizona. His father, William Preston ``W.P.'' Clements, was a banker and rancher. W.P. also served as mayor of Casa Grande back in the early 1900s. They raised Dudley with a strict work ethic and he survived much of the depression by working in Idaho as head of the new state liquor board, which was formed following the repeal of prohibition. His son, Bill, was born April 29, 1936, in Boise, Idaho. After a brief move to New York City following Bill's birth, Dudley along with wife, Patricia, and son moved to Arizona. Several partners joined to form All American Distributing. One of the more notable partners was the cinema singing cowboy, Gene Autrey. During that time, Arizona was a growing state and business was good. Over the years, All American grew from a small wholesaler with a limited portfolio of products into a large supplier of beers, wines, whiskeys, and scotches. Over time, the business even expanded to several different markets including Casa Grande, Globe, Flagstaff, Holbrook, and Tucson. In 1956, August A. Busch, Jr., Chairman of Anheuser-Busch (A.B.) and affectionately known as ``Gussy,'' called our grandfather to ask a seemingly simple question, but one with extensive implications. Would Dudley handle Budweiser? Our grandfather was skeptical. Back then, Budweiser was a regional brand known primarily in the Midwest and in the East. Schlitz, A-1, and Coors were the big brands in Arizona, with Budweiser merely an afterthought. Nevertheless, several of grandfather's key managers prodded him, and All American began to distribute Budweiser in Tucson, Casa Grande, Globe, and parts of Phoenix. At that time, our father, Bill, was in college at the University of Washington, playing football and majoring in engineering. With all those activities, he had practically no interest in entering the family business. After graduation, a degree in engineering brought many opportunities. In fact, Dad furthered his education and received a Ph.D. in Environmental Engineering from the University of California at Berkeley. He stayed in the San Francisco Bay area and eventually started his own firm. Much of his work involved the military and the National Aeronautical Space Administration (NASA). At one point, he was designing air flow specifications for spacecraft and consulting with the Defense Intelligence Agency (D.I.A.). Government projects began to dry up in 1967, when President Lyndon B. Johnson successfully moved many contracts out of California and into his native state of Texas. Dad was left contemplating his future. As it turned out, back at All American, Anheuser-Busch began to inquire about the status of Dudley's son. A.B. wanted a succession plan for the family. Sensing the long-term stability and profitability in the wholesale business, Dad returned to Phoenix with his new wife, Virginia, and worked alongside his father. He worked hard to learn the wholesale business, which was no easy task since he had no formal experience or training. Moreover, his father was very strict with him, holding him to higher expectations than his other employees. Despite his doctorate, his father expected him to perform even the most menial tasks, like scrubbing floors. But Dad persevered and came to know the business from the ground up. After several years, market pressures finally forced our grandfather to separate the liquor and the Budweiser side of business. Budweiser, along with Anheuser-Busch's other brands, had grown and deserved more attention. Consequently, Dad, Mom, and the two of us moved to Tucson to open the corporate headquarters for our new company. So, in the spring of 1974, Golden Eagle Distributors, an exclusive distributor of Anheuser-Busch products was born. The first few years in Tucson were difficult. Budweiser held a market share of less than 10 percent and, for a while, Golden Eagle destroyed more beer than it sold. In 1976, a national brewery strike nearly crippled the company. Dad dug deep into his own pockets and borrowed to keep the company afloat. He lost nearly 18 months of profits but never laid off one employee. It was this type of commitment to his company that would endear his employees to him for years to come. The strike soon ended and Golden Eagle finally had the freedom to grow. Between 1977 and 1984, Golden Eagle saw incredible change, including the proliferation of new brands like Natural Light and Michelob Light. In 1981, Tucson was the number one test market for a risky excursion in the light beer category, Budweiser Light. With the new growth, our company created new departments and new job opportunities. Golden Eagle added an in-house Marketing Department (one of the first of its kind in the nation). Chain stores began to demand more attention, so Golden Eagle established a National Account Representative position to better serve local buyers. Growth in computer technology mandated the development of an in-house Data Processing Department that continues to change and evolve with the needs of the business. With more employees, human resource management became a priority and our company established a Vice President of Human Resources. Through it all, Dad felt that it was imperative to give back to the community of Tucson and the cities of the surrounding branches for all he had received. He embraced countless community projects and donated his time and money to worthy causes. From Chairman of the United Way, to the Boy Scouts of America, to the Copper Bowl Foundation, to creating the Greater Tucson Economic Council--Bill Clements was a man who could never say ``no'' to anyone who asked for help. In addition, he was politically active and a close friend and confidant to many past and current members of this Congress. Not surprisingly, this legacy of duty to others continues to grow, both in ourselves and in our company. On February 23, 1995, our father died unexpectedly after a brief yet valiant bout with cancer. He was 58. At that time, we were both forced to forgo many training steps we would normally take and assume executive positions in the company. Currently, we are working to be recognized by Anheuser-Busch as Equity and Successor Managers of the company. Luck, and extensive and expensive estate planning, has allowed Golden Eagle Distributors to survive. Indeed, with the unprecedented growth in the business over the past twenty years, we are extremely fortunate that Dad foresaw the need to protect what he had built. Yet at what cost? Thousands of dollars were spent to hire lawyers, accountants, and insurance people to draw up trusts, wills, and accounts to protect the fruits of Dad's labor. Congress making changes to the already complicated tax laws forced Dad to frequently reevaluate our company's plan. Ironically, he finished the final arrangements in our family's estate plan barely six months before his death. Golden Eagle could have better used these ``necessary'' resources in the business for new salespeople, more trucks, better benefits, etc. In other words, we could have reinvested them in people. It was hard work, sacrifice, perseverance, and faith in people that allowed our father to be successful. Dad, however, knew that success in America carried with it a terrible price. We are lucky that all these measures were in place and that our company did not have to be sold to satisfy the I.R.S. Hundreds of jobs would have been lost and countless lives devastated. Thankfully, estate tax planning usually provides for no taxes due when the first spouse dies. However, at the death of the surviving spouse, it becomes very difficult and complicated to keep control of a family business for the next generation due to the heavy burden imposed by death taxes. Today, nearly three years following the death of our father, Golden Eagle is still a growing company forged by a vision of teamwork, fairness, and duty. Golden Eagle is a company of 242 employees across Arizona with annual wages and benefits of $10.3 million. It paid $3.1 million in state luxury taxes and purchased $5.3 million goods and services. Golden Eagle employees participate i funds from the corporation. Our health plan is one of the finest in the industry with employees able to choose almost any doctor they want. All of this viable economic activity takes place in six separate counties statewide--communities that would be severely affected if the company ever had to be sold to satisfy the greed of the federal government. There is a misconception in Washington, D.C., about how family businesses operate. Many government bureaucrats, who have never invested a lifetime in building a future for a family and a community, see family businesses as cash rich and easily able to pay the whopping 55 percent death tax levy. However, the vast majority of families who own a business have capital tied up directly in the operation. Not only in the plant(s) and equipment, but in the lives of its employees. Golden Eagle, for example, has capital tied up in the education of salesman Orlando Iosue's children and in driver Rudy Duarte's new marriage. While tangible items may be easily sold, it is the human capital that is the most precious and the most fragile. We are thankful that this Congress saw fit to pass new laws friendly to family businesses. Many in Congress, to their credit, attempted to alleviate the death tax burden by increasing the exemption levels from $600,000 to $1 million by the year 2006 in the last budget agreement. Unfortunately, these new increases in the unified credit do little for the majority of family businesses. In fact, none of the provisions, including those specifically targeted to family-owned and operated businesses, provide significant help for medium to large family businesses. Moreover, they are very complex to implement for small family-owned businesses. Further, although the current law provides for installments of 14 years to pay off a levied death tax, the government charges interest for this ``privilege.'' Although Congress reduced the rate from four percent to two percent, expecting a family that has paid countless taxes over the life of a business to pay interest to the government when a loved one dies is ridiculous. This interest payment is not even deductible for estate or income tax purposes. Again, an entrepreneur may have a net worth near or upwards of this amount, but most often his capital is tied up in nurturing his business. We think Senator Jon Kyl from Arizona and Congressman Christopher Cox from California have the correct approach to the death tax dilemma--do away with it! Mr. Chairman, we also know that if you had your way, this would be your solution as well. According to a recent Insight magazine article on the nation's growing tax burden, if the death tax were eliminated, ``the U.S. economy would be producing $79.2 billion more in annual output and creating 228,000 more new jobs a year.'' This is growing evidence that the tax revenue gained from the increase in Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and jobs would be enough to offset the elimination of the death tax. Understandably, the thought of completely eliminating the death tax may not be completely realistic for this Congress. Therefore, it is important that Members of Congress continue to recognize the unique nature of the family-owned business and consider exempting from the death tax a family business that is closely held by 50 percent or more by family members. As you know, the current laws provide some help for these types of businesses, but fall well short of eliminating the tax. Mr. Chairman, ladies and gentlemen of the Committee, the death tax is an injustice to American working families who have risked everything to make a business grow and create opportunities for their employees and communities. It is especially unfair to the smallest of businesses for they do not have the resources to set up the trusts, the accounts, and the wills to protect themselves from the death tax. It is time to lift this burden from the hundreds of thousands of family businesses in this country. Let us begin to protect one of America's greatest resources--the entrepreneur, the risk taker, the provider, the community leader, the philanthropist. A family business owner is all these things, and more. We know--we learned from one of the best. Why should a person build a business in America? To perpetuate it. To make it grow. To keep it through the generations. To provide opportunity for its employees and the community. We are committed to sending the message for those who might not have a voice. We hope that other wholesalers and all closely held family businesses would see fit to rally behind this important cause and give it the support it deserves. We thank the Chairman and the Committee members for the opportunity to address this vitally important issue and look forward to progressive steps to alleviate this unfair burden on American family businesses. Mr. Herger Thank you, Mr. Clements. We'll now hear from Richard Forrestel, Jr., treasurer, Cold Spring Construction Co., Akron, New York, on behalf of the Associated General Contractors of America. Mr. Forrestel. STATEMENT OF RICHARD FORRESTEL, JR., TREASURER, COLD SPRING CONSTRUCTION COMPANY, AKRON, NEW YORK, ON BEHALF OF ASSOCIATED GENERAL CONTRACTORS OF AMERICA Mr. Forrestel. Thank you and good afternoon. I am Richard Forrestel, Jr., a CPA and treasurer of Cold Spring Construction Company based in Akron, New York. I would like to thank Chairman Archer and the other Members of this distinguished Committee for the opportunity to discuss the devastating impact of the Federal estate tax, or death tax, on family-owned businesses. I am testifying on behalf of the Associated General Contractors of America, AGC, a national trade association representing more than 33,000 firms, including 7,500 of America's general contracting firms. AGC is the voice of the construction industry. While AGC's membership is diverse, the majority of AGC firms are closely held businesses, like our own. AGC member firms are 94 percent closely held, 81 percent are owned by fewer than four persons, and over 80 percent are small businesses with an average construction project under $5 million. Cold Spring was founded by Grandpa in 1911. We are a closely held, family-owned construction firm that specializes in highway and bridge construction. Our projects range in size from $1 million to $30 million. Dad and his brother, Uncle Tom, both entered the business after serving our country in World War II and worked together until Uncle Tom died in 1977. Dad, our chief executive officer, still remains very active today. In addition, my brother Steve, our president, and my brother Andrew, our vice president, are actively involved in managing the business. We have eight siblings who are not involved in Cold Spring, although each worked for Cold Spring every summer to pay for college, as did 12 of my first cousins. Congress needs to be reminded that Americans are smart people. When faced with an onerous tax like the death tax, family held businesses have been forced to jump through numerous, peculiar, and sometimes ridiculous tax hoops to ensure the livelihood and continuation of their family businesses. I began working for Cold Spring in 1975 and would like to describe some of the estate planning techniques we have employed in our battle to save our family business. Uncle Tom died at the young age of 49 in 1977. At the time, both he and Dad owned half the business. Subsequent to Uncle Tom's death, Dad negotiated with Aunt Jo and bought Uncle Tom's stock in the company. This transaction was completed in 1979. In 1980, Dad found himself with a potentially nasty estate tax problem brewing. Cold Spring did an estate freeze and created a preferred class of stock. In addition, a nonvoting common stock was created. Dad and Mom then began to gift the voting stock to the three of us involved in the business and the nonvoting stock to our eight siblings not involved in the business. Dad and Mom both used their unified credits to expedite the gifting. They brought their 11 children together in 1987 and told them of the gifting program. One of our sisters suggested that we have the option to call their nonvoting stock at some future date. This stock was called in the early nineties. As Dad approached 70, he felt it was necessary to create some immediate liquidity in his estate and the corporation redeemed his preferred stock. In 1980, Cold Spring bought a large life insurance policy on Dad's life. The reason for this purchase was to create liquidity in Dad's estate in the event of his demise. Cold Spring still maintains the policy on Dad along with policies on Steve, Andy, and me. More than $2 million has been paid in life insurance premiums since 1980 on these policies. The primary purpose of these, of course, is to ensure liquidity in our various estates to pay for estate taxes. In addition, Cold Spring has spent more than $2 million since 1980 redeeming stock from various shareholders. Again, these transactions were driven by estate taxes. Cold Spring missed a glorious planning opportunity in 1986 to become an S corporation when it found itself with three classes of stock. Those three classes of stock existed because of estate taxes. Chairman Archer, I have hit the highlights as to the hoops Cold Spring has jumped through to provide for a fourth generation in our family business. We have diverted enormous amounts of capital and management time to this process. We ought to be buying bulldozers and backhoes built in Peoria, Illinois, rather than intangible life insurance policies. We should also be providing long-term security for our employees. I believe the country and our company would be better served had these capital and intellectual diversions not been necessary. I appreciate the efforts made by this Committee in attempting to provide some estate tax relief to family-owned businesses as part of the 1997 Act. However, Congress needs to do much, much more to help the family-owned businesses threatened by the estate tax. AGC ultimately supports repeal. Short of full repeal, AGC supports every effort to reduce the impact of estate taxes on family-owned businesses so that they may survive to the next generation. I urge you to include estate tax repeal or large-scale estate tax relief in any upcoming bill. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Richard Forrestel, Jr., Treasurer, Cold Spring Construction Company, Akron, New York, on behalf of Associated General Contractors of America I am Richard Forrestel, Jr., a CPA and Treasurer of Cold Spring Construction, based in Akron, New York. I would like to thank Chairman Archer and other members of this distinguished Committee for the opportunity to discuss the devastating impact of the federal estate tax, or the death tax as we often refer to it, on family-owned businesses. I am testifying on behalf of the Associated General Contractors of America, a national trade association representing more than 33,000 firms, including 7,500 of America's leading general contracting firms. They are engaged in the construction of the nation's commercial buildings, shopping centers, factories, warehouses, highways, bridges, tunnels, airports, waterworks facilities, waste treatment facilities, dams, water conservation projects, defense facilities, multi-family housing projects, and site preparation/utilities installation for housing developments. While AGC's membership is diverse, the majority of AGC firms are closely-held businesses like my own. AGC member firms are 94% closely-held, 81% are owned by fewer than four persons, and over 80% are small businesses with an average construction project size under $5 million. Please note that the survey data mentioned in my testimony is drawn from the 1997 AGC/Deloitte and Touche Insights in Construction Survey and the 1995 Center for the Study of Taxation Federal Estate Tax Impact Survey. I. What the Death Tax Has Meant to My Family Cold Spring Construction Company was founded by Grandpa in 1911. We are a closely-held, family-owned construction firm that specializes in highway and bridge construction. Our projects range in size from $1 million to $30 million. Dad and his brother, Uncle Tom, both entered the business after serving our country in World War II and worked together until Uncle Tom died in 1977. Dad (C.E.O.) still remains very active in the business today. In addition, my brothers Steve (President) and Andy (Vice President) are actively involved in managing the business today. We have eight siblings who are not involved in Cold Spring, although each worked for Cold Spring every summer to pay for college, as did 12 of my first cousins. Congress needs to be reminded that Americans are smart people. When faced with an onerous tax like the death tax, family-held businesses have been forced to jump through numerous, peculiar, and sometimes ridiculous, tax hoops to ensure the livelihood and continuation of their family businesses. I began working for Cold Spring in 1975 and would like to describe some of the estate tax planning techniques we have employed in our battle to save our family business. Uncle Tom died at the young age of 49, in 1977. At the time, both he and Dad owned 50% of the business. Subsequent to Uncle Tom's death, Dad negotiated with Aunt Jo and bought Uncle Tom's stock in the company. This transaction was completed in 1979. In 1980 Dad found himself with a potentially nasty estate tax problem brewing. Cold Spring did an estate freeze and created a preferred class of stock. In addition, a non-voting common stock was created. Dad and Mom then began to gift the voting stock to the three of us involved in the business and the non-voting stock to our eight siblings not involved in the business. Dad and Mom both used their unified credits to expedite the gifting. They brought their eleven children together in 1987 and told them of the gifting program. One of our sisters suggested that we have the option to ``call'' their non-voting stock at some future date. This stock was called in the early 1990's. As Dad approached 70, he felt it was necessary to create some immediate liquidity in his estate and the corporation redeemed his preferred stock. In 1980 Cold Spring bought a large insurance policy on Dad's life. The reason for this purchase was to create liquidity in Dad's estate in the event of his demise. Cold Spring still maintains that policy on Dad today along with life insurance policies on Steve, Andy, and me. More than $2 million has been paid in insurance premiums since 1980 on these policies--the primary purpose of these is, of course, to ensure liquidity in our various estates to pay for estate taxes. In addition, Cold Spring has also spent more than $2 million since 1980 in redeeming stock from various shareholders. Again, these transactions were driven by estate taxes. Cold Spring missed a glorious planning opportunity in 1986 to become an S Corporation when it found itself with three classes of stock. Those three classes of stock existed because of estate taxes. Chairman Archer, I have hit the highlights as to the hoops Cold Spring has jumped through to provide for a fourth generation in our family business. We have diverted enormous amounts of capital and management time to this process. We ought to be buying bulldozers and backhoes built in Peoria, Illinois rather than wasting capital on intangible life insurance policies. We should also be providing long-term job security for our employees. I believe the country and our company would be better served had these capital and intellectual diversions not been necessary. II. What the Death Tax Means to All Family-Owned Construction Firms The federal estate tax is one of the most onerous obstacles to business continuity and growth. When the owner of a family business dies, his or her estate is subject to federal and state estate taxes. The total value of the estate includes the value of the family business along with other assets such as homes, cash, stocks and bonds. Currently, an estate over $625,000 is subject to the federal estate tax, and an estate over $3 million will be taxed at an astronomical 55% rate. This unfair tax is on top of the income, business, property, sales and capital gains taxes that have been paid on these same assets over a lifetime. This is double taxation of the worst kind. Even the smallest contractor has lifetime capital assets, property, real estate and insurance over $625,000. Most family- owned construction firms invest a significant portion of their after-tax profits in equipment, facilities, and working capital. This is necessary for these firms to increase their net worth, create jobs, and continue to be bonded for larger projects. Accordingly, the burden of the federal estate tax falls squarely on family-owned businesses, such as my own. The result is that many of these family-owned business must be sold, downsized, or liquidated just to pay the estate tax. Please allow me to tell you about several ways that the estate tax impacts small family-owned construction firms-- focusing on business continuity, cost of estate planning, job destruction, and the human toll. Business Continuity It is part of the American Dream to create a prosperous business and to pass that success on to future generations. Business continuity--the passing of years of hard work to the next generation--is a great concern to most family-owned businesses. Unfortunately, more than 70% of family businesses do not succeed to the second generation and 87% do not survive to the third generation. Furthermore, it is estimated that 90% of family businesses that fail shortly after the death of the founder fail because of the estate tax burden placed on family members. This is especially true in the case of capital-intensive industries such as construction. In a recent survey, 62% of AGC's membership said that the federal estate tax would make it significantly more difficult for the business to survive the death of the principle owner. For a business like Cold Spring, the federal estate tax and other tax considerations of passing a business to the next generation are an overwhelming obstacle. Cost of Estate Planning Let me state for the record, I am fortunate as a CPA to have a grasp of the impact of the death tax on our business. However, most of my colleagues in family-owned construction firms do not have an accounting background. More importantly, many construction firms do not have a CFO or in-house accountant. Remember, our goal is to construct buildings, bridges and highways. You can only imagine the frustration I share with my colleagues in the construction industry when we are confronted with the intricacies of the Internal Revenue Code. The current tax code, and particularly the estate tax, is so difficult to understand that most construction firms, notably smaller firms, are forced to hire costly outside accounting and legal advisors for estate planning. Those family-owned businesses that do survive to the next generation have spent thousands, sometimes millions of dollars, on estate planning so they are capable of paying the estate tax. Please note that I said to pay the tax, not to avoid the tax. Of AGC firms involved in estate planning, 63% purchase life insurance, 44% have buy/sell agreements and 29% provide lifetime gifts of stock. Again, allow me to use Cold Spring as a family-owned business example. We spend in excess of $100,000 a year in insurance costs and accounting fees to ensure that we have the capital to pay the estate tax and transfer our business from one generation to the next. These finances are being diverted from useful means that could support firms like mine in becoming more efficient and creating jobs. In fact, it is not unusual for contractors to forgo new equipment, manpower, and technology to plan for estate taxes. This monetary cost is in addition to the valuable time spent by family-owned business owners on estate planning, which would be better spent managing their companies so they are able to better compete in the marketplace. Job Destruction The estate tax not only affects the business owner, but also his or her employees. The Center for the Study of Taxation found that family-owned businesses created 78% of all new jobs in the United States from 1977 to 1990. In fact, AGC's family- owned firms employ on average 40 persons and have created on average 12 new jobs each in the last five years. At Cold Spring we help support 150 families through employment. The estate tax, however, can destroy these jobs because firms are often forced to sell, downsize or liquidate to pay this onerous tax. On average, 46 workers lose their jobs every time a family- owned business closes. Finally, let us not forget the impact that these family-owned businesses have on their immediate community. These family-owned businesses not only offer jobs, but they are also a vital part of every community providing specialized services, supporting local charities, and returning earnings back to the local economy. The Human Toll It has been said that, ``At birth you get a certificate...at marriage you get a license...at death you get a bill.'' That is the human side of the estate tax. Little needs to be said of the immense grief of the passing of a loved one. However, I do not believe that the fear of losing one's business should be any part of mourning the passing of a parent or sibling. Making a decision on the future of a family-owned business includes generations of hopes and dreams of your family, as well as your employees. The estate tax has a toll-- it hits when families are most in turmoil, especially owners of small family-owned businesses. III. Provide Death Tax Relief Now I appreciate the efforts made by this committee in lowering the estate tax as part of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. I also understand that numerous pieces of legislation have been introduced in the 105th Congress that would repeal or reform estate taxes. However, Congress needs to do much more to help the growing number of family-owned businesses facing the estate tax. AGC ultimately supports repeal of the federal estate tax. Short of full repeal, AGC supports every effort to reduce the impact of estate taxes on family-owned businesses so they may survive to the next generation. I urge you to include estate tax repeal or large-scale estate tax rate relief in any upcoming tax bill. This issue continues to loom over employers and their employees on a daily basis. Thank you for the opportunity to speak to you about this important issue. I will be happy to answer any questions. Chairman Archer [presiding]. Thank you, Mr. Forrestel. Let me just quickly interject, before I recognize Mr. Loop, that no, we have not done enough, but we should never forget the dramatic change for improvement rather than disimprovement that occurred after the election in 1994, because prior to that time the issue was, is the exclusion going to be reduced. You may remember that. Mr. Forrestel. Yes, sir. Chairman Archer. Mr. Loop. STATEMENT OF CARL B. LOOP, JR., PRESIDENT, LOOP'S NURSERY AND GREENHOUSES, INC., JACKSONVILLE, FLORIDA; VICE PRESIDENT, AMERICAN FARM BUREAU FEDERATION; AND PRESIDENT, FLORIDA FARM BUREAU FEDERATION Mr. Loop. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Members of the Committee. My name is Carl Loop. I'm president of Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses, Incorporated in Jacksonville, Florida. I serve as president of the Florida Farm Bureau. I'm also vice president of the American Farm Bureau. I'm pleased to be here today to talk about the unfairness of estate taxes and the threat they pose to family farmers and ranchers. Farm bureau's position on estate taxes is straightforward; we recommend their elimination. This issue is so emotionally charged that last year farm bureau members sent more than 70,000 letters to Washington calling for an end to the death taxes. I wrote several of those letters myself because death tax threatens the continuation of my family's livelihood. In 1949, I started a nursery business with a $1,500 loan and a borrowed truck. In the early years, we got by living on my wife's salary from teaching school and everything I earned went back into the business. For 49 years, I worked with my wife and children. We worked hard to build our business into one of the largest wholesale growers of flowering pot plants and tropical foliage in the southeastern United States. My family feels that our operation not only grows a needed product, but makes a positive contribution to our community. We employ over 85 people year round, support community activities, and provide a stable tax base. It's hard for us to understand why the government wants to penalize us for being successful, especially when we've already paid taxes on everything that we've earned. Inflation has increased the value of both our land and equipment to the point that my family would have to sell part of the nursery to pay death taxes. This could prove fatal to our business. Because greenhouses are a single-purpose structure, they don't have a whole lot of market value and the only thing a forced partial sale would accomplish would be to destroy our business viability. My son and daughter would like to continue the family business and I would like to pass it on to them. For the past 5 years, I've been working with attorneys to plan for my death. I purchased life insurance. I recapitalized the business, issued two classes of stock, set up revocable and irrevocable trust agreements, gifted assets, given stock options, and shifted some control of the business. After hours of worry and large attorney fees, I still don't know if my estate plan will serve to save our family business. I guess that won't be known until after my death. It seems to me and my family that Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses is worth much more to our community and the government as an ongoing business compared to the amount of a one-time estate tax payment. If my family is forced out of business by the death tax, the business will close, my family will lose their livelihood, people will lose their jobs, and a community-minded business that pays taxes will be gone. My situation is not unique. As a farm bureau official, I talk with farmers and ranchers across this country and I can tell you that people everywhere are concerned that death taxes will destroy their family businesses. Many don't know how severely they will be impacted because they don't realize how much the value of their property has increased because of inflation. Others understand the consequences but fail to adequately prepare because, first, the law is complicated, second, estate planning is expensive, and third, death is a subject that is difficult for a lot of people to talk about. The Tax Relief Act of 1997 made improvements in the estate tax system by increasing the exemption to $1 million by the year 2006 and creating the $1.3 million family business exemption. We commend Congress for enacting these changes. While they are helpful, most of the benefits are far in the future and the family business exemption has made the estate tax law even more complicated. Farm bureau renews its call for the elimination of estate taxes. Action by Congress is needed to preserve our Nation's family farms and ranches, the jobs they provide, and the contribution they make to their communities. I want to thank the Committee for this opportunity to be here today to explain why farmers and ranchers feel so strongly that death taxes should be eliminated. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Carl B. Loop, Jr., President, Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses, Inc., Jacksonville, Florida; Vice President, American Farm Bureau Federation; and President, Florida Farm Bureau Federation My name is Carl B. Loop, Jr., I am president of Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses, Inc., a wholesale plant nursery operation in Jacksonville, Florida. I serve as President of the Florida Farm Bureau Federation and as Vice President of the American Farm Bureau Federation. Farm Bureau is a general farm organization of 4.7 million member families who produce all commercially marketed commodities produced in this country. Last year's Taxpayer Relief Act made cuts in estate taxes that are helpful to agricultural producers but stopped short of ending death taxes that can destroy a family business. I am pleased to be here today to talk about the unfairness of estate taxes and the threat they pose to family farmers and ranchers. Farm Bureau's position on estate taxes is straightforward. We recommend their elimination. The issue is so emotionally charged that last year Farm Bureau members sent more than 70,000 letters to their representatives and senators calling for an end to death taxes. I wrote several of those letters because death taxes threaten the continuation of my family's livelihood. In 1949, after graduating from the University of Florida, I started my nursery business with a $1500 loan and a borrowed truck. In the early years we got by living on the teacher's salary of my wife, Ruth. Everything that I earned was reinvested in the business. For 49 years I, along with my wife and children, have worked hard to build our business into one of the largest wholesale nursery operations in the southeastern United States. I am proud that my nursery has allowed me to support my family and send my three children, Carol, 42, David, 39, and Jane, 32, to college. David, earned his degree in ornamental horticultural and agriculture economics and now runs the business on a daily basis. Without his involvement I wouldn't have been able to come here today. My youngest daughter, Jane, would also like to come into the business. Loop Nursery and Greenhouses, Inc., grows flowering pot plants and tropical foliage in 350,000 square feet (nine acres) of greenhouses. Also part of the business are warehouses, cold storage and the equipment needed to grow, harvest and market our products. Between 85 and 100 people are employed year- round. My family feels that our operation not only grows a needed product, but makes a positive contribution to our community. In addition to employing 85-plus people, we are a community minded business which provides a stable tax base for city, county, state and federal government. We do not understand why the government wants to penalize us for being successful, especially since we already paid taxes on what we have earned. Inflation has increased the value of both our land and equipment to the point that my family would have to sell part of the nursery to pay death taxes. This could prove fatal to our business because our assets can't be easily liquidated. Because greenhouses are single purpose structures, they don't have much market value and the only thing a forced partial sale would accomplish would be to destroy the viability of our business. My son and daughter want to continue our family business and I would like to pass it on to them. For the last five years, I have been working with attorneys to plan for my death. I have purchased life insurance, recapitalized the business, issued two classes of stock, set up revocable and irrevocable trust agreements, gifted assets, given stock options, and shifted control of the business. After hours of worry and large attorney fees I still don't know if my estate tax plan will save our family business. It seems to me and my family that Loop's Nursery and Greenhouses, Inc., is worth much more to our community and the government as an ongoing business when compared to the amount of a one-time estate tax payment. If my family is forced out of business by death taxes everything that I have worked for will be lost, my family will lose its livelihood, 85-plus families will lose their incomes and the community will lose a valuable part of its business base. My situation is not unique. As vice president of the American Farm Bureau, I talk with farmers and ranchers from across the country and I can tell you that people everywhere are concerned that death taxes will destroy their family businesses. Many don't know how severely they will be impacted because they don't realize how much their property has increased in value due to inflation. Others understand the consequences but fail to adequately prepare because the law is complicated, because lawyers, accountants and life insurance are expensive and because death is a difficult subject. It bothers me and my family that while death taxes can cost farm and ranch families their businesses and cost them hundreds of hours and thousands of dollars for estate planning, relatively little revenue is generated for the federal government. The estate tax raised a total of about $17.2 billion in fiscal year 1996, as reported by the Office of Management and Budget. The potential impact of estate taxes on the future of American agriculture is enormous. Ninety-nine percent of U.S. farms are owned by individuals, family partnerships or family corporations. About half of farm and ranch operators are 55 years or older and are approaching the time when they will transfer their farms and ranches to their children. The situation in my state of Florida is acute. The value of farmland there has been inflated far beyond its worth for agriculture because developers are willing to pay high prices to convert farmland to other uses. It is not uncommon for land to be valued at as much as $10,000 an acre. On paper this makes a Florida farmer look like a wealthy person, but my farm neighbors aren't rich. They simply don't have the money to pay a huge estate tax bill without selling part or all of their business. While estate tax planning can protect some of the farms, it is costly and takes resources that could be better used to upgrade and expand their businesses. The Tax Relief Act of 1997 made improvements in the estate tax system by increasing the per person exemption to $1 million by 2006 and creating the $1.3 million family business exemption. We commend Congress for enacting these changes. While they are helpful, most of the benefits are far in the future and the family business exemption has made the estate tax law even more complex. Farm Bureau renews its call for the elimination of estate taxes. Action by Congress is needed to preserve our nation's family farms and ranches, the jobs they provide and the contribution they make to their communities. Until repeal of estate taxes can be accomplished, Farm Bureau urges increasing the estate tax exemption to $5 million per person, indexing the exemption for inflation and cutting the tax rate for assets above the threshold by half. Special-use valuation should be expanded, an estate tax exemption for protected farmland should be put in place and the annual gift tax exemption should be increased to $50,000. Thank you for the opportunity to be here today to explain why farmers and ranchers feel so strongly that death taxes should be eliminated. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Loop, and finally, a gentleman who is no stranger to our Committee and a gentleman who I greatly respect, who is one of the Nation's outstanding experts on the death tax and all of its details and complexities, Mr. Harold Apolinsky. STATEMENT OF HAROLD I. APOLINSKY, GENERAL COUNSEL, AMERICAN FAMILY BUSINESS INSTITUTE, AND VICE PRESIDENT, LEGISLATION, AND PAST CHAIR, SMALL BUSINESS COUNCIL OF AMERICA Mr. Apolinsky. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is a privilege to be with these members on these panels. These stories to me of family businesses are just absolutely chilling. Mr. Loop is correct when he says that the majority of people, I think maybe 80 percent of the people in this country who will be impacted by this 55 percent death tax, do not really know it. Unless you hire me or somebody else as an estate tax lawyer or sell life insurance, it just does not occur to you. We all get a dose of income tax every April but we do not get a dose of death tax until someone dies. As you say, I am an estate tax lawyer. I have been doing this for 36 years. I have been teaching estate planning at both the University of Alabama School and Law and Cumberland School of Law for 26 years. I flew up this morning and go back this evening. I feel privileged, on behalf of the American Family Business Institute and the Small Business Council of America, to share ideas with this Committee for your important work. In my firm, we have 110 lawyers in Alabama. We believe that is enough lawyers to solve any problem or cause any problem, depending on what the client really would like to hire us to do. We have nine full-time trust and estate lawyers and yet we all agree that this death tax needs to be repealed. Even though it would impact our practices, we will find something productive to do. We have seen how harmful it is to family businesses, family farms, family capital to want to get rid of it. It is relatively easy to calculate the death tax. Most people, as Mr. Loop says, have not. You simply add up the fair market value, of everything a person owns; qualified retirement plans, life insurance, even tax exempt bonds are not exempt from the 55 percent death tax. You subtract liabilities, you subtract $1 million, and then multiply by 50 percent. That's a little conservative because the top rate, as you know, is 55 percent. If you have a large qualified retirement plan, you basically pay 75 percent in tax, both income and estate, and so the children get 25 cents on the dollar. Thank you for repealing the 15 percent extra excise tax on retirement accounts because when that hit, only 10 percent went to the children. But I still think a 75 percent tax on qualified retirement plans is unreasonable. And then, if parents decide they want to leave assets to grandchildren, there may be an extra 55 percent generation- skipping tax. I am blessed with two grandchildren. One is seven and one is four. I understand why they are called grandchildren because they really are grand. But if you want to leave the grandchildren a significant amount, I'm widowed, let's say more than $1 million, there's an extra 55 percent generation- skipping tax on top of the 55 percent estate tax on what goes to grandchildren. So, it is really confiscatory. I am grateful that your Committee encouraged Congress to increase the tax-free amount from $600,000 to, this year, $625,000. It moves up in rather odd increments, I must admit. It is good that you do not build stairs in houses or people would fall down because it is so unusual and uneven. It would be easier if it went up equally but I understand the budget problems. I tell my clients that, the tax-free amount will be $1 million in 2006 so please live as long as you can, which seems to please them. Unfortunately, if you have a qualified family- owned business interest, you really need to die early. You have described the Code, and I agree, Mr. Chairman, as a lawyer in your past life, as an attractive nuisance. In my judgment, 2033 A, the Qualified Family Owned Business Exclusion, is an unattractive nuisance. Both the American College of Trust and Estate Counsel, ACTEC, senior estate planning lawyers, I am a member, and the Real Property and Probate section of the American Bar Association have asked that this provision be repealed. In the most recent issue of Trusts and Estates, the writer described 2033 A as one of the most ambiguous and complicated tax provisions to be passed in decades. So help me, this is true. There is even a web page now on the Internet on 2033 A. I have given the Committee my exhibit C to my testimony as a tool to try and understand 2033A. As Professor Graetz said, I, too, am apprehensive as I kick off my estate planning class this spring as to whether the law seniors can understand this Code section. I warned them that they may go through the entire semester and then I will be so happy if I get the estate tax repealed. I promised all 56 of them an A but they will get no tuition rebate. I determined if a business fits under 2033A, you have to master a fraction with 14 variables. It is simply so complex. With dynamic scoring the cost of repeal will drop dramatically. Please put this as number one because this is the one thing, as the Clements family mentioned, that you cannot program. You just do not know when death is going to strike. You can program a lot of other things, but this one, I would say, we ought to try to put first. If we repeal the death tax, obviously the inherited step-up in bases would logically go away. Income tax will be collected when assets are sold. It should not bother anybody because if you are going to sell something, you know the price, so we can stop litigating values. You also expect to pay a tax when you sell something. We do not have to worry about the profit on a home anymore. If you still find you do not have enough money, repeal 2033A. It will not harm the lawyers because we really have not picked up all the legal fees yet that are out there that we will when we explain and investigate 2033A. Remove the death tax from qualified retirement plans. And, number three, reduce the top rate. I do not think of this as a prowealth situation. As the panel described it, I think it is profamily and projobs. I believe the American people will endorse that. Sixty Plus, a great organization started us down this road of repeal. We are grateful to Roger Zion and his team and Jim Martin. They did a poll recently of the American people and 77 percent of them said that they would rather vote for a Member of Congress who repealed the death tax, as for someone who would not. That 77 percent wanted that death tax repealed. I have attached as exhibit D, a list of 15 states that have repealed their State death taxes since 1980, 15 of them. They took an exit poll in California and people said it was not fair to tax during life and at death. It was a fairness issue in California and elsewhere. Indiana is going to repeal, I believe, this year, and Kansas will repeal as well. H.R. 902 in the House, Representative Cox's bill, now has 166 cosponsors to repeal. Senator Kyl now has 30. Please strike a blow for fairness and simplicities and families. Put me and my colleagues out of work. Repeal the death tax. It would be one of the most wonderful things we could do. We should, in my personal view, repeal the Internal Revenue Code but I think that may come a little bit later. I would like to get rid of the death tax first. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of Harold I. Apolinsky, General Counsel, American Family Business Institute; and Vice President, Legislation, and Past Chair, Small Business Council of America Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, I am Harold I. Apolinsky, General Counsel of the American Family Business Institute and Past Chair of the Small Business Council of America (SBCA) and currently Vice President--Legislation. I am also a practicing tax attorney (over 30 years) who specializes in estate planning and probate. For over 25 years, I have taught estate planning and estate, gift and generation-skipping taxation as my avocation to law school seniors at both the University of Alabama School of Law in Tuscaloosa, Alabama and the Cumberland School of Law in Birmingham, Alabama. I am here to present our views on the unfairness of the estate, gift and generation-skipping taxes. The American Family Business Institute is a year old non- profit organization. Our members are family businesses employing over 5,000 employees throughout the United States facing forced sale or liquidation because of this 55% death tax. Our mission is to educate and alert family business owners regarding the death tax and to seek its repeal by Congress. We hope you will put us out of business this year. SBCA is a national nonprofit organization which represents the interests of privately-held and family-owned businesses on federal tax, health care and employee benefit matters. The SBCA, through its members, represents well over 20,000 enterprises in retail, manufacturing and service industries, which enterprises represent or sponsor over two hundred thousand qualified retirement and welfare plans, and employ over 1,500,000 employees. We are delighted and heartened by the overwhelming response that this issue has evoked from Members of Congress and their staffs. It is indeed refreshing to observe the level of understanding and commitment that individual Members have demonstrated. The existence and harm of the 55% death tax is not generally known other than to estate tax lawyers and families who have suffered the loss of a loved one owning more than the applicable exclusion amount, now $625,000. Thank you for the increase in this tax-free amount. I advise my clients to try and live to 2006, but die early if they own a qualified family business. Unfortunately, neither this nor the unworkable 2033A Family-Owned Business Exclusion will save 90% of family businesses. We submit that the time has come for Congress to repeal the estate, gift and generation-skipping taxes. It is unfair to tax people all their working lives and then again at death. An estate tax due nine months after death is imposed on the transfer to children or other heirs of the taxable estate of every decedent who is a citizen or resident of the United States ($625,000 of assets are now exempt). The graduated estate tax rates begin effectively at 37% and increase to a maximum rate of 55% (see Exhibit ``A'' for how the tax is calculated). Taxes on bequests to spouses may be deferred until the last-to-die of husband and wife. A gift tax is levied on taxable gifts (excluding $10,000 per donee per year) as a back-stop to the estate taxes. The graduated rates are the same. (The current $625,000 exempt amount may be used during life for gifts or at death.) An extra, flat 55% generation-skipping tax is imposed on gifts or bequests to grandchildren ($1,000,000 is now exempt). Combined income and estate taxes frequently consume 75% or better of retirement plan accounts at death (see chart attached as Exhibit ``B''). Thank you also for repealing the 15% excise tax. With that, only10% would go to children. The 1995 White House Conference on Small Business recommended repeal of estate and gift taxes. In fact, ranked by votes, this was the number four (out of sixty) recommendation to come out of the Conference. It is well known that only 30% of family business and farms make it through the second generation. Seventy percent (70%) do not. Only 13% make it through the third generation. Eighty- seven (87%) do not. The primary cause of the demise of family businesses and farms, after the death of the founder and the founder's spouse, is the 55% estate tax. It is hard for the successful business to afford enough life insurance. (Premiums are not deductible and deplete working capital.) The new Qualified Family-Owned Business Interest Exclusion (QFOBI) is now the most complex provision in the Tax Code. At best, it will help less than 5% of family businesses facing sale or liquidation from the death tax. Just look at Exhibit ``C'' which I use to try and teach 2033A. It may make you laugh. Both the American College of Trust and Estate Counsel (to which I belong) and the Real Property and Probate Division of the American Bar Association have urged repeal. In an article in the January 1998 issue of Trusts & Estates the author referred to 2033A as ``one of the most ambiguous and complicated tax provisions to be passed in decades.'' The estate tax took its present form primarily in the early 30's. The express purpose was to ``break-up wealth.'' Is this consistent with a free enterprise economic system and a very competitive world economy? The 55% estate and gift tax cannot be justified as playing an important role in financing the federal government; it now brings in less than 1.2 percent of total federal revenues. The expense of administering this system probably offset 75% or more of the revenue. Since the step-up in basis will also be repealed, resulting in tax when assets are sold by heirs, the net loss of revenue will be modest. Since 1980, 15 states have repealed their state death tax (see Exhibit ``D''). California voters approved Proposition 6 in 1982 to repeal the California death tax. Exit polls determined that voters, even in this state with such a wide disparity between rich and poor, did not feel it fair to pay taxes during life and at death. The fair approach is to repeal the death tax in 1998. As I have testified before, if the estate tax were repealed, we believe based upon studies conducted by Professor Richard Wagner of George Mason University, by the Heritage Foundation and by Kennesaw State College that the beneficial effect on the economy would be significant. According to the study conducted by Professor Richard Wagner of George Mason University, the effect of the estate tax on the cost of capital is so great that within eight years, a U.S. economy without an estate tax would be producing $80 billion more in annual output and would have created 250,000 additional jobs and a $640 billion larger capital stock. The Heritage Foundation study utilizing two leading econometric models also found that repealing the estate tax would have a beneficial effect on the economy. The Heritage analysis found that if the tax were repealed in 1996, over the next nine years: The nation's economy would average as much as $11 billion per year in extra output; An average of 145,000 additional new jobs could be created; Personal income could rise by an average of $8 billion per year above current projections; and The deficit actually would decline, since revenues generated by extra growth would more than compensate for the meager revenues currently raised by the inefficient estate tax. We submit if repealing estate taxes accomplished only half of these things, the country would be significantly better off than staying under the current draconian estate tax system. The estate tax system raises very little revenue at a heavy cost to the economy. It generates complex tax avoidance schemes, it promotes spending instead of saving and it promotes people ``giving up'' on the family business or farm. It helps my estate tax lawyers (now 9 in my 110 lawyer firm), but is not fair to families or good for my country. The Kennesaw State College Study on the Impact of the Federal Estate Tax, prepared by Astrachan and Aronoff, studied in detail the impact of the estate tax on members of the Associated Equipment Distributors (AED), an association composed of capital-intensive family-owned distribution businesses and on newly-emerging, minority-owned family enterprises selected from lists published by Black Enterprise Magazine. The study showed that for the AED group: Nearly $5 million is spent annually in life insurance premiums in order to have proceeds available to meet their estate tax liability. The survey shows an average of $27,000 per year expended by distributors on such insurance. $6.6 million has been spent on lawyers, accountants and other advisors for estate tax planning purposes. On average companies spent nearly: $20,000 in legal fees $11,900 in accounting fees $11,200 for other advisors In addition to the protection provided by life insurance premiums, roughly 12% of the AED respondents reserved over $51 million in liquid assets for the purpose of having cash available for the payment of the estate tax. The study showed that 57% of the businesses felt that the imposition of the estate tax would make long term survival of the business after the death of the current owner significantly more difficult. They are not wrong--the statistics show it is extraordinarily difficult to have the family business survive the death of the first generation. Working capital to a business is like fuel to an airplane. When you run out of fuel, the plane comes down whether at an airport or not. Removing 55% of the value of a family business often removes more than 55% of the working capital. Australia repealed their estate and gift tax laws in the mid-1970's. It was felt that these transfer taxes were an inhibitor on the growth of family businesses. The legislative body of Australia sought more jobs which they believed would come if family businesses grew larger and were not caused to sell, downsize, or liquidate at the death of the founder to pay estate taxes. More recently, Canada has also repealed estate taxes for the same reasons. The SBCA has a legal and advisory board comprised of the top legal, accounting, insurance, pension and actuarial advisors to small business in the country. It is contrary to the financial interests of these board members in their tax practice and advisory businesses to urge repeal of these transfer taxes. We stand firmly behind repeal or significant reform, however, because it is the right thing to do to help grow family businesses, provide jobs and encourage the entrepreneurial spirit needed for small businesses to become large businesses. We applaud the bills introduced by Congressman Cox (HR 902 now with 166 co-sponsors) AND Senators Kyl (S-75 now with 30 co-sponsors) and Lugar (S-30) to repeal these taxes. The country will be far better off if any of them become law. As a country, we cannot stand by and see one more farm or one more small business get torn apart because of an obsolete tax supposedly in place to redistribute massive wealth. Part of the problem with estate taxes is that many of the families who are ultimately destroyed by the estate tax are not even aware that it exists. Many times no one in the family has ever been subjected to it. The 55% death tax (the highest in the world) does the most harm to capital of any tax we have. Once it leaves the family at death and goes to Washington, it never seems to come back to provide jobs back home. It is simply not fair! [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.078 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.079 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.080 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.081 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Apolinsky. Let me piggy- back momentarily on what Mr. Loop said. I believe it's accurate to say that we did not increase the complexities in the Code relative to the small business exemption but we did not simplify them. We left in place the complexities that were already in the Code. Is that a fair statement, Mr. Apolinsky? Mr. Apolinsky. Mr. Chairman, I am afraid we did add to the complexity. I am afraid that 2033 A is an additional complexity because it incorporates 14 provisions from 2032 A. I realize it is elective, which is useful. But, from an estate planner's perspective, we feel the necessity to contact all of our family business clients, explain the law to them, have them engage us to check it out, make any required changes and, document material participation. So, this is an additional burden, and expense to family businesses. I worry that only about 2 to 5 percent of family businesses will really qualify. But I think every family business needs to take a look at it to see if they can, ultimately, qualify because it may save $400,000 or $500,000 in tax. Chairman Archer. My understanding, though, and you certainly have been one of my educators on this over the last several years, is that the existing definition of small business or farm in the Code before the 1997 act was already so very complex that it, in itself, limited the practical application to a very small percentage of people who thought they probably qualified. Is that a fair statement? Mr. Apolinsky. Mr. Chairman, that is a fair statement. As you remember better than I, in 1976, Congress wanted to save the family farm, a great idea. Congress passed 2032A. It is 11 pages of statute. It has now been challenged constantly in court. There have been 138 court decisions to date. About two- thirds were won by the Internal Revenue Service. This is probably at least an equal number in the pipeline. You are exactly right. And then, you know, I realize, it was not the House, in my judgment authorized 2033A. It came out of the Senate. I tried to start teaching this in 1995 when it was the Dole-Roth. Chairman Archer. That is a correct thing to say in this room, Mr. Apolinsky. Thank you very much. [Laughter.] Mr. Apolinsky. I hope no Senators are here. [Laughter.] Chairman Archer. Let me comment just briefly on a couple of things. I read an article recently where a financial counselor was telling his clients, you should not have an IRA, you should not have a tax-deductible retirement plan because in the end the taxes are so brutal at the time of your death that it is far better to do something else. Now, what a terrible thing to have to say to the American public. It is terrible to tell people if they get married, they're going to pay more taxes. It is also terrible to tell them if they put aside for their own retirement, it's a mistake because of the Tax Code. I don't think the Members of Congress understand that the savings that the law permits, and our salaries, which go into a thrift savings account for our retirement, will be taxed at unbelievably high rates at the time of death. As you've pointed out, that applies to all tax-deductible savings accounts, so much so that you end up, if you leave funds in that account and you die prematurely, before you actuarially have been able to pull out the amount there in your lifetime, what you leave to your children gives them roughly 25 percent. That is highway robbery and I appreciate your suggestion that if we don't do anything else, we should change that, well, you've said many other things, but as a part of it, that we should change that provision in the Code. Now, let me ask you if you have any data for us as to the net revenues that the death tax provides to the Federal Government, because I've read articles that say that the cost of collecting it and the loss of other revenues, through other tax programs, actually is virtually an offset to where it produces no net income to the Federal Government. Do you have any data on that at all? Mr. Apolinsky. One of the members of the next panel, Bill Beach, has worked with a group that I have assisted from a technical standpoint to try and do a study of what would be the revenue from a combination where you repeal the death tax, factor in the expenses, and, although I have not seen their final study, factor in some income from sales by heirs selling--using a carryover basis. Chairman Archer. Good. Mr. Apolinsky. But, my impression, everything I have seen, supports the concept that roughly 65 percent of the dollar goes into the cost of collecting. Then, if you factor in the revenue that will come from the sale by heirs from that, I think it would be a question whether it is 2 or 3 or 4 years before it becomes positive revenue. More revenue will flow if family businessowners spend time with their marketing people, their manufacturing people, and less time with their tax lawyers. As much fun as I enjoy being with them and I love being paid by them. I have one client in Birmingham, Alabama, a little town, that is paying $2 million a year in life insurance premium to try to keep a family bottling company in the family through the third generation. His expansion has just stopped. I told him, I said, Jimmy, let me tell you what I'm working on, to repeal. Would it mean anything to your company if I got the tax repealed? His eyes got wide. He said, Harold, I'll promise you I will build a bronze statue to you at Legion Field, which is our football stadium. People will walk by and say, who's that old man in the houndstooth hat, because we have Bear Bryant's statue there. They'll say, I don't know him but I know that's Harold Apolinsky. He got the estate tax repealed. [Laughter.] Chairman Archer. That's a great story. Now, in a socialist or communist country, I could understand it, but it defies me that in a free-enterprise country that has built the finest life, economically, for any people in the history of the world, not without its faults, but nevertheless in a relative sense, the finest life for the people who are its citizens of any country in the history of the world, that we would say to people in the later years of their life, if you continue to work and to produce and to expand the wealth of this country, you will be losing because all that you can ever leave to kids out of that will be 25 percent. That the government will get 75 percent because at 44 percent income tax that comes off the top and then another 55 percent of the 56 percent that is left leaves you with 25 percent. What incentive is there for people to continue to produce and to build more for everybody in this country, jobs, and so forth? And, clearly, it is wrong and we should do something about it. Let me stop there and recognize my colleagues for any inquiry they might like to make. First, Mr. Hulshof. Mr. Hulshof. Thanks, Mr. Chairman. Ms. Clements, Mr. Clements, I hope that America hears your story and I'm confident that your father is probably looking down and smiling because he knows that the lessons he taught you you have learned well. As the only son of a Missouri farm family, I know firsthand your plight. First of all, we welcome you here to Washington, DC. We have to continue to tell this story back home and I hope you go back to Arizona and continue to talk about your story because of the incredible battle we have ahead of us. Just a few short months ago, a high-ranking official in this White House made the public pronouncement that those of us who seek to change the death tax laws are committing the ultimate act of selfishness. A high-ranking Congressman from my State of Missouri, who once sat on this Committee when his party was in the majority, has tried in the past to lower the exemption so that more family businesses and more family farms, Mr. Loop, are subject to paying the tax in an effort to satisfy the government's insatiable appetite for more taxes. And so, when we have those on the other side that are fighting the efforts to repeal and do away with the death tax, we have formidable foes but I think if your story and stories that each of you have told, if we can talk back home in our congressional districts and tell those stories, then I believe the best policy will come out. And, quite frankly, Ms. Clements, I thought your testimony hit the nail squarely on the head in that the vision of our Founding Fathers was very simple. And that is, all Americans should be able to reap from the fruits of their labors. And that's the right of life and the liberty and property and that is a sacred right and we should be able to pass on the fruits of our labors to those who follow us and that, in essence, is the American dream. So, please continue to tell your story because my personal opinion is a simple one and that is that the death of a family member should not be a taxable event, period. So, we welcome you here but please help us continue to fight this fight. And I appreciate the time, Mr. Chairman, and yield back. Ms. Clements. Thank you. Mr. Clements. Thank you, very much. Chairman Archer. Mr. Hayworth. Mr. Hayworth. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I'd like to thank all members of the panel and, of course, I'm especially pleased to have Chris and Kim Clements here from Tucson. I would echo the comments of my colleague from Missouri and point out the irony. We saw it again last night in the State of the Union Address, to have one side of the chamber rise in enthusiastic applause for the largest tax increase in American history, which I thought was extremely telling, and, from the Chief Executive, this rather unique modern revisionism less than 5 years after the fact. Be that as it may, Chris and Kim, in a town not very far from one of your facilities, you have one in Holbrook, over in Winslow, Arizona we had a townhall meeting a couple of months ago. I think it ties into what Mr. Apolinsky said. Many concerned citizens came by there. We had the townhall there in the council chambers. Two young men, in particular, who hope to go to military academies had received permission to leave their class and come to the townhall. And we were talking with small business owners, with seniors, about the scourge of the death tax and one of the young men, so earnest as a high school junior or senior, stood up, Congressman, sir, do you mean to tell me the government taxes you upon your death? And the knowing laughter, almost a variation of Art Linkletter's ``Kids Say the Darndest Things,'' was incredible, but all too often that laughter is to keep from crying because we are talking about our tax policy in the realm of the absurd. Chris, I have no compulsion to try to dredge up emotional times for you and Kim, but so often people are accused of putting on the green eyeshade and looking at the bottom line, all of that. Can you take us back to that trying time immediately following your father's death? Both emotionally and financially. Is there any way to encapsulate the challenges you faced immediately, even following the plan that your father had instituted? If you had to sum it up, what was the greatest challenge in the wake of all that and dealing with this notion of the death tax, Chris? Mr. Clements. The greatest challenge. Well, I think the greatest challenge in this regard is really comforting our employees, comforting our mother who had no experience in the business other than being the wife of our father, and assuring everyone that, indeed, the business would go on, that we would attempt to perpetuate it the best we could. Kimberly touched on the vast outpouring of affection in terms of questions and what we received not only from our employees but also our community. We have a company that is very active in our community and in many of the communities around the State. And the questions came from them much more, in terms of will the business be sold, do you have to pay a large levy. And people were rather educated about it and, because we give so much back, they were wondering exactly what would happen to us. Congressman Cox hit right on the head with his tale today about the gentleman who was on his deathbed and preparing his estate. Kimberly motioned to me and said, well, that sounds really familiar because our mother was doing the same sort of things because our father was virtually incapacitated. She was making sure everything was OK, that the business would not have to be sold, and it's interesting because now we're engaged in evaluating the life of our mother. How long will she live? When she dies, what would the business be worth then? At that time, how much insurance will we need to provide for ourselves in order to pay the government? That's a very interesting task because we're not tax lawyers and we certainly don't understand all of it. All we understand is that our father is gone, and that we have a responsibility to our employees and our community to continue what he had started. That's the only thing we've ever understood. Mr. Hayworth. Chris, thank you very much. Mr. Forrestel, as the treasurer of your family business, you left us with a very intriguing statement. We won't ask you to inventory it right now but you talked about the amazing possibilities that existed for your business if that money weren't taken out to deal with this type of planning. Mr. Loop, I thought one particular observation you had was especially germane: why should you be punished for succeeding and living the American dream. And, just in conclusion, Mr. Apolinsky, ``J.D.'' in my name does not stand for juris doctor. I'm not an attorney, I've never played one on television. But, I do find it encouraging that you and your brethren in the legal profession are perfectly willing to take on other work and, in conclusion, Mr. Chairman, I'd just simply like to echo the words of our dear colleague from Colorado, Bob Schaffer, who makes the point that he believes there should be no taxation without respiration. I thank you and yield back. Chairman Archer. Gentlemen and ladies, thank you very much for all of your testimony. We appreciate your coming and giving us the benefit of it. You're excused and we will go to the next panel, the next and final panel. Douglas Stinson, Jeannine Mizell, Roger Hannay, and William Beach, if you'll please come to the witness table. Welcome to each of you to the Committee. Thank you for coming today. Mr. Stinson, would you lead off, and give us the benefit of your testimony, and I think since you've been in the audience you know the general procedures here that we'd like for you to limit oral testimony to 5 minutes or less, and your entire written statement, without objection, will be printed in the record. You may proceed. Mr. Stinson? Yes, sir, and if you'll identify yourself for the record. STATEMENT OF DOUGLAS P. STINSON, OWNER, COWLITZ RIDGE TREE FARM, TOLEDO, WASHINGTON, ON BEHALF OF FOREST INDUSTRIES COUNCIL ON TAXATION, AMERICAN FOREST & PAPER ASSOCIATION, AMERICAN TREE FARM SYSTEM, AND WASHINGTON FARM FORESTRY ASSOCIATION Mr. Stinson. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My name is Doug Stinson, and I'm a tree farmer from the State of Washington. My wife and our three children own the Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm which consists of four parcels of forest land totaling 1,000 acres near Toledo, Washington. I'm here today to represent the American Tree Farm System, a national network of 70,000 private forest landowners committed to protecting water, wildlife, soil and recreation and at the same time to grow trees for forest products. We are committed to sustainable forestry. Tree farmers are private citizens from all walks of life who take great pride in practicing forest stewardship on their land, and I'm proud to be speaking on their behalf. In addition, I'm proud to be speaking for the Forest Industries Council on Taxation, the American Forest and Paper Association, and the Washington Farm and Forest Association. Two years ago, I sat before this Committee and told you about the disincentives built into the Federal Tax Code that discourage people from being good forest stewards, specifically, the capital gains tax and the estate tax provisions. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 went a long way toward remedying these problems, and I commend you for your actions and your support for American forests, but to ensure the long term health of American private forests which make up 58 percent of our total forest land, we must go further. Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm has four goals: first, to earn a living; second, to live in balance with nature; third, to leave the land in better condition than when we acquired it, and fourth, to educate the public and other landowners on the value of good forest stewardship. Cowlitz Ridge is managed as an economically viable forest. We are operating on a sustained yield basis and have harvested approximately 65 percent of our forest growth in the past 26 years. In other words, we're growing more wood than we're harvesting. To make sure that our forests remain sustainable we invest $325 per acre to establish and nurture a new stand of trees. We will not see any cash flow for 25 years and will have to wait 60 to 80 years for the full return of that investment. You can see investing in timberland is not for the faint- hearted. Many risks, including wildfire, wind storms, and insect blights and regulatory uncertainty are involved as we work to build a legacy for our children and grandchildren, and this legacy is not just for our family. We give educational tours to several hundred people each year. Our forest lands are open to the public for hunting, berry picking, hiking, and horseback riding. Today, family-owned tree farms are still being destroyed by the Federal estate tax, because many of them are highly illiquid. For tree farmers, much of their cash is in standing trees. If you've heard the saying, ``land rich and cash poor,'' well, that's an apt description of many forest landowners. The annual household income of the average tree farmer is less than $50,000, yet, on paper, the typical tree farmer can be valued at well above $2 million. Even with the increase in the exemption under the unified credit and newly created business exclusion, which provides a total exclusion of $1.3 million, the death tax hit on these forest lands can be several hundred thousand dollars. This forces many families to liquidate the timber or, even worse, to fragment the woodland by selling off pieces of their forest land. We need incentives for landowners to stop conversions. In Washington State, the Department of Natural Resources current figures show there's 100 acres a day of prime forest land being converted. The death tax is the leading cause of forest fragmentation today, and in my opinion, the greatest threat to the long-term health of American forests. Thousands of American families like mine cycle earnings back into their businesses. At Cowlitz Ridge, we spend approximately $25,000 each year on forest regeneration and timber stand improvement. We protect and enhance habitat and watersheds. We have excluded 200 acres of forested wetlands and streamside buffers from harvest. We minimize soil disturbance when we harvest and keep our regenerative cuts to between 5 and 20 acres. Because we replant immediately after we harvest and use large, high quality seedlings, we minimize herbicide use and avoid aerial spraying. The death tax provisions you included in the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 will ease the estate tax burden of many small landowners, but it leaves many issues unresolved. For instance, the $10,000 gift exclusion and the $750,000 special use valuation were areas indexed for inflation. The increase in unified credit was not indexed. When you consider that many harvests don't occur for 40 to 60 years or more, you can see that inflation alone can put many families over the total exclusion limit. My family has worked hard on our tree farm to earn a living and create a forest where wildlife, water, air quality, and aesthetic beauty are sustained. We have formed a limited family partnership to help pass this legacy on to our children. We are in the process of forming a habitat conservation plan, but I'm still concerned with all that we have done, our children will still be forced to break up Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm. It's disturbing to know that the death tax generates only 1 percent of all Federal revenues, and for that jobs are lost, communities damaged, and forests destroyed. It seems to me that's a high price to exact on our national heritage for such little return. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Douglas P. Stinson, Owner, Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm, Toledo, Washington, on behalf of Forest Industries Council on Taxation, American Forest & Paper Association, American Tree Farm System, and Washington Farm Forestry Association My name is Doug Stinson, and I am a Tree Farmer from Washington State. My wife, our three children, and I own the Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm--four parcels of forestland totaling 1000 acres near Toledo, WA. I am here today representing the American Tree Farm System, a national network of nearly 70,000 private forest landowners committed to protecting water, wildlife, soil and recreation opportunities and at the same time grow trees for forest products. We are committed to sustainable forestry. Tree Farmers are private citizens from all walks of life who take great pride in practicing forest stewardship on our land, and I'm proud to be speaking on their behalf. In addition, I am proud to be speaking for the Forest Industries Council on Taxation, American Forest & Paper Association and the Washington Farm Forestry Association. Two years ago, Tree Farmer Chester Thigpen of Mississippi, and I sat before this committee and told you about the disincentives built into the federal tax code that discourage people from being good forest stewards--specifically the capital gains and the estate tax provisions. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 went a long way toward remedying those problems. Along with millions of other Americans, I commend you for your actions and support for America's forests. But to insure the long-term health of Americas private forests, which make up 58 percent of our total forestland--we must go even further. As I told this committee in 1995, we have four goals at Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm: 1. To earn a living. 2. To live in balance with nature. 3. To leave the land in better condition than when we purchased it. 4. To educate the public and other landowners on the value of good forest stewardship. Cowlitz Ridge is managed as an economically viable forest. We are operating on a sustained yield basis, and have harvested approximately 65% of our forest growth in the past 20 years. In other words, we are growing more wood than we are harvesting. To make sure that our forests remain sustainable, we invest $325 per acre to establish and nurture a new stand of trees at Cowlitz Ridge. We won't see any cash flow for 25 years and will have to wait between 60 and 80 years for the full return on that investment. So as you can see, investing in timberland is not for the fainthearted. Many risks, including wildfire, wind damage, and insect blights are involved as we work to build a legacy for our children and our grandchildren. Just two weeks ago, in fact, New Hampshire Tree Farmer Tom Thomson lost 90 percent of his 1,060-acre woodland to an ice storm. For the past 20 years, Tom had been building a legacy for his son. Today, most of that legacy lies in splinters on the ground. But many Tree Farmers face another risk, one that is much more certain to strike than an ice storm: The Death Tax. Today, family-owned Tree Farms and small businesses are still being destroyed by the federal estate tax because many of them are highly illiquid. For Tree Farmers, much of our cash is literally in our standing trees. You've heard the saying ``land rich and cash poor.'' Well, that's an apt description of many forest landowners. The annual household income of the average Tree Farmer is less than $50,000. Yet on paper, the typical Tree Farm can be valued at well above $2 million. Even with the increase in the exemption under the unified credit and newly created business exclusion which provides a total exclusion of $1.3 million, the Death Tax ``hit'' on these forestlands can be several hundred thousand dollars. This forces many families to liquidate the timber, or even worse, to fragment the woodland by selling off pieces of their property. In Washington State, 25,000 acres of prime forest land a year is converted to other uses. The Death Tax is the leading cause of forest fragmentation today, and in my opinion is the greatest threat to the long-term health of America's forests. Thousands of American families like mine cycle earnings back into their businesses. At Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm, we spend approximately $25,000 each year on forest regeneration and timber stand improvement. We protect and enhance habitat and watersheds. We have excluded our 150 acres of wetlands from harvest. We minimize soil disturbance when we harvest and keep our harvest areas small. Because we replant immediately after we harvest, and use large high quality seedlings, we minimize herbicide use and avoid aerial spraying. This is a large investment of time and money. But it's worth it to me as long as I know I can pass our legacy along to our children and their children's children. The Death Tax provisions you included in The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 will ease the estate tax burden of many small landowners, but it leaves many issues unresolved. For instance, the $10,000 gift exclusion and the $750,000 special use valuation were the only areas indexed for inflation. When you consider that many harvests don't occur for 60 years or more, you can see that inflation alone can put many families over the total exclusion limit. My family has worked hard on our Tree Farm to earn a living and create a place where wildlife, water and air quality and aesthetic beauty are sustained. We have formed a limited family partnership to help pass on this legacy to our children. We are in the process of forming a habitat conservation plan. But I am concerned that even after all I've done they will be forced to break up Cowlitz Ridge Tree Farm. It's disturbing to know that the Death tax generates only one percent of all federal revenues. And for that, jobs are lost, communities damaged and forests destroyed. I'm not an economist, but it seems to me that's a high price to exact on our national heritage for such little return. I applaud you for convening these hearings. Further reforms in the estate tax for Tree Farmers and small business owners will save jobs, strengthen communities and help guarantee the long-term health and productivity of our nation's private forestlands. Thank you. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Stinson. Our next witness is Jeannine Mizell. If you'll identify yourself, we'll be pleased to hear your testimony, and you may proceed. STATEMENT OF JEANNINE MIZELL, OWNER AND MANAGER, MIZELL LUMBER AND HARDWARE COMPANY, INC., KENSINGTON, MARYLAND, AND MEMBER, U.S. CHAMBER OF COMMERCE Ms. Mizell. Good afternoon, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. I am Jeannine Mizell, a third-generation owner and manager of Mizell Lumber and Hardware Company which is located in Kensington, Maryland. I am also a member of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, the world's largest business federation, representing more than 3 million businesses and organizations of every size, sector, and region. I appreciate this opportunity to tell my story and to express the views of the U.S. Chamber on the Federal estate and gift tax and the need for its repeal or significant reform. My grandfather founded Mizell Lumber in 1922. In 1931, he purchased the property on which Mizell Lumber is still operated. He paid approximately $55,000 for the property. My father, Fred Mizell, joined his dad in the family business in 1947. My father worked 6 days a week for 37 years. He rarely took a vacation or even a day off. Then, one Friday night in 1984, he drove home from work, suffered a heart attack, and died at the age of 63. At that time, his assets, the most valuable of which was Mizell Lumber, passed to my mother. My mother died on September 7, 1990. In administering my mother's estate, my two brothers and I were told by our attorney that we would need to hire appraisers to determine the fair market value of the business including the land on which Mizell Lumber is operated. I can recall feeling shocked when I learned that we would have to pay Federal estate taxes on the value of the lumber company as of the date of my mother's death. The land, which my grandfather originally had purchased for $55,000 and which had been in the family for almost 60 years, was now appraised at $1, 247,000. To our surprise and chagrin we owed a whopping $297,000 in Federal estate taxes. In addition, we had to pay more than $5,000 for the appraisals and $40,000 for attorneys' fees because the estate had many issues so complex that it took two and a half years for it to be settled, and all of this was occurring as we were grieving the loss of our mother. These days I hear so much talk that Americans are not saving enough for retirement and are buying too many things on credit. Well, my father could have taught a class on fiscal responsibility. He never used a credit card in his life. He didn't purchase a new car until he had the money saved up to pay cash for it. My dad worked hard, 6 days a week, 52 weeks a year. He always lived within his means and saved for the future. His number one priority was his children's education. He sent all 3 of us through 12 years of catholic school and then to the college of our choice and most importantly he wanted to leave a legacy to his children and grandchildren. How was my father rewarded for his lifetime of hard work and frugality? We had to liquidate his certificates of deposit, bank accounts, stocks and bonds, and send nearly all of the cash we could come up with to the Internal Revenue Service, yet, that still wasn't enough to pay the Federal estate taxes. We were allowed to defer paying approximately $150,000 of the total tax liability over 15 years. We have sent an estate tax payment of about $19,000 to the Internal Revenue Service every June and will continue to do so until the year 2006. I feel very fortunate that we didn't have to liquidate or sell the business in order to pay off these estate taxes. Nonetheless, I ask, where is the incentive to work hard, invest, be responsible, and pay as you go if a businessowner's estate is taxed the fair market value on property that has been in the family for decades. I have three small children. My oldest son is 9 years old, and he sits behind me today. He is a fourth-grader at Holy Cross Elementary School in Garrett Park, Maryland. He is a straight-A student and recently won the National Geographic Geography Bee for his entire school, beating out all of the older students in grades five through eight. He deserves to attend one of the finest universities in the United States. If I could invest my share of the estate taxes that we are paying, his college education and that of my two younger children would be assured. In conclusion, it is clear to me that the estate and gift tax depletes the estates of taxpayers who have saved their entire lives forcing many successful family businesses to either lay off workers, borrow funds, reduce capital investments, or, in a worst case scenario, liquidate or sell to an outsider. Taxpayers should be motivated to make financial decisions for business and investment reasons and not be punished for individual initiative, hard work, and capital accumulation. The U.S. Chamber believes that the estate and gift tax should be completely repealed, however, if outright repeal is not feasible at this time, it should be significantly reformed in order to reduce or eliminate its negative effect on individuals and the owners of family businesses. Thank you for allowing me the opportunity to testify here today, and I ask that my entire written statement be placed in the record. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Jeannine Mizell, Owner and Manager, Mizell Lumber and Hardware Company, Inc., Kensington, Maryland, and Member, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, my name is Jeannine Mizell and I am a third generation owner and manager of Mizell Lumber and Hardware Company, Inc., which is located in Kensington, Maryland. I am also a member of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce--the world's largest business federation, representing more than three million businesses and organizations of every size, sector, and region. I appreciate this opportunity to relate my story, and to express the views of the U.S. Chamber on the federal estate and gift tax and the need for its repeal or significant reform. I hereby ask that my entire statement be incorporated into the record. While this afternoon's topic of discussion is the federal estate and gift tax and its negative affect on businesses, such as mine, the U.S. Chamber would also like to point out that additional tax relief measures need to be enacted to further increase economic growth, productivity and international competitiveness. These tax measures include: repealing, or in the alternative, further reducing the alternative minimum tax and capital gains tax; permanently extending the research and experimentation tax credit; simplifying the foreign tax rules; reforming and restructuring the Internal Revenue Service, simplifying the worker classification rules, further expanding individual retirement accounts; lowering the maximum tax rate on the reinvested earnings of all flow-through entities, and further reforming the S corporation rules. BACKGROUND OF THE ESTATE AND GIFT TAX Originally, federal estate taxes were imposed primarily to finance wars or threats of war. The first federal estate tax was a stamp tax imposed in 1797. The first progressive estate tax was adopted in 1916, with the maximum tax rate varying from 10 percent in 1916 to 77 percent in 1941. The gift tax was first imposed in 1924, repealed two years later, and then reinstated in 1932. Before 1976, estate taxes were imposed on transfers occurring at death, while gift taxes were imposed on transfers made during a taxpayer's life. In 1976, the estate and gift tax structures were combined and a single unified graduated estate and gift tax system was created. This unified tax system has since applied to the cumulative taxable transfers made by a taxpayer during his or her lifetime and at death. In 1948, Congress provided the first marital deduction, allowing 50 percent of the value of any property transferred to a spouse to be excluded from a decedent's taxable estate. This deduction was later increased to 100 percent. In addition, an individual can give to an unlimited number of recipients up to $10,000 in gifts annually without triggering the gift tax. Under the current estate and gift tax rate structure, rates begin at 18 percent on the first $10,000 of cumulative transfers and reach 55 percent on transfers that exceed $3 million. In addition, a 5-percent surtax is imposed upon cumulative taxable transfers between $10 million and $21,040,000. A unified tax credit is available to offset a specific amount of a decedent's federal estate and gift tax liability. From 1987 through 1997, the unified credit effectively exempted the first $600,000 of cumulative taxable transfers of a decedent from the estate and gift tax. Under the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, the effective exemption amount was increased to $625,000 for 1998, $650,000 for 1999, $675,000 for 2000 and 2001, $700,000 for 2002 and 2003, $850,000 for 2004, $950,000 for 2005, and $1 million for 2006 and years thereafter. The exemption amount, however, will not be indexed for inflation after 2006. In addition, the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 created a new exemption for ``qualified family-owned business interests'' beginning in 1998. However, this exemption, plus the amount effectively exempted by the applicable unified credit, can not exceed $1,300,000. Whether a decedent's estate can qualify for the maximum $1,300,000 exemption amount will depend on the blend of personal and qualified business assets in the estate at death. THE ESTATE AND GIFT TAX IS COMPLEX, UNFAIR AND INEFFICIENT When the government in a free society uses its power to tax, it has an obligation to do so in the least intrusive manner. Taxes imposed should meet the basic criteria of simplicity, efficiency, neutrality and fairness. The federal estate and gift tax fails to meet any of these requisites. The estate tax is anything but simple to understand or comply with. It is a multi-layered taxing mechanism so complex and convoluted that it has given rise to a cottage industry of estate tax planners, accountants and lawyers. While this may be acceptable to those professionals who make their living from the federal estate and gift tax system, it is not acceptable to the thousands of individuals who are forced to pay billions of dollars each year in estate taxes, planning fees, and compliance costs. Even the simplest of estates require a certain amount of estate tax planning in order to avoid the pitfalls of this complicated tax system. Estate tax planning often includes the creation of one or more trusts, such as a living trust or ``Q- TIP'' (qualified terminable interest property) trust, adding even more expense for taxpayers. The estate tax system also contains generation-skipping provisions designed to tax transfers from grandparents to their grandchildren. While the newly-created ``qualified family-owned business interest'' exclusion will reduce estate taxes for some businesses, the provisions have added complexity to an already overly complicated tax system. The estate and gift tax is also inefficient. Taxes are efficient when they waste few resources in the collection process, impose no unnecessary compliance costs on taxpayers and make a high percentage of the proceeds available for public goods. The estate tax has very high collection and compliance costs, even though its revenues only account for slightly more than one percent of total federal tax collections. Individuals and businesses that do not owe estate tax still spend millions of dollars on estate planning and tax return preparation. For example, in 1995, approximately 31,000 estates were subject to estate tax, however, about 70,000 estates had to go through the expense of filing estate tax returns. The other characteristics of an acceptable tax are its neutrality and fairness. While measuring these aspects require a certain amount of subjectivity, the estate tax can not be considered either neutral or fair to individuals or businesses. The highly-progressive nature of this tax severely penalizes those who have saved more, risked more, and worked harder than others. Furthermore, those with large estates often hire expensive estate tax planners and attorneys to establish elaborate estate plans in order to eliminate, substantially reduce, or defer their estate tax liabilities. Unfortunately, many small and family-owned business owners are either unaware of the need for estate tax planning or unable to afford it, which later results in enormous estate tax liabilities for such businesses. In order to pay such liabilities, these businesses are forced to either lay off workers, borrow funds, reduce capital investments, liquidate, or sell to an outside buyer. These actions hurt everyone connected with these businesses, including its owners, employees, customers, vendors, and families. THE ESTATE AND GIFT TAX THWARTS ECONOMIC GROWTH AND PRODUCTIVITY Public policies should not only improve our nation's current economic environment, but also ensure our future prosperity. The key to a stronger economic future is simple to define (i.e., a high rate of economic growth), but difficult to achieve. It is strong economic growth that will allow us to maintain our position of world leadership, increase our standard of living, and meet the daunting demographic challenges that will begin to present themselves early in the next century. But economic growth does not occur by accident. Just as our farmers do not rely on good luck for bountiful harvests, neither can we rely on chance or the momentum of the past to propel us in the future. The seeds of tomorrow's economic success must be planted today, and so, when evaluating economic policies, we must ask how they would cultivate long-term economic growth. By definition, economic growth is simply the product of growth in the labor force (i.e., the number of hours worked) and growth in productivity (i.e., output per hour). With growth in hours worked largely determined by demographics, sensible economic policy must emphasize strong productivity growth. This is a crucial issue because productivity growth has been languishing for the past quarter-century or so. After expanding at a healthy 2.7 percent rate during the 1960's, for example, productivity growth has slowed to an anemic one percent rate so far in the 1990's. With growth in hours worked hovering a little below 1.5 percent, long-term economic growth is thus limited to 2.5 percent--well below the average of the post-World War II era. While measurement problems related to productivity have expanded with the growing share of the economy devoted to service-producers rather than goods-producers, the decline in economic growth over the same period confirms that we are suffering a decline in the underlying growth rate in productivity. The question then becomes: What can we do to raise productivity growth? Like the farmer who sows the seed corn and cultivates the soil, households and businesses must also prepare for the future. Virtually all economists agree that this is done by saving and investing in capital--both human capital (education) and physical capital (plant and equipment). Thus the issue of long-term productivity growth and, in turn, economic growth becomes one of fostering additions to, and improvements in, capital. Consequently, today's economic policies must be targeted toward improving economic growth by fostering saving, investment, and capital formation. Only through such pro-growth policies can we lay the foundation of prosperity and security for our children into and beyond the 21st century. To boost productivity, the federal government must end its misdirection of resources and curb its appetite for borrowing so that national savings and investment can be increased. This will yield stronger productivity growth, which in turn will propel the economy on a higher growth track. Besides balancing the budget, other policy elements that would aid long-term economic growth include overhauling our regulatory and tort systems, enhancing education and job training programs, reducing the tax burden, and reforming the tax code. THE ESTATE AND GIFT TAX NEEDS TO BE REPEALED OR REFORMED While the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 will provide some businesses with relief from the estate and gift tax, and is certainly a step in the right direction, the best solution would be to repeal the tax outright. The U.S. Chamber supports legislation introduced by Senator Jon L. Kyl (R-AZ) and Representative Christopher Cox (R-CA)--the Family Heritage Preservation Act (S. 75, H.R. 902)--which would immediately repeal the federal estate and gift tax. However, if repeal is not politically feasible in the near term, additional reforms should be implemented to make the tax less harmful to small business owners and their workers. First, the unified credit (and its corresponding exemption amount) should be increased even further. In today's marketplace, the value of many ``small'' businesses easily exceed the prescribed exemption amounts, making them potentially subject to estate tax. In addition, the recently- enacted $1-million exemption amount should be phased-in over a much quicker time period. For example, while the effective exemption amount is scheduled to increase to $1 million by 2006, such amount will not exceed $700,000 until 2004. The credit also needs to be indexed for inflation so its value is not eroded over time. Under current law, once the effective exemption amount reaches $1 million, it is scheduled to remain at that level indefinitely. Second, overall estate and gift tax rates--which can reach as high as 60 percent--need to be significantly reduced. The value of a decedent's taxable estate only has to exceed $2 million before it becomes subject to a 49-percent rate, and $3 million before it becomes subject to a 55-percent rate. These rates are excessive and need to be significantly lowered in order to promote business and job growth. The U.S. Chamber supports legislation introduced by Senator Don Nickles (R-OK)-- the Estate Tax Reduction Act of 1997 (S. 650)--which would drop the maximum marginal estate tax rate to 30 percent. Third, in order to promote the continuation of family-owned businesses, the amount of the newly-enacted ``qualified family- owned business interest'' exclusion needs to be further increased, as well as expanded to encapsulate more businesses. When a substantial portion of a decedent's wealth is invested in his or her business, payment of the estate and gift tax can be extremely difficult without having to liquidate or sell the business, sell key assets, lay off hard-working employees, or borrow against its assets. The U.S. Chamber supports legislation introduced by Representatives Jim McCrery (R-LA), Jennifer Dunn (R-WA), and others--the Family Business Protection Act (H.R. 1299)--which would, among other things, exempt from estate tax the first $1.5 million in value, and 50 percent of any excess value, of a ``qualified family-owned business interest.'' Fourth, existing installment payment rules need to be further broadened. Under current law, the estate tax attributable to a ``closely-held'' business can be paid in annual installments over a 14-year period. In addition, tax on the first $1 million in value of a such a business is eligible for a special two percent interest rate. In addition to increasing the 14-year installment period, more businesses should be able to qualify for installment plans, and a greater amount of estate tax should be eligible for a low, or zero percent, interest rate. The U.S. Chamber supports legislation introduced by Senators Charles E. Grassley (R-IA), Trent Lott (R-MS), and others--the Estate Tax Relief for the American Family Act of 1997 (S. 479)--which would, among other things, increase the installment payment period to 20 years. MY ESTATE TAX HORROR STORY My grandfather founded Mizell Lumber in 1922. In 1931, he purchased the property on which Mizell Lumber is still operated for approximately $55,000. My father, Fred Mizell, joined his Dad in the family business in 1947. My father worked six days a week for 37 years, rarely taking a vacation or even a day off. Then one Friday night in 1984, he drove home from work, suffered a heart attack, and died at the age of 63. At that time, his assets, the most valuable of which was Mizell Lumber, passed to my mother. However, my mother died on September 7, 1990. My two brothers and I were told by our estate tax attorney that we would need to hire appraisers to determine the fair market value of the business, including the land on which Mizell Lumber is operated. I can recall feeling shocked when I learned that we would have to pay federal estate taxes on the fair market value of the lumber company as of the date of my mother's death. The land, which my grandfather originally had purchased for $55,000, and which had been in the family for almost 60 years, was now appraised at $1,247,000. To our surprise and chagrin, we owed a whopping $297,000 in federal estate taxes! In addition, we had to pay more than $5,000 for the appraisal itself, as well as $40,000 for attorney fees because the estate had many issues so complex that it took two and one-half years to settle the estate. All this was occurring as we were grieving the loss of our mother! I hear so much talk in the news regarding the fact that Americans are not saving enough for retirement and are buying too many things on credit. Well, my father could have taught a class on fiscal responsibility. He never used a credit card in his life. He didn't purchase a new car until he had the money saved up to pay cash for it. My Dad worked hard six days a week, 52 weeks a year. He always lived within his means and saved his money for the future. His number one priority was his children's education. He sent all three of us through twelve years of Catholic schools and then to the college of our choice. Most importantly, he wanted to leave a legacy to his children and grandchildren. How was my father rewarded for his lifetime of hard work and frugality? We had to liquidate his certificates of deposit, bank accounts, stocks and bonds, and send nearly all of the cash we could come up with to the Internal Revenue Service. And yet that still wasn't enough to pay the federal estate taxes! We deferred paying approximately $150,000 of the total taxes due over fifteen years. Mizell Lumber has sent an estate tax payment of about $19,000 every June, and will do so until the hear 2006. I feel very fortunate that we didn't have to liquidate or sell the business in order to pay off these estate taxes. Where is the incentive to work hard, invest, be responsible and pay-as-you-go if a business owner's estate is taxed at fair market value on property that has been in the family for decades? I have three small children. My oldest son is nine years old. He is a 4th grader at Holy Cross Elementary School in Garrett Park, Maryland. He is a straight-A student and recently won the National Geographic Geography Bee for his entire school, beating out all the older students in grades 5 through 8. He deserves to attend one of the finest universities in the United States. If I could invest my share of the estate taxes that the business is paying, his college education, and that of my two younger children, would be assured. CONCLUSION The estate and gift tax depletes the estates of taxpayers who have saved their entire lives, often forcing successful family businesses to liquidate or take on burdensome debt to pay the tax. Taxpayers should be motivated to make financial decisions for business and investment reasons, and not be punished for individual initiative, hard work, and capital accumulation. The U.S. Chamber believes that the estate and gift tax should be completely repealed. However, if outright repeal is not politically feasible, it should be significantly reformed in order to reduce or eliminate its negative effect on individuals and the owners of family businesses. Thank you for the allowing me the opportunity to testify here today. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Ms. Mizell, and, without objection, your written statement will be put in the record in full as will be true of all witnesses. The next witness is Mr. Hannay. Welcome. STATEMENT OF ROGER HANNAY, PRESIDENT AND CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER, HANNAY REELS, INC., WESTERLO, NEW YORK, ON BEHALF OF NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF MANUFACTURERS Mr. Hannay. Thank you, sir. Good afternoon, Mr. Chairman and other Members of the Committee. My name is Roger Hannay, and I am president and chief executive officer of Hannay Reels, Inc., a small manufacturer in the foothills of the Catskill Mountains in upstate New York, 25 miles from Albany. What we make is heavy duty reels that wind up hoses such as on a fire truck or on a fuel delivery aircraft refueler, and so forth. I'd like to address you today about the death tax. It's been aptly named that several times today. For years, it's been euphemistically known as the estate tax, which reminds me more of a nice place in Virginia that you raise horses than a tax, so I will continue to refer to it as the death tax--it is, after all, indeed, a tax on dying. On November 10, 1997, my dad, George, was lost to us, to myself and my siblings, and he was a second-generation owner and former chief executive officer and current chairman when he passed away. He missed just about as few days of work as my counterpart's dad did over the years he was there; he was still at work 1 week before his death at age 77. I'd like to thank, in absentia, but in spirit, Mike McNulty--my own Congressman who's on this panel--for his kindness to us at that time. He and his dad were both there for the memorial service. Our fourth generation which consists of my son, Eric, and my daughter, Elaine--who's with us a little bit further back in the room today--they represent the hopes and plans of our company for continuation of the business. They are both committed to succeeding in both senses of that word. To do so, we'll have to successfully navigate the mine field of the normal family planning issues: getting along with each other; making the business work; deciding who has gifts for what areas of the business, and, also, surviving the repeated blows from the death tax. It's a challenge that revisits us with every generation. The tax challenge is definitely in our case the more difficult of those two challenges in our family which is reasonably nondysfunctional--to use a double negative. Death taxes are an issue, not just because of the recent loss of our dad but also because of the need to prepare for my passing. I just realized, looking in the mirror, I'm now the older generation. So, for the sake of our 150 employees and what they represent to our little community which has about 300 residents, we'd like very much to see that happen without the necessity for selling the business simply to pay the taxes. My dad's estate will, not may, be subject to a full IRS audit; it's a sure thing; it's a slam dunk because of its dollar value. Almost any successful small manufacturing business or small farm or tree stand will be for an automatic audit. As chief executive officer and also other roles such as oldest son, older brother, executor, and father to my kids, I will literally be dealing with the grief over our dad's loss for probably the next 4 years. I heard one optimistic number earlier today of two and a half years, but it makes it very difficult to have closure over the loss of our dad. I also lost my mom April 20 of last year, so it was kind of a double whammy kind of year for us. I will not attempt, today, to deal with the more technical issues of the tax. There are many people in this town and beyond that are much better trained and qualified to do that than I, and you heard some of them today, however, even with my limited tax knowledge I am aware of a couple of basic points. First of all, I understand that the net revenue produced by this tax after factoring out the costs of collecting it and auditing it are roughly 1 percent of Federal revenues. If we're wrong, we're all wrong together today, because we've all been using roughly that number. The modest source of revenue that that brings imposes unbelievably complex and costly burdens on my business. It causes a dark cloud over our business and thousands of others like it. Did we, indeed, dot all the i's and cross all the t's? Can you ever really know in advance with certainty that the estate plan is correct and complete? I don't think so. What's the value of 20/20 hindsight when we, as executors, talk about could have done, should have done, might have done, if the business has to end up being sold. At least with most other taxes, you can debate and adjust while you're still alive; not so with the death tax. It's also very obvious to me and others here today that it represents at least double taxation without representation which Patrick Henry would have had difficulty with. Everything in one's estate has already been taxed once before, in some cases twice. From time to time I lament with my accountants also that I'd like to spend some more of my time and money with them talking about creative and positive things, not defensive things like planning for the death event. There really are other things that accountants and lawyers can do besides this activity as we've already heard. I'd like to make it real clear that I'm not advocating further tinkering, tweaking with the present tax, although we do appreciate the modest Band-Aid that's been applied for the next few months. We basically want to kill the death tax as New York State, for one, has already done for the year 2000. Why is dying a taxable event? It's almost like this is the punishment for having the audacity to die. I sense quite a bit of support for repeal out in the hinterlands. It has been said at least partially in jest, ``If it moves, tax it.'' I'd like to suggest--maybe we could propose a new saying, ``If it quits moving, don't tax it anymore.'' Since some friends have become aware that I would be active on this subject, I began receiving some unsolicited war stories one of which very much resembles my colleague to the left here in terms of a forest land where the loss of a multigenerational family farm, or family business, has indeed occurred; there was no alternative. In closing, I've heard that something close to 95 percent of family-owned businesses don't make it successfully to the fourth generation as ours is attempting to do, and a very high number not to the second or third. If so, I think we have to candidly ask ourselves, ``How many of these failures are because the families just didn't get along or competitive pressures--which are certainly formidable challenges--and how many are successful in those arenas only to lose it to the tax man?'' I thank you very much for your kind invitation to be here today. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Roger Hannay, President and Chief Executive Officer, Hannay Reels, Inc., Westerlo, New York, on behalf of National Association of Manufacturers Good afternoon gentlewomen and gentlemen, my name is Roger Hannay and I am President and CEO of Hannay Reels, Inc., a small manufacturer with 150 employees in the foothills of the Catskill Mountains, 25 miles from Albany, New York. I'd like to address you today about the ``death'' tax, which for years has been euphemistically known as the ``estate'' tax. Frankly, the word ``estate'' reminds me more of a nice place in the countryside of Virginia where you raise horses, rather than a tax, so I will continue to refer to it as the ``death tax.'' After all, it is indeed a tax on dying. On November 10, 1997, my siblings and I lost our Dad, George, a second generation owner and former CEO and then Chairman of our company. On April 20 of the same year, we had lost our Mom. Our fourth generation, my son, Eric, and my daughter, Elaine, who is with me here today, represent the hopes and plans we have for continuation of the business. They are both committed to ``succeeding'' in the business (in both senses of that word). To do so, we will have to successfully navigate the minefield of ``passing the torch'' of leadership in the company and surviving repeated blows from the death tax. The tax challenge is definitely the more difficult one of the two in our reasonably non-dysfunctional family (to use a double negative). Death taxes are an issue not just because of the recent loss of my father, but also because of the need to prepare for my passing. For the sake of our 150 employees and what they represent to the community, we would like very much to see that happen without being forced to sell the business simply to pay taxes. My father's estate will be subjected to a full audit by the IRS, because of its dollar value. Almost any successful small manufacturing business will exceed the threshold for an automatic audit. As CEO, and also oldest son, older brother, executor, and father, I will literally be dealing with the grief over the loss of my parents last year for about the next four years until the final death tax audit is complete. This makes it very difficult to have closure regarding the loss of my parents. I will not attempt today to deal with the more technical issues of the tax. There are many people, in this town and beyond, who are much better trained and qualified to do that than I. However, even with my limited tax knowledge, I am aware of a couple of basic points. First of all, I understand that the net revenue produced by this tax, after factoring out the costs of collecting and auditing it, are roughly one percent of federal revenues. This modest source of revenue imposes unbelievably complex and costly burdens on my business. It casts a dark cloud over our business and thousands of other family owned businesses: Did we indeed dot all the i's and cross all the t's? Can you ever know (in advance) with certainty that the estate plan is correct and complete? What is the value of 20/20 hindsight when we talk as executors about ``could have done'' or ``should have done'' if the business has been sold? At least with most other taxes, you can debate and adjust, while you are alive. Not so with the death tax. It is also very obvious to me that it is a tax that represents at least double taxation without representation, a principle that would have been unthinkable to Patrick Henry. After all, virtually everything in one's estate has already been taxed at least once before. From time to time, I lament with my accountants that I would like to spend some of my time and money with them talking about creative and positive things, rather than defensive things like planning for the death event. There really are other things accountants can do in addition to tax planning. I'd like to make it very clear that I am not advocating further ``tinkering'' or ``tweaking'' with the present tax, although we do appreciate the modest tinkering with the lifetime exclusion that has been proffered as a short-term Band-Aid. We basically want to ``Kill the death tax.'' Why is dying a taxable event? It's almost as if this tax is the punishment for having the audacity to die. I sense quite a bit of support for repeal out in the hinterlands. It has been said, at least partially in jest, ``if it moves, tax it.'' Perhaps we could begin to agree on a philosophy of ``if it quits moving, don't tax it anymore.'' Since some friends have become aware that I would be active on this subject, I've begun to receive unsolicited ``war stories'' from these folks about the situations of their own parents, and what it meant in terms of the loss of a multi- generational family farm or family business. As I become aware of more of these in detail, I will be happy to share them with all who are interested. In closing, I've heard that something close to 95 percent or more of family-owned businesses do not make it successfully to the fourth generation, as ours is striving to do. If so, I think we have to candidly ask ourselves how many of those failures are because of competitive pressures or families just not getting along (which are certainly formidable enough challenges), and how many are successful in those arenas only to lose these endeavors to the death tax? I thank you very much for your kind invitation to be with you today. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Hannay. Our last witness on this panel is Mr. William Beach. Mr. Beach, welcome. STATEMENT OF WILLIAM W. BEACH, JOHN M. OLIN SENIOR FELLOW IN ECONOMICS; AND DIRECTOR, CENTER FOR DATA ANALYSIS, HERITAGE FOUNDATION Mr. Beach. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Members of the Committee on Ways and Means of the House of Representatives, it's a great pleasure for me to be here today. My name is William W. Beach. I am the John Olin Senior Fellow in Economics at the Heritage Foundation and being the last witness on the last panel, I am literally at the end of the day. I'm going to abandon my formal remarks; what you've heard from everybody on the panels preceding what I'm about to say. It's much more important than what I'm about to say, because they are speaking to the heart of the matter, and the heart of the matter is that we have in the estate tax an utter contradiction, not only the rest of the Tax Code and everything it stands for but of the basis of this country; that if we work hard; if we live by the law; if we try to succeed; educate ourselves; save, we will succeed, and as Carol Moseley-Braun, a Senator from Illinois, said in a hearing before the Finance Committee not too long ago, ``in fact, it's the nightmare of the American dream.'' It's the thing that you wake up when you're 55 years of age, and you say, ``Oh my gosh, my accountant has just told me that there's something out there called the estate tax.'' So let me being--since I'm the last witness, sort of be the sum-up person--and also, Mr. Chairman, I'm the one that wears the green eyeshade, and I have some answers to revenue questions that you asked in the previous panel. There are a number of arguments for why we should repeal the estate tax; you've heard them all, and it's very important to listen to what is being said about how it hurts businesses. The other side of that and not represented at these panels is it hurts people who have jobs in these businesses. So, an indirect effect of the estate tax is that it reduces the number of jobs. It also reduces the number of potential jobs, thus, hurting people who are young; who are struggling; who are entering the labor force. We could say an indirect effect of the estate tax is to hurt the working man and the working women in the place in which they live most and that is in their checkbook. Represented at these panels today and at other panels at other Committee hearings on this subject have been women in business. It's very important to note that with the fastest growing segment of the self-employed people being women entrepreneurs, that the estate tax has become a quintessential women's issue. So among the victims of the estate tax, not only do we count people who are laboring, workers, we can now count women. Did you know, Mr. Chairman, that the most feared tax among black businessmen today is not the income tax; not the corporation income tax; not the foreign services tax, it's the estate tax. A recent survey by Kennesaw State University professors of accounting and economics--a very nice survey, which I'm happy to send you if you don't have a copy of it--of black businesspeople in this country, African-Americans, who have struggled to provide for their children the kind of life that they didn't have when they started out says the estate tax is the surprise, the thing that would be the most unexpected development. And why this is such a feared tax is all of their life savings have gone into their businesses. These are people who are successful in their businesses but not in their pocketbook. Asian-Americans, we could go on and on and on again. In fact, I think, Mr. Chairman, the strongest argument today for the estate tax comes from the liberal wing of the American tax community. You know because you have had testimony from Professor Edward McCaffery. His amazing admission being a person who in every other respect will approach taxes from a liberal standpoint, but he must now conclude that he is not in favor, cannot be in favor, must be opposed to the estate tax, and I'll read one short paragraph from his testimony before the Senate Committee on Finance June 7, 1995, ``I am an unrequited liberal in both the classical and contemporary political senses of that word whose views on social and distributive justice might best be described as progressive,'' and indeed he will haunt this Committee because of a recent book that he just published called Taxing Women--you'll see it come up many, many times during this tax season. I used to believe in the gifts and estate tax as a vehicle for obtaining justice. I am now prepared to confess that I was blind, but now I can see. It seems to me that there are three ways to repeal the estate tax, Mr. Chairman, and that's in my written remarks. First, outright repeal, it has an amazing support in both the House and Senate, and, indeed, the economic and revenue effects of outright repeal, similar to that in House Resolution 902 or in Senate bill number 75, are very, very good. In a study we prepared in 1996, in August, on this subject we found that if we were to repeal the estate and gift tax, we would have $11 billion more annually in gross domestic product, 145,000 more additional jobs; personal income would rise by $8 billion a year, and the deficit would in fact be unaffected after the fifth year. I would strongly support outright repeal as the way in which we should proceed, particularly as a result of last night's speech by the President. Oddly enough, he put us on a 1 year short order for Social Security reform. If we, indeed, go the direction of personalization or even partial personalization as a majority of the advisory council on Social Security have recommended, then we're going to have projections of many middle-income Americans with substantial estates upon their retirement in the year 2025 to 2040. The estate tax, if it's not addresses, will be a problem that everybody will face. The second way is phaseouts. Phaseouts are very attractive. We don't get the economic benefits of repeal immediately, but if you're interested in revenue and protecting the revenue then there are ways to phase out the estate tax over a 10-year period. I would recommend rate reduction coupled with a steady increase in the unified credit, and we are working on simulations that show what that does. The most interesting and exciting approach--and I'll conclude with this--is what we are calling the unified capital gains. This is a relatively new idea that came out of a hearing in front of the Senate Finance Committee last year. The unified capital gains repeals the estate tax and takes all of the estate tax base and places it under the capital gains tax. It follows directly what Mr. Apolinsky was talking about where we in fact no longer have step-up in basis. Putting in place a $1 million exemption for taxable dispositions out of estates and taxing the rest of those dispositions if they are taxable under capital gains law essentially results in about a 50-percent reduction statically in what you would otherwise get from the estate tax. The dynamic effects are substantial. We're measuring now the economic effects of eliminating compliance, putting all of that together, Mr. Chairman--to answer the question you asked Mr. Apolinsky--out of a total static loss from outright repeal of $180 billion in estate tax revenues over 7 years, the Treasury of the United States would be at a loss of no more than $24 billion if you take in the static and dynamic effects from unified capital gains. On any of these proposals, we'd be very happy to supply the Committee with additional details. We've measured each of these; measured them using, I think, the best macroeconomic models available, The Warten Econometric Forecasting Associates, DRI, McGraw-Hill. Most economists, now, are on the side of phasing out at least the estate tax or of the unified capital gains tax move. Thank you very much for allowing me to have these remarks, and I urge the Committee to move forward on estate tax reform. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of William W. Beach, John M. Olin Senior Fellow in Economics; and Director, Center for Data Analysis, Heritage Foundation My name is William W. Beach, and I am delighted to present the following arguments in support of estate tax repeal to the Committee on Ways and Means of the United States House of Representatives. I am the John M. Olin Senior Fellow in Economics at the Heritage Foundation, a Washington based public policy research organization. The following remarks constitute my own opinions, and nothing in this testimony should be construed as representing the views of The Heritage Foundation or support by the Foundation for any legislation pending before the Congress. Testimony The 105th Congress took important steps in the Taxpayers Relief Act of 1997 toward lightening the burden of death taxes on certain well-defined taxpaying segments. By expanding the exemption of taxable wealth for estates containing small businesses or farms, the Congress officially recognized the harmful effects that death taxes now have on entrepreneurship and family-owned enterprises. By increasing the unified credit from six-hundred thousand to one million dollars over 10 years, the tax writing committees signaled their understanding that estates of this size will be increasingly common in the near future and that small estates should not be taxed. The tax act of 1997, however, did little more than address the immediate shortcomings of this peculiar tax. The increase in the unified credit keeps taxpayers roughly even with inflation, even though a little less than half of the higher credit comes in the last two years of the ten-year phase-in period. The additional exemptions for small businesses will offer some taxpayers relief, but the complex steps that taxpayers must take to discover whether they are eligible for the higher exemptions will require significant legal advice and the counsel of high-priced accountants. It is doubtful that more than a few hundred estates containing small business assets will ever qualify for these ``tax savings'' Congress enacted last year. The actions taken by Congress in last year's legislation had one additional effect: they left largely in place all of the arguments for repealing federal death taxes. It remains a tax that unintentionally falls most heavily on small businesses, farmers, ethnic minorities, women entrepreneurs and, indirectly but importantly, on poor people. While virtually every Congress since the middle 1930s has spent considerable effort designing tax policy that would help these types of taxpayers, intergenerational wealth transfer taxation has produced an effect almost completely opposite that of nearly every other part of the Code. It appears that the estate tax actually bears down most heavily on the intended beneficiaries of wealth taxation, not the tax policy's apparent targets: owners of small and medium-sized businesses, who often are ethnic or female, discover too late for remedy that their legacy of hard work and frugality will not pass to their children but instead will fall victim to confiscatory taxation and liquidation; farmers, many of whom are descendants of the Populists who rallied at the end of the nineteenth century in support of wealth taxation, lose their farms not because of wealthy agribusinesses or capitalist ``robber barons'' but because the federal government demands a tax payment upon death from people who have invested their earnings back into their family legacy and have maintained meager liquid savings; workers suffer, too, when small and medium-sized businesses are liquidated to pay estate taxes and when high capital costs depress the number of new business creations that could offer new jobs; and poor people are harmed by the estate tax, not only because the general economy is weakened by the estate tax's rapacious appetite for family-owned businesses but also because the estate tax discourages savings and encourages consumption (particularly among wealthy individuals), thus undermining the federal income tax from which the funds are raised to support programs for disadvantaged Americans. What should Congress do to address these problems stemming from federal death taxes? In my view, nothing short of repeal will eliminate the significant indirect effects of the tax, such as job losses that result from forced liquidations of businesses contained in taxable estates. Indeed, repeal may be the only appropriate step if Congress wishes to address the moral quandaries raised by multiple taxation. There appears to be three repeal options open to Congress: immediate repeal of those Code sections that permit estate, gift, and generation-skipping taxation; a phase-out plan that reduces the top tax rate and raises the unified credit over a specified number of years; and the unified capital gains tax (which repeals federal death taxes and unifies the old estate tax base with the capital gains tax base). Let me describe each option separately. Immediate Repeal Ending death as a taxable event is the objective of H.R. 902, sponsored by Congressman Chris Cox, and S. 75 offered by Senator Jon Kyl. These two identical bills repeal estate, gift and generation-skipping taxes and currently enjoy substantial support in their respective chambers: there are 31 sponsors of the Senate bill and 161 sponsors of this legislation in the House. Many of the co-sponsors of these two bills doubtless support repeal because of the compelling moral argument behind this reform, which I describe below. However, others are more comfortable with repeal following several demonstrations that federal revenues are enhanced by elimination of federal death taxes rather than harmed. An analysis by The Heritage Foundation using two leading econometric models found that repealing the estate tax would have a large and beneficial effect on the economy.\1\ Specifically, the Heritage analysis found that if the tax were repealed this year, over the next nine years: --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ William W. Beach, ``The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax,'' The Heritage Foundation Backgrounder, no. 1091, August, 1996. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- the nation's economy would average as much as $11 billion per year in extra output; an average of 145,000 additional new jobs could be created; personal income could rise by an average of $8 billion per year above current projections; and the deficit actually would decline, since revenues generated by extra growth would more than compensate for the meager revenues currently raised by the inefficient estate tax. The Heritage analysis of repeal's positive effects has been recently supported by work on the unified capital gains tax by Richard Fullenbaum and Mariana McNeill.\2\ Their work includes estimates of how much economic output would change from eliminating the costs of complying with death tax law. These costs were not included in the Heritage study of 1996. Had they been, the positive effects described above would be enhanced. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \2\ Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill, ``The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy,'' forthcoming from The Research Institute for Small & Emerging Business (1998). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Phasing Down Tax Rates and Increasing the Unified Credit A number of Members have expressed interest in slowly but steadily reducing the top statutory tax rate on estates. Congressman Pappas in particular has championed this approach to repeal. Others have indicated an interest in coupling reductions in rates with increases in the unified credit, which accelerates the phase-out period by shrinking the number and size of taxable estates. Over time, federal death taxes simply disappear. There are a number of unpublished revenue and economic estimates of various phase-out plans, all of which indicate that significant improvements to economic efficiency follow reductions in death tax burden. However, the positive economic and revenue effects that come from immediate repeal overwhelm those that stem from a slow phase-out program. Not only do compliance costs continue to burden taxpayers, but tax avoidance behavior persists, which results in capital and labor costs remaining higher than they otherwise would be following outright repeal. Despite the likelihood that phasing out the estate tax would result in fewer economic bonuses than would immediate repeal, the advocates of the phaseout option argue that the Treasury would ``lose'' fewer tax dollars than under the immediate repeal option. While my research indicates that immediate repeal produces more total income tax revenue after the four years than the phase-out option, the advocates of this more cautious approach are doubtless correct on the direction of revenue change in the very short run. The Unified Capital Gains Tax The unification of the estate tax base and the capital gains tax base through the unified capital gains tax appeals to those repeal advocates concerned with the moral dimensions of federal death taxes as well as those focused on repeal's revenue effects. The proposal repeals all federal death taxes (thus ending death as a taxable event) and imposes the long- term capital gains tax rate on only those asset transfers from estates that 1) would be taxable under existing capital gains law and 2) exceed a special one-million dollar exemption on otherwise taxable dispositions from estates to persons as defined and recognized in present tax law. Some advocates of this approach would end step-up in tax basis. By making the ``tax moment'' the disposition of an asset rather than the death of a taxpayer, the unified capital gain tax addresses many of the moral concerns advanced by supporters of outright repeal. Death is not the taxable event, and unprepared taxpayers will no longer be forced to liquidate ongoing businesses or family assets just to pay a tax. Of course, the unified capital gains tax only eliminates one layer of multiple taxation: many assets created from after-tax income will be taxed again under capital gain tax law. However, the repeal of the estate tax clearly moves tax policy in the direction a flatter tax system, and the proposal should interest those tax policy reformers interested in fundamental tax changes. Economic analysis of the unified capital gains tax by Fullenbaum and McNeill indicates that this tax policy change would likely result in improved economic performance and surprisingly little revenue ``loss'' in the short run. Fullenbaum and McNeill predict significant employment and income gains from repeal, largely stemming from the drop in capital and compliance costs that follow unification. The small drop in revenues reverses sign after four years, and income taxes from individuals and corporations grow above CBO baseline projections. The Moral Argument for Repeal All three of these proposals for repealing federal death taxes draw on a growing body of empirical evidence and philosophical argument that is ineluctably undermining the historical justification for intergenerational wealth transfer taxation. Between 1913 and 1916 the Congress deployed a system of income taxation that had two objectives: to raise revenue for the federal government and to contain the economic power of wealthy individuals through taxation. This latter objective dominated Congress's discussion of income taxation and inspired support among political activists during the ratification process for the Sixteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution. In its common translation, the ``containment'' objective of early tax policy meant simply this: the increasing concentration of wealth in the hands of a few individuals prevents many Americans from enjoying the economic opportunities that this country was founded to provide and that our fundamental law protects. While revenue requirements were always high on Congress's agenda, especially during the ensuing world war, it is fair to say that wealth containment was the fundamental public policy goal that Congress intended wealth taxation to achieve. It also is fair to say that, after eighty years of estate taxation, this objective has not been met. If it was Congress's intention to craft a public policy that threatens and destroys small and medium-sized businesses, devastates rural communities, weakens the economy and depresses job growth for new and displaced workers, and makes it more, not less, difficult for poor people to rise up the income ladder and participate more fully in the economic opportunities of American civilization; they could have done little better than the estate tax. But this outcome, of course, was precisely the opposite of Congress's purpose. U.S. wealth taxation policy surely is a classic instance of unintended consequences. Reversing these perverse results should be the current Congress's principal tax policy program. It is politically unconscionable as well as morally dubious to assert, on the one hand, that a principal objective of U.S. tax policy is to expand economic opportunity for disadvantaged Americans--blacks, Hispanics, women, workers, and poor people-- while, on the other hand, vigorously enforcing a part of U.S. tax policy that contracts their economic opportunity. This dilemma is resolved only by repealing the estate, gift and generation-skipping tax. Reforms that ``protect'' certain taxpayers from the estate tax (an intriguing admission in itself of the contradictions inherent in the law) through increases in the unified credit do nothing for those Americans above the new taxable threshold but who are no different from their brothers and sisters just below the threshold except that they are modestly more successful. Reforms do nothing for workers in firms that are not ``protected,'' for farmers whose land values have risen above the new threshold because they abut a new suburb or cross a cellular transmission grid, or for poor people living in an economy still insufficiently robust to lift them out of poverty. Reforms do nothing to reverse the incentive to consume rather than save or to purchase expensive life insurance, legal and accounting advice that moves resources to sectors of the economy that do little to raise worker productivity and worker wages. And reforms do nothing to resolve the public's increasing demand that Congress enact substantive tax reforms that result in a simpler, flatter, and fairer tax system. It is ironic but perhaps fitting that most of the energy for estate tax repeal has come from political conservatives. One would think that the rich tradition among American liberals of supporting middle class incomes, jobs for new workers, economic opportunities for disadvantaged groups, and protection of the family farm would have made estate tax repeal a top objective. Surely the liberal objection that repeal would only benefit rich people could be addressed by modest changes to capital gain tax law where, indeed, many wealthy people currently choose to be taxed. And surely the objection that too much revenue would be lost with repeal could be addressed by simple demonstrations that the estate tax currently undermines the income tax directly through legal avoidance schemes that shelter income from estate taxes and indirectly through consumption rather than savings. Take, for example, the growing evidence of the estate tax's harm to the general economy and to jobs in particular. Economists across a wide political spectrum have produced a rich body of empirical and inferential evidence that the estate tax reduces economic activity and fails to achieve its stated purpose. For example, Alan Blinder, who served in President Clinton's first Council of Economic Advisers and later as Vice- Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, argued that ``[t]he reformer eyeing the estate tax as a means to reduce [income] inequality had best look elsewhere.'' \3\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \3\ As quoted in Edward J. McCaffery, ``The Uneasy Case for Wealth Transfer Taxation,'' The Yale Law Journal, Vol. 104 (November 1994), p. 322, note 143. Also see Joseph E. Stiglitz, ``Notes on Estate Taxes, Redistribution, and the Concept of Balanced Growth Path Incidence,'' Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86 (1978), Supplement, pp. 137-150; Alan S. Blinder, ``A Model of Inherited Wealth,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 87 (1973), pp. 608-626; Blinder, ``Inequality and Mobility in the Distribution of Wealth,'' Kyklos, Vol. 29 (1976), pp 607, 619; Michael Boskin, ``An Economist's Perspective on Estate Taxation,'' in Death, Taxes and Family Property: Essays and American Assembly Report, ed. Edward Halback, Jr. (St. Paul, Minn.: West Publishing Co., 1977); Lawrence H. Summers, ``Capital Taxation and Accumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model,'' American Economic Review, Vol. 71 (1981); Martin Feldstein, ``The Welfare Cost of Capital Income Taxation,'' Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86 (1978); and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, ``Intergenerational Transfers and Savings,'' Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 2 (1988). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- The complex estate and gift tax edifice rests on the foundation that taxing intergenerational wealth transfers results in less concentrated wealth holdings and that this leads in turn to greater economic opportunity and a more democratic society. If the tax's supporters cannot sustain the argument that the estate tax improves equality of economic opportunity, then there exists little else (except perhaps inertia) to recommend continuation of this part of U.S. tax policy. Other, simpler taxes could meet revenue objectives far more efficiently and fairly. Academic support for intergenerational wealth taxation remains warm, in large part because of the role it plays in the most important theoretical treatise on liberal egalitarianism, John Rawls's A Theory of Justice.\4\ Since its publication in 1971, this careful, magisterial presentation of the case for liberal democracy infused with just institutions has permeated thinking on most issues in social and political theory. It is fair to say that no stronger theoretical case for intergenerational wealth taxation exists. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \4\ John Rawls, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- At the center of Rawls's case for wealth taxation is the principle that ``[a]ll social primary goods--liberty and opportunity, income and wealth, and the bases of self-respect-- are to be distributed equally unless an unequal distribution of any or all of these goods is to the advantage of the least favored.'' \5\ While at first blush this principle would appear to suggest radical egalitarianism in economic and political life, Rawls recognizes the superiority of ``free'' over socialized markets to produce benefits for the least advantaged citizens, which leads him and many like-minded political theorists to support significant differences in the economic conditions of individuals within a generation. After a century of economic experimentation, there can belittle doubt that everyone achieves greater economic benefit when individuals are allowed to discover their own comparative advantage and focus their labor in the area where they can make the greatest economic difference. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \5\ Ibid., p. 303. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- This tolerance for intragenerational differences leads Rawls to oppose all income taxes, since economic income stems from natural differences in talent and from differing propensities of individuals to apply themselves to hard work.\6\ However, two principles considerations compel Rawls to take substantial exception to intergenerational differences in economic condition. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \6\ Rawls advances a consumption tax to replace income taxes. ``For one thing, it is preferable to an income tax (of any kind) at the level of common sense precepts of justice, since it imposes a levy according to how much a person takes out of the common store of goods and not according to how much he contributes (assuming here that income is fairly earned).'' Ibid., p. 278. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- First, Rawls opposes the transfer of accumulated property to succeeding generations because it undermines the first principle of a just society: that everyone has ``an equal right to the most extensive total system of equal basic liberties compatible with a similar system of liberty for all.'' \7\ Those who begin with a significant unearned endowment of property resources place others not so advantaged in a less equal condition, and this undermines the principle that everyone should have access to the same system of equal basic liberties. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \7\ Ibid., p. 302. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Second, this difference might be tolerated if it produced greater benefits for the least advantaged than for the advantaged. However, intergenerational wealth transfers create benefits that flow in the opposite direction: Over time, they enhance the advantages of inheriting generations and generally degrade the liberties of the unbenefitted. The ``[t]he taxation of inheritance and income at progressive rates (when necessary), and the legal definition of property rights, are to secure the institutions of equal liberty in a property-owning democracy and the fair value of the rights they establish.'' \8\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \8\ Ibid., p. 279. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- While Rawls does not advance confiscatory taxation of intergenerational wealth transfers, his argument does imply substantial taxing discretion by the state. In his universe, the state guides the institutions of distribution; should government determine that wealth transfers constitute significant barriers to the equal enjoyment of liberties (as defined by Rawls), it clearly has the power to tax away as much of the wealth that moves between generations as it deems necessary to restore justice. A number of objections could be raised against the Rawlsian case for wealth transfer taxation, not the least of them being the questionable assertion of government authority over the intergenerational disposition of private property. If wealth is acquired legally and transferred peacefully (that is, in some non-tortious fashion that breaches no contract pertaining to property), government has no ethical standing to interfere with its disposition. Of course, liberal egalitarians claim a more expansive role for government, a principal element of which is the progressive enhancement of equality of condition among citizens. Thus, it is important first to consider the estate tax within the context of the argument that justifies the tax's existence. If it can be shown that the estate tax does not advance the ethical program of the liberal egalitarians, then other objections to this tax that can be raised without assuming this ethical and moral framework become more compelling. This approach to analyzing the estate tax was taken in a seminal monograph by Edward J. McCaffery published in The Yale Law Journal in 1994.\9\ Professor McCaffery comes to the debate over the estate tax with impeccable political credentials. Unlike many critics of intergenerational taxation who frame their objections within a larger, politically conservative analysis of contemporary government, McCaffery formulated his critique of the estate tax within a liberal framework. As he stated last year before this committee: --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \9\ Edward J. McCaffery, ``The Uneasy Case for Wealth Transfer Taxation,'' The Yale Law Journal, Vol. 104 (November 1994), pp 283-365. I am an unrequited liberal, in both the classical and contemporary political senses of that word, whose views on social and distributive justice might best be described as progressive. I used to believe in the gift and estate tax as a vehicle for obtaining justice. As to the latter belief, only, I am now prepared to confess that I ``was blind, but now can see.'' \10\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \10\ Edward J. McCaffery, ``Testimony before the Senate Committee on Finance, June 7, 1995.'' McCaffery raises five general objections to the liberal egalitarian argument supporting intergenerational wealth taxation. Each of them assumes the ethical and moral objectives of the liberal program. 1) The currently combined income and estate tax system encourages large inter vivos gift transfers, which have the effect of creating a greater inequality of starting points or a less level economic playing field. This predictable effect of the estate tax law is aggravated further by the fact that high estate tax rates encourage the consumption rather than the transfer of wealth. Purchasing goods and services instead of saving the funds that support that consumption produces larger differences between rich and poor people. Thus, the estate tax is illiberal because it undermines rather than advances the liberal egalitarian objective of equality of economic opportunity. 2) While higher wealth transfer taxes might reduce the level of inter vivos gifts, and other tax law changes could be made to penalize the spending behavior of rich families, it currently is both practically and politically impossible to do so. On the one hand, analysts are becoming increasingly aware of the intergenerational focus of much current saving behavior at all income levels. Liberals should promote the creation of transferable wealth among the less advantaged. On the other hand, politicians are becoming increasingly aware of how much voters want taxes to fall, not rise. The estate or inheritance tax has been repealed in Australia, Canada, Israel, and California; and the movement for tax reform is a spreading, worldwide movement. 3) There will always be differences between the starting conditions of people in a non-ideal world. If liberal egalitarians attempted to eliminate all the differences that stem from intergenerational wealth transfers, they would risk leaving the least advantaged even worse off than they were before. Not only would confiscatory taxation reduce the consumption behavior of wealthy people, thereby also reducing employment and incomes among poorer citizens, but it would depress the amount of economic capital as well, thereby reducing economic expansion and income growth, both of which are central to improving the conditions of the least advantaged. 4) ``[It] is the use and not the mere concentration of wealth that threatens reasonable liberal values.'' \11\ Generally speaking, the accumulation of savings and the promotion of earnings that underlie the growth of savings are ``goods'' that liberals like. Earnings and savings create a ``common pool'' of resources that can be used to promote improvements in the general welfare through public and private means. Liberals generally regard the consumption behavior of the wealthy as objectionable; thus, wealth transfer taxation, which attacks savings and promotes wanton consumption, is wholly ill-suited to the attainment of an ideal liberal society. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \11\ McCaffery, ``The Uneasy Case for Wealth Transfer Taxation,'' p. 296. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- 5) The best tax policy that liberal egalitarians could pursue, if attaining liberal social and political objectives truly motivates the liberal program, is one that taxes consumption, not savings. McCaffery writes that ``[b]y getting our reasonable political judgments wrong--by taxing work and savings while condoning, even encouraging large-scale use [consumption]--the status quo impedes the liberal project.... The real threats to liberty and equality from private possession alone turn out, on closer scrutiny, to relate to possession qua potential or actual use, each of which can be addressed--indeed, can best be addressed--in a tax system without an estate tax.'' \12\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \12\ Ibid.; emphasis in original. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Not only, then, is the estate tax inconsistent with a liberal program of promoting quality of economic condition, but it encourages behavior that works against liberal objectives. It supports consumption and depletion by penalizing savings and earnings. it encourages the kind of strange world where it costs less for a millionaire like Steve Forbes to spend $30 million of his own money on a presidential campaign than to save $30 million for his children's future--an investment upon which he will pay 55 percent transfer tax as opposed to a campaign expenditure upon which no additional taxes are ever levied. How many new jobs and new businesses did Mr. Forbes's campaign create as opposed to the same amount saved in a bank that lends the funds to entrepreneurs and business managers? Liberals and conservatives are beginning to answer this question in precisely the same way. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Beach, and you certainly are the appropriate person to wind up this hearing today with your expertise in this field. I believe, personally, that if it were not for revenue implications--and that's what you addressed to a great degree in your testimony--we would be pursuing repeal of the death tax. Mr. Beach. I agree. Chairman Archer. And that the majority in this Congress, a majority that has had a new approach to things beginning in January 1995, would be supportive of that. Mr. Beach. Yes. Chairman Archer. But we do have to deal with the revenue constraints, and we do have to deal with the official estimates and not the estimates that come from Heritage even though in the end the estimates coming from Heritage, may prove to be more accurate. We have that limitation. Mr. Beach. That's right. Chairman Archer. And we are limited by the constraints of the Budget Act, such that--as I've been saying over the last few days--we cannot risk tipping the balance into a deficit again in this country. We're on the threshold of a balanced budget, which to me is a millennium in itself. It's a dream that I had when I came to Congress in 1971, but only a dream, and it is going to become a reality. We must adhere to that for the benefit of our children, and the death tax is relative to what's going to happen to our children too, which is awfully important. I hope that your data will be factored by CBO and the Joint Committee when they undertake their estimates on whatever proposal comes before the Congress, but we are forced to live with those official estimates of the Joint Committee and CBO. And as a result, even though it is a relatively small percentage of the revenue that comes into the Federal Government, it still is a significant amount of money unless we can get those estimates changed, so I personally will welcome your input, and I hope that it will be considered very carefully by the estimating agencies of the government. I thank all of you for your testimony, because I've said over and over again now for 2 or 3 years that the income tax is bad for this country because it puts all Americans in a tax trap: the harder you work, the longer you work, the more you pay, and that's wrong. But when you add the death tax on top of it, it becomes the harder you work, the longer you work, the more you save, the more you pay, and that is doubly wrong. That creates an environment that works against the best interests of all Americans, not just the producer but those who benefit from that production by having gainful jobs and the ability to support their own families. To me, that's the essence of what our country stands for: to encourage a work ethic, to encourage savings, and, thereby, to create more wealth that can be shared by all the people in this country. So, I am completely with you philosophically on what we need to do, but we have to work through this estimating process and these revenue estimates if you---- Mr. Beach. If I could just have one comment on that, Mr. Chairman. First of all, we've been blessed to work very closely with the Joint Committee and to learn how they work with their staff, and this Committee is well served by the Joint Committee staff. The revenue estimates I could disagree with, but the level of disagreement would be under $1 billion per year. But it is true--and I think your economists will privately tell you this as well--that here we're dealing with a tax issue that more even than the income tax has an economic story that needs to be understood. So, let me recommend this--knowing your rules, and knowing that you need to work with the static--what I call the static estimates--to ask the Joint Committee to do what it did last year and that is to bring several groups together each posed with the problem, measure the effects of the elimination of the estate tax, and have that report produced by whoever will now be the Chief of Staff and given to this Committee to inform them of the range of estimates--ours is one of those--that come from repeal. I think that information would be very informative to the Committee. It would do two things: It would move the estate tax forward, and it would also move this Committee forward, I hope, more closely to consensus, dynamic revenue estimating. Chairman Archer. Well, we began, 3 years ago, to get more behavioral response into the estimating process, as I mentioned during the discussion on the marriage penalty, and I'm pleased about that because I've been Chairman of the Joint Committee on Taxation as well as Chairman of the Ways and Means Committee, and I believe we should always strive for accuracy. I don't want something to come out because it weighs in favor of what I believe in that isn't accurate. That means that we do have to take into account behavioral response, and in the end we have to bridge the disconnect between the CBO and Joint Committee, and that disconnect is as follows: that the CBO, today, has a responsibility for the macroeconomic impact; that is, how many more jobs are going to be created, and how much extra income tax will flow into the Treasury as a result of whatever we do? The Joint Committee does not have the ability to do that, nor do they have, under the law, the responsibility to do that. They must accept whatever the baseline is that the Congressional Budget Office puts out, and then they must overlay their estimate as to the specific tax change, and the baseline that the CBO puts out is not changed to accommodate what impact the tax change will have on the economy. Now, that's our responsibility; to find a way to overcome that, and we're in the process right now of trying to work through that, but our goal should always be accuracy, and I just want to assure that I'm going to do everything I can to see that happen. Mr. Hulshof. Mr. Hulshof. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank each of you for being here, and Ms. Mizell, it's great to have your supporters here. It sounds like that straight-A 9-year-old fourth grader might have a future in politics someday. Mr. Beach, I want to be a devil's advocate for the brief moments I have, and I want to be, just for purposes of this question, as a hard as it is for me, an unrequited tax liberal. Mr. Beach. All right. Mr. Hulshof. And here is their argument: If the principle objective of our U.S. tax policy is to expand economic opportunities for disadvantaged Americans, and the way we do that is to redistribute income from one segment to another, then doesn't your proposal to repeal--and, again, this is a hypothetical--the fact that you're trying to repeal the death tax--shouldn't the Bill Gates of the world be required to pay to help provide economic opportunity for those on the lower rungs of society? What is the response to that liberal tax argument? Mr. Beach. Well, thank you for that question, and I know, Mr. Hulshof, that that was difficult question for you to ask. [Laughter.] It's an interesting response. The tax rate of the estate tax is so high that it does several things if you're wealthy. First of all, it tells you, ``Don't save your money, spend it today.'' So instead of saving money that creates jobs for ordinary Americans; that expands the economic pie--and by the way, that expands the income taxes that come into the Federal Government--what we have is a signal sent by the estate tax, ``Buy that cigarette boat; go to that vacation home in Vale, and buy expensive art in London.'' In other words, it supports consumption expenditures rather than savings. So, it doesn't have the effect that you would expect it to have on wealthy people. Now, wealthy people also have this advantage: They can hire Harold Apolinsky; they can hire the high-priced accountants and lawyers which allow them to find out early in life that they're going to have this problem and then to set in place a lifetime plan which is oftentimes very expensive of avoiding the 55, the 50, even the 35 percent tax rate. So, they have that ability, and the people that you've heard today generally do not; they're surprised by that tax. And then they can distribute their money through gifts and trusts and other kinds of things, again, expensive to their children and to other people. What happens when that happens? It maldistributes wealth. It perpetuates wealth just like the consumption of wealth maldistributes consumption. So, I think--and there are many other responses I could make here, but if you go down all of these responses and you talk to someone who's on the liberal side in a quiet moment in a bar perhaps, they have to conclude, ``This is the tax I have to oppose,'' because it is keeping people from entering the work force. It is telling people to consume and to--you know, conspicuous consumption, and we lots of pictures from Aspen and Vale are troublesome sometimes. It is undermining the income tax; it is hurting blacks and women, minority entrepreneurs, all of them. Mr. Hulshof. How so? How does repeal of the death tax--how would help the disadvantaged or minorities? Mr. Beach. Well, if I'm--let's suppose that I'm a Hispanic person and I have worked and saved and now I've opened a business and 20 years later this business is a big business for me; I've hired 5 or 6 people. Why have I done that? To provide a better life for my children. That's really the overriding thing. The intergenerational consideration of parents overrides money any day; trumps it. Let me give you the story of Wen Trac. She escaped from Indochina when she was 13 years old; illegally entered the United States--this is a documented case--and began to work the streets in Seattle--it was the only thing she knew how to do. She saved some money and she opened a bucket and washerboard business, and by the time she was 30 she had enough money to open a storefront drycleaning business; married, two daughters. Now, she's 72 years of age. She has two drycleaning businesses. She has learned that she's going to have to liquidate the entirety of her holdings in order to pay the estate tax. All of her savings was in that business, not in the form of cash, but in the form of a job for her two daughters, and those two daughters are now going to have to go back--maybe on the street, but certainly not where Wen Trac wanted them to go. And we all know the famous story of Mr. Thigpen. He was in the tree business, and he and his wife of 40 years working up a business--treegrowers of the year twice in a row. This is a wonderful business. Liquidating that business, and it's a very strong prospect. Mr. Thigpen, by the way, is a grandson of slaves that his son is going to have to go to work for one of the local Mississippi farmers. Now, they may be a white farmer. Is that the outcome that people on the liberal side want? Is that what they want for Wen Trac or the Hispanics or for the African-Americans? It's that contradiction which led Mr. McCaffery to depart and say, ``This is not consistent with the liberal vision of what taxes should do.'' We have spend 70 years now building a Tax Code that would help disadvantaged people and redistribute wealth. This is wrong; it is contradictory; it is inconsistent; it has to be excised from the body of Tax Code in order for the rest to be consistent. Mr. Hulshof. Well, I appreciate that, and your description of this conspicuous consumption suddenly brings the realization--my parents, I think, just put a new bumper sticker on their car that says, ``I'm spending my children's inheritance.'' I want to thank Mr. Chairman for the time and thank each of you for being here. Chairman Archer. Well, thank you, Mr. Hulsolf, and I'm grateful to all four you for the input that you've given the Committee today. I want to make one last comment, and that is relative to-- was it McCaffery that you said, Mr. Beach? Mr. Beach. Yes, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Who identified himself as a contemporary liberal and a historic liberal, or what was the other? Mr. Beach. Classical as well as contemporary. Chairman Archer. Classical as well as contemporary. And I would say that that is an oxymoron---- Mr. Beach. Well, that may be. Chairman Archer [continuing].--because I would refer everyone in this country to read the recent book on Thomas Jefferson called American Sphinx. He was the classical liberal, and I am identified as an 18th century liberal, and in today's contemporary times I'm identified as a conservative. There is no connection between the classical liberal and the contemporary liberal because Thomas Jefferson said, when the Constitution was being framed, No. 1, the Federal Government should never have any taxing authority. He was the classical liberal. The Federal Government should have no taxing authority. And then he, furthermore, said, during the creation of the Constitution, to his friend James Madison, ``Godsend that our Nation never have a government it can feel.'' Now I say to all of you, do you feel the estate tax, the death tax? Do you feel the income tax? Do you feel the government regulations? Do you feel the government programs from Washington? And I think the answer is very clear. Thank you very much. I wish you well. The Committee will be adjourned. [Whereupon, at 3:50 p.m., the hearing was adjourned subject to the call of the Chair.] REDUCING THE TAX BURDEN ---------- WEDNESDAY, FEBRUARY 4, 1998 House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, Washington, DC. The Committee met, pursuant to call, at 10 a.m., in room 1100, Longworth House Office Building, Hon. Bill Archer (Chairman of the Committee) presiding. Chairman Archer. The Committee will come to order. We're still awaiting our first witness, but in the interim, I would like to make a few comments and then recognize Mr. Coyne for what comments he might like to make. Today we hold the second in a series of hearings on proposals to reduce the tax burden on the American people. Taxes as a percentage of gross domestic product this year are at the highest level in our Nation's history in peacetime. Disappointingly, the President's budget increases taxes to an even higher level in 1999. High taxes represent a moral and a social challenge to families that are struggling to make ends meet. The more the government takes, the less the families have to invest in themselves, their children, their retirement, their health care, their education, and their communities. This year I intend to do two things: reduce the national debt and provide tax relief. If we fail to do both, millions of middle-income taxpayers, especially those who are planning for their retirements, will suffer. When the government takes away the resources people were counting on to help themselves, the people will turn to big government to solve their problems. High taxation creates an endless cycle of public dependency and too big government. Isn't it better to pay down the debt and reduce taxes so people have more money to spend on their own child care needs, health care needs, and everyday needs? They should be free to invest this money themselves. Today our hearing will look at tax rates--what they are, and what they should be. The Tax Code has five statutory tax rates, but according to a report released today by the Joint Committee on Taxation, 21 hidden tax provisions force more than 33 million Americans to pay higher taxes than they thought. These sneak attack tax hikes are akin to false advertising by the government. One in four taxpayers aren't in the brackets that they thought they were. For example, a senior citizen earning $30,000 a year who thinks that he or she is in a 28 percent tax bracket really pays a marginal rate of 42 percent, thanks to a phaseout of the exclusion for Social Security benefits. Five million seniors suffer that fate. A single parent making $40,000 a year with 2 children in college who thought that he or she was in the 15 percent bracket will pay a marginal rate of 53.5 percent, 53 and a half percent, due to the phaseout of the Hope scholarship that they are involved in. 1.2 million Hope scholarships taxpayers are hit by this sneak attack tax hike. The list goes on and on, but that's just under the regular rate. There's also the two-rate alternative minimum tax, which can kick in at unpredictable times. What throws you into the AMT? Three major things: paying State and local taxes, having children, and getting sick. Do those sound like tax shelters? I don't think so. According to Joint Committee estimates, the individual AMT, which applied to only 414,000 taxpayers in 1995, will hit 8.8 million in the year 2008. And that's just the taxpayers who will pay the AMT. There are also millions more who will lose some or all of their child credit, Hope credit, lifetime learning credit, dependent care credit, and other tax credits each year because credits cannot reduce regular tax liabilities below the AMT liability. The AMT is a tax hike time bomb. And it's disappointing that the President's budget leaves it ticking. Finally this morning we'll hear about a proposal to protect taxpayers who make as little as $26,000 a year by lowering the 28 percent tax bracket to 15 percent for millions of Americans. For every $5,000 the 15 percent tax bracket is expanded, each taxpayer affected would save $650. This across-the-board, middle-class tax cut would let 25 million Americans have more money to invest in themselves, their children, and their communities. It's another reason why reducing taxes solves more social problems than increased spending. Let me just close with a reminder as the Committee weighs the merits of various tax proposals. I intend to be conservative. I am not going to over-promise the American people and create unrealistic expectations. I will never, I repeat, never, tip the budget out of balance. And I will favor proposals that simplify the Tax Code. I will say to my colleagues that all of us are in for a rude awakening when we learn that the budget law, the PAY-GO provisions, which is the law of the land today, prohibit us from using any surplus moneys for tax reduction. And that in itself, unless it is changed, will severely limit the ability of this Committee to create a tax relief bill. I will add also that that same budget PAY-GO provision prohibits us from using any savings in discretionary spending for tax relief. I am going to do all that I can to see that this law is changed. But in the interim, it is going to be very, very difficult to be able to pass a tax reduction bill unless we simply increase taxes on somebody else, which results in no net tax relief. And that is not a desirable position for this Committee to take. So, having said that, I now recognize Mr. Coyne for any statement that he might like to make on behalf of the Minority. Mr. Coyne. Mr. Coyne. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for the opportunity to make this statement on behalf of the Ranking Member, Mr. Rangel. As we begin this hearing on Federal tax burden and as we begin putting together the tax component of the fiscal 1999 budget, I want to urge the Committee to take a serious look at the recommendations contained in President Clinton's budget regarding taxes. I believe that there is fairly broad bipartisan support for many of his provisions; for example, the low-income housing tax credit. Our colleagues Mr. Ensign and Mr. Rangel have introduced legislation to increase the State volume limitation on the low-income housing tax credit. I am a cosponsor of the bill, and there is a great deal of bipartisan support for the low-income housing tax credit. I would ask the Chairman to hold a hearing on this issue and to include this provision in the Chairman's mark that he will eventually present to the Committee. The President's budget request also recommended an expansion of the education zone program that was included in last year's Taxpayer Relief Act. This expansion would provide needed assistance to State and local governments in meeting the need to repair and construct public schools. Addressing this issue through the expansion of last year's act would help our community schools while minimizing bureaucracy and administrative costs. Many of us hope that there will be bipartisan interest in addressing the issue of tax credits for school construction bonds. I would also ask the Chairman to consider including this provision in his mark as well. The President's budget request included tax provisions to assist working families in meeting child care expenses. This, too, is an issue of bipartisan concern and interest. I hope that we can develop a bipartisan child care initiative similar to the one suggested by the President. The President's budget also proposes an extension of expiring Tax Code provisions like the research credit, the work opportunity credit, the welfare-to-work credit, and the brownfields tax incentives. I would hope that we could work together in a bipartisan fashion to address these issues as well. The hearings that we are currently engaged in seem to be designed to highlight some of the problems that exist in the current tax system. Such hearings can be very helpful to the Committee in suggesting important focal points for our tax reform efforts. Some of the issues that are being raised, however, like the marriage penalty, have been discussed in this Committee as long as I have served on it. We all agree on the nature of the problem and the need to fix it. The sticking point has always been how to fix such problems in a fiscally responsible way. I look forward to the Chairman's proposal for solving this difficult question, and I hope that we can work together to address it. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. The Chair thanks the gentleman for his statement. And now, without objection, any other Member will be permitted to insert a written statement into the record. [The opening statement of Mr. Ramstad follows:] Statement of Hon. Jim Ramstad, a Representative in Congress from the State of Minnesota Mr. Chairman, thank you for your leadership in examining the tax burdens confronting American families. I especially appreciate this focus on tax rates, which is fundamental to discussions of tax fairness. We know that more and more families are going to be pushed into alternative minimum tax situations, which is probably the only thing on earth worse than paying the ordinary income tax. And I am pleased we will be looking into the ``hidden rates'' in our tax code that effectively raise the tax burden beyond statutory rates. As you point out, Mr. Chairman, Americans are now paying more in taxes as a percentage of GDP than at any peacetime in history. I look forward to our discussion today and in the coming weeks, as we explore critical tax issues facing American families. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We now turn to our first witness, one of our own colleagues, Congressman John Thune. John, we're happy to have you before the Committee today, and we're pleased to receive your testimony. I will say to you and for the benefit of any subsequent witnesses that the rules of the Committee are not too different from other Committees. We're going to ask you to keep your oral testimony to 5 minutes. And the yellow light will come on in front of you when there's 1 minute to go, and the red light will come on when 5 minutes have expired. Your entire printed statement will, without objection, be inserted in the record. And that will apply to all witnesses. So we're happy to have you, John. You may proceed. Mr. Thune. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. STATEMENT OF HON. JOHN R. THUNE, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF SOUTH DAKOTA Mr. Thune. I do appreciate as most of you I think should have a copy of my written statement. And I will try as best I can to explain briefly these proposals and summarize my comments. Let me just start by saying that the reason I think we're having this discussion today is that we are for the first time in about 30 years in a position where we're talking about operating in the black, potentially having a surplus. And any time you do that, it's a situation where I think for some politicians, that's a dream, but for the taxpayers, it's a nightmare. My concern has been all along with respect to this issue that we look at putting aside money to retire the debt, to repay the trust funds. And, in fact, I am cosponsoring legislation which would do that here in the House. But I sort of got interested in this whole subject where these bills are concerned as I was listening some weeks and months ago to many of the President's proposals for new spending. The thing that struck me about that was that I think it's a very dangerous precedent to start embarking on a course of new spending because we are doing well today and building in a lot of new government programs into the base assuming that at some point in the future, we'll have the revenue to support those programs. And I'm not sure at this point in time we're prepared to make that assumption. So, as an alternative to that, people would ask me, ``Well, if you don't like what the President's proposal is with respect to child care, what do you have as an alternative?'' And so we started to think about that. Really, what we came up with were a couple of proposals that I think address the need but do it in a very different way. And that is to allow individuals and families to make the decisions about how they want to address those needs in their lives, rather than having a government solution to it. And so we drafted a couple of bills. Of course, let me just say also that I agree with you, Mr. Chairman, that anything that we do ought to be in the context of a balanced budget. We should not in any way finance any tax relief with our children's future. And so to the extent that we are able to do anything, I think it's going to mean it's because we have the room to accommodate and absorb within the budget any tax relief that we might put out there. Having said that, the two bills that I would bring before you today really are an attempt I think to do something which is sort of novel around here. One of the things that troubles me the most about many of the President's proposals is this obsession with targeting, you know, that we're going to try to pick winners and losers and we're going to please this group if you act this way. These bills really are designed to distribute tax relief in a broad, even way. And, frankly, as I look at the first bill, which raises the caps, the income caps, at which the 28-percent rate would apply, it does, in fact, take a number of people, about 10 million filers we're told in this country, out of the 28 percent bracket back to the 15 percent bracket and allows I think people who are trying to improve their lives, trying to do better to be rewarded and rather than as a disincentive push into a higher, much higher tax rate. And so it's a way which I think is very simple and clean, and that's the other aspect I like about that bill. With the whole issue of where we go in terms of tax policy in this country, I think it's the right approach. And when you made the comment in your opening statement about you're going to favor attempts to simplify the Tax Code, that, too, is a priority of mine and one reason why I think this particular proposal makes so much sense. It starts moving us to where we are getting more people paying at the 15-percent rate. And I think that's something that's a very positive development. The other bill just let me say briefly as well is a fairly straightforward, simple thing. And that is to raise the personal exemption for each individual taxpayer. When you sit down and figure out again who benefits from raising the exemption or from the raise in the thresholds, it does deliver tax relief to those in the middle- and low-income categories. Now, if you assume, of course, that the payroll tax comes off somewhere in the $60,000 range, you've got people who are caught in the middle there who are paying the payroll tax, the 28-percent rate. And I think what this does is you are really penalizing people in the middle-income categories. This attempts to correct that, and it also, with the personal exemption bill, helps those who are currently in the 15 percent tax bracket. So in trying to summarize all of that, what we were looking at doing with these is an approach which is simple, which is fair, which is a broad-based approach, rather than a targeted picking winners and losers, which treats people the same, whether they are married or whether they are single. I've had people ask me ``What does a single person get out of all of this tax relief?'' Most of the bills that we pass we say we're doing this for married people or married with children. And, again, this is not discriminatory in the approach. It's very straightforward. It's across the board. And I think it's the right approach for the future as we move toward what I hope will be a debate about tax reform, about how we can further simplify the Code and make it more friendly to the taxpayer. Let me just close by saying that I don't know what we might have in terms of budgetary constraints, what we might be able to accommodate in terms of a tax relief proposal this year, but to the extent that we can, my own view is having looked at a lot of the tax relief proposals that are out there, that this makes the most sense in my view and moving toward the long-term goal again of simplifying the Tax Code and of doing tax relief in a way that benefits everybody in this country and not a select few. So, with that, I will close. Thank you for the opportunity to present testimony this morning. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. John R. Thune, a Representative in Congress from the State of South Dakota Chairman Archer, members of the Committee, thank you for the opportunity today to talk about tax reform proposals. This is indeed an important and timely topic. The American taxpayers are on the verge of realizing the most significant tax cut in over 17 years. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 provided important relief for taxpayers at every stage of life from the cradle to the grave. At the same time, we did nothing to make the already complicated tax code any simpler. The passage of the Middle Class Tax Relief Act of 1998 and the Taxpayer Choice Act of 1998 would help us make strides toward tax relief that is both broad and simple. I also hope these bills can be considered as an alternative to future targeted tax cuts and as an alternative to new government spending. In his State of the Union address, the President outlined his policy goals. Now that his budget is out, we know his ideas translate into some $150 billion in new Washington spending. Most of us can agree with his goals. From important priorities like caring for and educating our children, to providing health care for an aging population. These are important issues. On that we all agree. However, the differences are clear in trying to determine how best to achieve those goals--particularly with the prospect of a revenue surplus. The President's programs mark an incredibly expansive reach by the federal government into the lives of Americans. At the same time, he is highlighting the need to reserve any surplus for Social Security. While I agree Congress must begin to restore the Social Security Trust Fund, the juxtaposition of saving and spending sends mixed signals to me and to the American public. There is a responsible approach to dealing with any potential surplus. Accordingly, I support an approach that would apportion any potential surplus to paying off debt and restoring the integrity of the various federal trust funds, while reducing taxes on hard working Americans. Such an approach would allow us to give something back to the taxpayers of this country. After all, it is their money. If the President is able to build $150 billion in new Washington spending into his budget, it would necessarily follow that the President and Congress could give back the same amount to the taxpayers. The best solution to helping working families deal with tough issues like child care is to give them some money back and allow them to make the best decision about how to address this important need. In order to provide for some tax relief that is both fair and effective, my friend and colleague from the State of Washington, Congresswoman Jennifer Dunn, and I introduced two pieces of tax relief legislation that I believe will serve as alternatives to the new Washington spending in the President's budget. At the same time, these bills are consistent with the dual goals of distributing tax relief broadly and evenly and of simplifying an inordinately complicated tax code. The first bill, the Middle Class Tax Relief Act, addresses the concept of ``bracket creep'' by allowing working Americans to enjoy success rather than suffer the penalty imposed by a significantly higher tax bracket. The Middle Class Tax Relief Act would lower taxes by raising the income threshold at which the 28 percent tax bracket would apply. Simply put, more income of working Americans would be subject to the 15 percent tax bracket rather than the much higher 28 percent bracket. This legislation would help middle income-earners who are doing better and making more, but as a consequence, have graduated from the 15 percent tax bracket. Due to bracket creep, 28 cents of each additional dollar they earn now goes to the federal government. Under our legislation, many of these hardworking people would have an incentive to continue to be hard working people, by removing the threat of a higher tax rate on each additional dollar they earn. And this relief pays no attention to family status or other behavioral factors. Presently, the higher 28 percent tax rate applies to a single person making more than $25,350. Our legislation would raise that threshold to $35,000. For heads of household, the 28 percent rate starts at $33,950. We would raise that to $52,600. For married couples, the 28 percent rate starts at $42,350. We would raise it to $70,000. According to the Tax Foundation, over 29,000,000 filers would see their taxes lowered under this proposal, with the average savings of nearly $1,200 per filer. Over 10 million filers would move out of the 28 percent bracket to the 15 percent bracket. A $1,200 tax cut could pay for sixteen weeks of child care, four car payments, and up to three months of housing bills, or fourteen weeks of grocery bills. That's real help for working families. The other bill I propose is the Taxpayer Choice Act. The Taxpayer Choice Act would raise the personal exemption from $2,700 to $3,400. The bill would reduce the taxable income of hard working Americans and allow them the freedom to choose how best to use the benefit of their tax reduction. By reducing taxable income by $700, this legislation would deliver broad based tax relief to taxpayers in the lower and middle income ranges. This change is straightforward and easy to calculate. For someone in the 15 percent tax bracket, I have estimated a savings of $100, or for a family of four, $400, or the approximate equivalent of five weeks of child care, a car payment, housing payment or five weeks of grocery bills. That's real relief and those are real life choices. For earnings in the 28 percent tax bracket, I estimated the legislation would provide $200 per individual, or $800 per family of four. That is approximately equal to ten weeks of child care, almost ten weeks of grocery bills, three car payments, or a couple of housing payments. As is true today, the deduction would phase out for wage earners whose incomes exceed $124,500. These bills both say to the people of this country: You have the freedom of choice. We trust your judgement. We believe you are capable of caring for your children and making good decisions about their future. We believe that as a matter of principle, America is infinitely better off when families and individuals are making decisions rather than Washington bureaucrats. As we reform the tax code, we should resist from targeting tax cuts. Too often, Washington has chosen to pick winners and losers as it moves to cut taxes. For too long Washington has tried to dissect our society as it attempts to do something as simple as lowering taxes. I supported last year's Taxpayer Relief Act, which had plenty of targeting in it. That law has made important changes in the tax code to lower the burden of many individuals and businesses. However, I believe we should strive toward a more perfect union and look for ways that allow all Americans--irrespective of marriage status, age, or heritage--to participate in the benefits of the greater freedom that comes with lower taxes. We should strive to make all taxpayers equal under the law. Furthermore, we should take a consistent approach to making the tax code simpler. Most of the tax relief proposals I have seen to date further complicate the tax code. Such efforts do not take us down the road toward a less intrusive and more user friendly government. I would like to come back to a point I made earlier. We agree with the President that working families in America need relief. However, the President has mistakenly interpreted that need as a request for more Washington spending and targeted tax cuts. What working families are really asking for is not more federal government, but relief from more federal government. At the same time, the two bills, the Middle Class Tax Relief Act and the Taxpayer Choice Act, both work toward a tax code that is more simple and more fair. Americans waste way too much time and money filling out tax returns. It's a dream for lobbyists, lawyers and tax preparers. It's a nightmare for the American taxpayer. The two bills I introduced yesterday are consistent with a simpler, fairer approach to the tax code. Now is the time to reform the code with a focus on inviting all Americans to participate in the benefits of a growing economy. These are our goals and I look forward to working with the Chairman and the rest of this committee to make these initiatives become a reality. Again, I thank the chair and would be happy to answer any questions you may have. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Congressman Thune. Does any Member of the Committee wish to inquire? [No response.] Chairman Archer. If not, I compliment you on your testimony. We're glad to have your entire statement. And we wish you well. Mr. Thune. Thank you. We need your help. Thanks. Chairman Archer. The next panel is: Dr. J.D. Foster; Mr. Michael Mares; Dr. Martin Regalia; and Mr. Kenneth Kies. I think all of you were in the room when I cited the rules the Committee likes to operate under in these hearings. So I won't repeat them but just to welcome all of you en banc, as it was, to the Committee. And according to the schedule before me, Dr. Foster will lead off. So if you are prepared, Dr. Foster, we will be pleased to receive your testimony. I would like to add one other thing in that I'd like for each of you to identify yourselves and if you're representing anybody, to identify who that is before you commence your testimony. Dr. Foster. Mr. Foster. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF J.D. FOSTER, PH.D., EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR AND CHIEF ECONOMIST, TAX FOUNDATION Mr. Foster. I'm J.D. Foster, the executive director and chief economist of the Tax Foundation. I appreciate the opportunity to appear before the Committee today. I personally think we have a very good reason to be talking about tax reductions today. The economy is producing tax revenues far in excess of what was projected just a few months ago. As the President's budget makes clear, the surpluses that we're looking forward to in the near future are largely the product of these revenues. So I find a certain simple logic for using some of these tax revenues for tax relief. In considering tax cuts, I think we should take a couple of lessons from tax reform. One of these lessons is the imperative of focusing on economic growth. Yes, it's true the economy is doing well right now, but that's no reason why we shouldn't allow it to do better. I believe tax cuts should always be gauged by their ability to encourage economic growth. A second lesson from tax reform is tax simplification. Complexity in the Tax Code is wasteful, and it is wrong. The one sure consensus on tax reform is that the Tax Code is too complex. Tax reform is not the issue today, but the lessons are the same. No tax cut should complicate the Tax Code. Every tax cut should be oriented toward encouraging economic growth. Reducing marginal tax rates hits on both counts. Reducing marginal tax rates has many other benefits, however. If your concern is the tax burden on families generally, then tax rate reduction is your answer. If your concern is the marriage tax penalty, tax rate reduction will help without the complexity inherent in many of the solutions we have been talking about. If your goal is to encourage private savings, then again tax rate reduction is your answer. This Committee has heard for years that Americans save too little. Assuming this is true, high marginal tax rates must bear much of the blame. People respond strongly to incentives and disincentives. Why do you suppose brokerage houses advertise track records of yielding value to investors if investors are not swayed by yields? Why do supermarkets advertise their prices in the local paper? Because even reductions in the price of a can of soup or a bunch of bananas is going to alter consumer behavior. Even the Tax Code relies heavily on disincentives to function. It has a highly developed system of tax penalties to discourage tax cheating. If monetary penalties discourage tax cheating, why would we think that high marginal tax rates wouldn't discourage saving? Reducing marginal tax rates and thereby reducing the tax burden on saving will increase national saving. If your goal in tax reductions is to increase investment in plant and equipment, then again tax rate reduction is your answer. Reducing marginal tax rates reduces the cost of capital, particularly if those rate reductions are extended to the corporate tax system. The 1997 tax bill was criticized because many provisions affecting individual taxpayers introduced new complexities in the Tax Code. I've attached to my testimony the new rules on capital gains and losses. These new instructions are mind- numbing. And it is wrong to inflict them on taxpayers. Despite these complexities, I believe last year's tax bill was a great victory for taxpayers. It slowed but did not halt the rising tide of taxes. And it may have ushered in a new era of tax cutting. However, it also opened up the Congress to real criticism for reasons beyond complexity. The bill created millions of winners, but it created a legion of the ignored. In appearance, this was rent seeking at its worst. This is not a game I believe the Committee or the Congress should be playing. The surest way to avoid this unseemly game while providing significant tax relief is to reduce tax rates. Tax rate reduction can be devised so that all taxpayers benefit and not just a select few. Tax rate reduction is simple. Many tax cut proposals are complex. Its simplicity encourages a sense of public fairness. Tax rate reduction is easy to explain and, therefore, easily garners public support. And tax rate reduction is very flexible. By lowering rates and raising bracket points, you can fine-tune the amount of tax relief that you want to give the American people. The opponents of marginal tax rate reduction are primarily special interests who want to get a bigger slice of the pie for their own constituencies, appropriate for a democracy but not the best way to reduce taxes in my opinion. Some might argue that we've reduced our statutory tax rates significantly over the last 17 years and we probably shouldn't go any further. This argument might be valid if we are only talking about whether to cut taxes. But once we're talking about cutting taxes, the argument has no merit. High marginal tax rates of the past were counterproductive and have been roundly repudiated. Today's rates have no basis in theory. They're a product of revenue requirements and politics. If the politics and the revenue requirements have changed and would permit tax reductions, then marginal tax rate reductions should be this Committee's primary goal. I believe it's time to create a virtuous cycle. Cut taxes to spur economic growth. Use the additional revenues from faster economic growth to cut taxes further and keep the process rolling. Cutting marginal tax rates I believe is your first best choice for tax reduction. They're your first best choice for creating this virtuous fiscal cycle. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of J.D. Foster, Ph.D., Executive Director and Chief Economist, Tax Foundation Mr. Chairman, Mr. Rangel, Members of the Committee, it is with great pleasure that I appear before this Committee to testify to the importance of focusing on tax rates as the centerpiece of any tax reduction program in 1998. I am the Executive Director and Chief Economist of the Tax Foundation. The Tax Foundation is a 60-year old non-profit, non-partisan research institution. Our mission is a simple one: To provide accurate and timely information on matters of federal, state, and local fiscal policy so that policymakers may make better policy. Mr. Chairman, we have good reason today to discuss tax reduction. We have an economy that is yielding tax revenues far in excess of official expectations of only a few months ago. This enormous revenue stream has created the possibility of budget surpluses in the near or very near future. While the caution previously urged by White House officials and others against a change in policy predicated on surpluses is well- taken, it is perfectly appropriate for this Committee to consider what actions it might want to take should a surplus arrive earlier than expected. Further, as this happy prospect of surpluses is the product of extraordinary growth in tax receipts, there is a certain simple logic to using the surpluses for tax relief. Another reason to consider tax relief is simply that taxes are now at their highest levels in our nation's history. Last year, Tax Freedom Day arrived on May 9, the latest day ever. Tax Freedom Day is a simple representation of the total federal, state, and local tax burden. If all of the average taxpayer's income goes to pay his taxes beginning on January 1st, then Tax Freedom Day is the day his annual fiscal debt to society is marked ``Paid In Full.'' Tax Freedom Day 1998 is almost certain to fall even later in the calendar. It's also important to rite last year's historic tax cut. Why is that? Because last year's tax cuts were slight indeed compared to the revenues produced by a strong economy. Which Taxes to Cut There are, therefore, very good reasons to consider tax reductions at this time. In establishing a tax cut program, I believe the Committee should take a couple pages from the tax reform debates. The number one tax policy lesson from these debates is the great imperative to get the tax base right. Economic distortions due to taxation are minimized when the definition of the tax base is correct. On the other hand, whatever the tax rate, economic distortions grow with each error in the tax base. A second lesson from the tax reform debates is the importance of tax simplification both economically and politically. Complexity in the tax code is wasteful and it is wrong. If there is anything about tax reform about which there is a general consensus, it is this--the current tax system is too complex. Perhaps if the Members of the Committee were required to do their own taxes as a condition for sitting on this Committee, then the proliferation of complex tax changes would cease halt. Of course, tax reform is not the issue here, today. But the lessons remain the same. In an ideal world the Committee's focus ought to be to effect tax policy changes that simplify the system and that move the federal income tax in the direction of a proper definition of taxable income. That would mean, for example, increasing as far as possible the ability of taxpayers to exclude capital income from taxation, eliminating that abomination of federal tax policy known as the Alternative Minimum Tax, and integrating the personal and corporate income taxes. To the extent reality impinges on this ideal world, as it must in a democracy, I would urge the Committee to eschew narrow, targeted tax changes in favor of reducing marginal tax rates. Whatever distortions exist in the federal income tax, and they are legion, they are given greater r are the marginal tax rates to which taxpayers are subjected. Conversely, reducing tax rates reduces virtually all the distortions created by the tax code that rob the economy of vitality and rob the American people of greater opportunity and prosperity. This Committee is fully versed in the distortions to the economy created by the federal income tax and in the multitude of opportunities for greater prosperity lost as a result. Therefore, I will not discuss them in great detail. Instead, I will briefly enumerate the most important of these. Income taxes imposed on wages and salaries reduce the incentive to work and, conversely, increase the incentive to take one's leisure. At very low tax rates, one's incentive to work is about equal to one's economic contribution to society. At low tax rates the price of leisure is high. At high marginal tax rates, one's return to work a few more hour's drops rapidly and the price of leisure drops along with it. Reducing marginal tax rates directly reduces the disincentive to work. This Committee has heard for years that the people of the United States save too little. Assuming this is true, the federal income tax must bear much of the blame. Despite the many slivers of tax relief available to some saving, current law continues to heap layer upon layer of tax on additional saving. In most cases, income is taxed as earned irrespective of what one does with it. If it is saved, it is likely to face multiple layers of additional tax in the form of taxes on interest, dividends, corporate income, capital gains, and estate taxes. People respond to incentives and disincentives. Why do brokerage houses advertise their strong track records yielding value to investors if investors are not influenced by yields? Why would car companies advertise price reductions, year-end discounts, and low financing rates if they fail to elicit more sales? Why do supermarkets advertise their sales in the local papers? Because even reductions in relatively low-priced items can alter consumer choices. The tax code has a highly developed system of tax penalties to discourage taxpayers from cheating on their taxes. Why would we believe that monetary penalties would be effective in discouraging tax cheating, and yet not believe that monetary penalties would be effective in discouraging saving? Reducing marginal tax rates and thereby reducing the tax on saving directly reduces the disincentive to save. To demonstrate how widespread would be the benefits of marginal tax rate reductions, consider: If a major concern is the tax burden on families generally, then rate reduction will help. If your concern is the marriage penalty, or even the single tax filer penalty, then rate reduction will help-- without the complexity inherent in most solutions to this problem. If your goal is to encourage additional investment in plant and equipment, then rate reduction is your answer because it would reduce the cost of capital, particularly if the rate reduction is extended to the corporate income tax rates. Rate reduction reduces the tax on dividend and interest income and, if extended to capital gains, it can further reduce the tax burden on capital gains. The 1997 tax bill was criticized, not entirely unfairly in my opinion, for being a hodgepodge of tax provisions, some large and some small. Many of the provisions, particularly as they relate to individual taxpayers, introduced enormous new complexities into the tax code. I have attached to my testimony the new rules appearing in this year's tax instructions for. These instructions are mind numbing. Indeed, perhaps the Committee could use these instructions as a simple test of the qualifications of any person seeking employment at the Joint Tax Committee: They must be able to explain this procedure, in English, after reading it through no more than ten times. I suggest few would pass the test. I believe last year's tax bill was a tremendous victory for taxpayers. The tax cuts slowed, but did not halt the tide of rising taxes and may have ushered in a new era of tax cutting. However, last year's tax bill also opened the Congress to real criticism for reasons beyond complexity. The bill created millions of winners, but it also created legions of the ignored. In appearance, at least, this was rent seeking at its worst. This is not a game I believe the Committee or the Congress should be playing. The surest way to avoid a similar trap and yet to provide significant tax relief is by reducing tax rates. Tax rate reduction can be devised so that all taxpayers benefit, and not just a select and well-represented few. There are other important reasons to favor tax rate reduction: It is simple. A great many tax cut proposals would increase the tax complexity hurdle for those lucky taxpayers who would qualify. It's simplicity further enhances a public sense of its fairness. The Congress would not be perceived as bestowing relief on a select few. It is very flexible. Through the lowering of rates and raising of bracket points, the Committee has a great ability to fine-tune the amount of relief, again without complex special rules and effective dates. And it is easy to explain and therefore easily garners credibility and public support. The case for making tax rate reduction a major component of any tax relief bill is so compelling it is worth considering why it might not be favored in some quarters. One valid reason for emphasizing alternate tax cut proposals would be if the Committee was to choose to correct the tax base instead. As noted above, taxable income is badly defined under current law. Working towards an economically sound definition of taxable income should always be a policy goal of the first order. A second source of opposition to across-the-board marginal tax rate cuts might arise from special interests who will fight to get a bigger piece of any tax cut pie for their own constituencies. Even when their objectives are sound, as is often the case, they put this Committee in the terrible position of playing Santa Claus to a select few. A good example of such a special interest is the ``pro-family'' groups whose efforts resulted last year in the child tax credit--an item of zero consequence for economic growth and one that specifically targeted certain beneficiaries to the exclusion of all others. This year these same groups are back fighting to eliminate the marriage tax penalty. The marriage tax penalty relates to the tax burden of some married couples relative to the tax they would owe if they were ``single'' filers. It is problematic. Yet for every four couples suffering from the penalty, there are five couples who pay less tax because of their joint filing status than they would had they filed single. If the pro-family groups were fightiress the marriage bonus families and the marriage tax penalized. To my knowledge, they are silent on the bonus, and so they stand self-indicted as purely special interests. Across-the-board rate cuts, in comparison, would benefit proportionately those subject to the marriage penalty, those subject to the marriage bonus, and all single tax filers. Finally, some might argue that statutory tax rates have declined significantly over the past 17 years, and that further reductions are therefore not needed. If one opposes tax reductions generally, then this argument is at least defensible. However, if the question is not whether to cut taxes, but how, then this argument is without foundation. The high marginal tax rates of the past were found to be counter- productive and have been roundly repudiated. Today's rates have no basis in theory. They are the product of revenue requirements and politics. If the politics and revenue requirements permit tax reductions, then marginal tax rate cuts should be the Committee's primary goal. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.082 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Dr. Foster. Our next witness is Dr. Regalia. And if you'll identify yourself, we'll be pleased to receive your testimony. Mr. Regalia. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF MARTIN A. REGALIA, PH.D., VICE PRESIDENT AND CHIEF ECONOMIST, U.S. CHAMBER OF COMMERCE Mr. Regalia. My name is Martin Regalia. I'm vice president and chief economist for the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. And we thank you for inviting us here today to testify. Well, few people actually like paying taxes. Most of us understand the need to pay tax to provide basic services, provide roads, infrastructure, national defense. However, we believe the government also has the responsibility to tax in a simple, efficient, and fair manner and to keep the overall burden on individuals and businesses as low as possible. Our Federal tax burden is too high. Total Federal receipts as a percentage of GDP were 19.8 percent in 1997, up from 17.8 percent just 4 years ago. We agree with you, Mr. Chairman, that Federal taxes as a percentage of GDP need to be reduced. And we appreciate your leadership in this area. The maximum marginal tax rate for individuals is now a stifling 39.6 percent and applies to income derived from sole proprietorships, partnerships, limited liability companies, and S corporations. In addition, the corporate income tax rates vary from 15 percent to a troubling 39 percent. Tax rates should be lower and less steeply graduated for all individuals and businesses. Furthermore, the Tax Code contains various hidden taxes created by phaseouts of tax benefits and tax floors for certain expenses. Some benefits phase out at a low level of income, yet are justifiable because they are intended specifically to benefit low-income taxpayers. Other benefits, however, such as itemized deductions and personal exemptions, phase out at middle and upper incomes and are really done so only to raise more revenue. While doing so, they create disincentives for work, savings, and investment. And the Tax Code should be adjusted to remove these disincentives. Social Security and Medicare taxes have climbed dramatically since their inception. The combined employer- employee tax rate for self-employed individuals, which self- employed individuals bear entirely themselves, is an astounding 15.3 percent, up from 9.6 percent in 1970 and 3 percent in 1950. These taxes should be reduced, or at a minimum, made deductible for income tax purposes. The Federal estate and gift tax is onerous tax which should be repealed or significantly reformed by further increasing the unified credit, reducing overall tax rates, and expanding the family-owned business exclusion. Another counterproductive tax is the alternative minimum tax. Originally envisioned as a method to ensure that all taxpayers pay a minimum amount of tax, the AMT penalizes individuals and businesses that save and invest, both requirements for economic growth. While the 1997 tax act made certain reforms to the corporate AMT, it did not fully repeal the depreciation adjustment or reform the individual AMT. The AMT should be eliminated. If that's not possible, additional reforms should be enacted, such as creating an exemption for unincorporated businesses, eliminating the depreciation adjustment, increasing the individual exemption amounts, and allowing taxpayers to offset their current year AMT with accumulated tax credits. The 1997 act provided approximately $151 billion of gross tax relief over the next 5 years. However, business and business-related tax and investment incentives accounted for a very small portion of those. We urge Congress to continue to reduce the Federal tax burden. And we think that there are a number of ways that they could do this. We think that permanently extending the research and experimentation and the work opportunity tax credits, further reforming Subchapter S rules, reforming the foreign tax rules, simplifying the worker classification rules, providing corporate capital gains relief, and increasing the equipment expense allowance are all areas for concern. Finally, we think that restructuring the IRS to make it a more efficient, accountable, and taxpayer-friendly organization is something that needs to be done now. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Martin A. Regalia, Ph.D., Vice President and Chief Economist, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, my name is Martin Regalia. I am Vice President and Chief Economist of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce--the world's largest business federation, representing more than three million businesses and organizations of every size, sector and region. The U.S. Chamber appreciates this opportunity to express our views on how to reduce the federal tax burden of individuals and businesses. I will be addressing various aspects of this increasingly growing problem, including high statutory tax rates, ``hidden'' taxes buried throughout the federal tax code, the alternative minimum tax for individuals and corporations, and additional tax relief measures which would reduce the overall federal tax burden. Our Overall Tax Burden is Too High Justice Holmes once commented that taxation is the price we pay for civilization. Let's face it, nobody likes paying taxes. However, most of us understand that our federal, state and local governments need to tax its citizens in order to provide basic services which we all want and expect (e.g., roads, national defense, schools). I suspect most individuals and businesses would not complain so much about taxes if they were fair, simple, properly administered, and promoted economic growth, saving, and investment. Unfortunately, our existing federal tax system fails to meet these basic criteria. Simply stated, taxes should be levied for the purpose of obtaining those revenues necessary to fund limited government expenditures in a way that minimizes their negative impact on taxpayers, overall economic growth and the international competitiveness of American business. History demonstrates that taxation carried to unreasonably high levels defeats its basic purpose by doing irreparable harm to the civilization and freedom that government is designed to protect. Aggravating the problem of overtaxation in America is the notion that the federal government wastes a good portion of its revenues on unproductive projects, services, and bureaucracies. The overall tax burden on American families and businesses is too high. According to the Tax Foundation, total taxes imposed on individuals as a percent of total income was almost 35 percent in 1996. Federal taxes accounted for 23 percent, while state and local taxes accounted for 12 percent. Based on this study, Americans work almost three months every year to support the federal government. According to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), total federal receipts, as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP), was 19.8 percent in 1997, up from 17.8 percent just four years earlier. Federal individual income tax receipts, as a percentage of GDP, has risen from 7.7 percent in 1992 to 9.3 percent in 1997, while the percentage for corporate income tax receipts has risen from 1.6 percent in 1992 to 2.3 percent in 1997. In addition, social insurance and retirement receipts, as a percentage of GDP, has increased from 1.6 percent in 1950, to 4.4 percent in 1970, to 6.8 percent today. Federal Tax Rates Need to be Lowered Federal individual income taxes are too high and need to be lowered. Generally, an individual's federal income tax liability is determined by multiplying his or her taxable income, or tax base, by the applicable tax rates, and then subtracting various tax credits. Overall income tax rates for individuals dropped significantly in the 1980's. The Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 reduced the maximum statutory tax rate from 70 percent to 50 percent, and the Tax Reform Act of 1986 further reduced it to 28 percent. However, the Tax Reform Act of 1986 also eliminated or limited certain deductions or exemptions, such as those relating to personal interest and passive losses, which expanded the tax base for many individuals. Since 1986, however, the maximum statutory tax rate has been increased, first to 31 percent in 1990, and then to 39.6 percent (36 percent plus a 3.6 percent surcharge) in 1993. Deductions and exclusions for individuals, on the other hand, have not been increased in equal measure. This is a primary reason why the federal income tax burden on individuals has increased over the last few years. For 1997, a 15 percent tax rate applies to the first $24,650 of taxable income for single filers ($41,200 for married couples filing joint returns). The marginal tax rate then almost doubles to 28 percent for single filers with taxable incomes between $24,650 and $59,750 (between $41,200 and $99,600 for married couples). The rate increases to 31 percent for single filers with taxable incomes between $59,750 and $124,650 (between $99,600 and $151,750 for married couples), and to 36 percent for single filers with taxable incomes between $124,650 and $271,050 (between $151,750 and $271,050 for married couples). For taxable incomes above $271,050, a maximum statutory 39.6 percent rate applies for both single filers and married couples. A taxpayer's effective maximum tax rate can be even higher when various phase-outs (e.g., certain itemized deductions, personal exemptions) are taken into effect. These tax rates are not only too high, but apply to most types of income, including those derived from a sole proprietorship, partnership, limited liability company or S corporation. This creates a disincentive for business owners to work longer hours and generate additional income since they realize that an ever increasing share of their income will be going to the federal government. At a minimum, legislation should be enacted to lower the maximum income tax rate on the reinvested or retained earnings of these business owners. Furthermore, the progressive nature of the federal income tax system causes many married dual-earner couples to be subjected to a ``marriage penalty''--that is, they pay more in combined income taxes than they would if they were not married and were filing single returns. This is simply unacceptable and needs to be remedied. The high rates of income tax imposed on corporations are just as troubling. The maximum federal corporate income tax rate is 39 percent, and applies to taxable income between $100,000 and $335,000. Taxable income in excess of $335,000 is subject to varying rates of 34 percent, 35 percent and 38 percent. The taxable income of certain personal service corporations, including those that perform health, law, consulting, and engineering services, is taxed at a flat rate of 35 percent. To make matters worse, certain amounts of corporate income are subject to double taxation--first at the corporate level, and then at the individual level when non-deductible dividends are distributed to shareholders. Small or family-owned businesses may be able to characterize most or all payments to their owners as deductible wages, rather than non-deductible dividends. However, such payments would have to be deemed ``reasonable'' compensation, and could be subject to a maximum individual income tax rate of 39.6 percent, as well as Social Security and Medicare taxes. Social Security and Medicare taxes, perhaps two of the most criticized taxes, have climbed dramatically since their inception. The combined employer-employee tax rate--which self- employed individuals must bear entirely on their own--is currently 15.3 percent, up from 9.6 percent in 1970 and 3 percent in 1950. The maximum taxable wage (and self-employment) base has also increased steadily, from $7,800 in 1971 for both Social Security and Medicare, to $68,400 today for Social Security, and an unlimited amount for Medicare. These two taxes have become a growing thorn in the side of American workers and businesses. Individuals must work harder and longer hours to fund these programs, which may or may not be fiscally sound when they retire. Regardless of whether Social Security becomes fully or partially privatized, we need to reduce the growing tax burden of this, as well as the Medicare, systems. At a minimum, such taxes should be deductible for income tax purposes in order to eliminate double taxation on the wage bases. The federal estate and gift tax is another tax which needs dramatic reform. This tax is extremely onerous, not only because it is triggered by death and is based on the value of a decedent's accumulated assets, but because its tax rates are so high and take affect at such a low threshold. For example, in 1997, a tax rate of 37 percent applies once a taxable estate exceeds $600,000. The rate quickly climbs to 55 percent once the taxable estate exceeds $3 million. In fact, a 60 percent rate applies to taxable estates between $10 million and $21 million. The estate tax should be repealed. If repeal is not feasible, significant reforms should be implemented. Such reforms include further increasing the unified credit, reducing overall tax rates, increasing and expanding the newly created ``family-owned business interest'' exclusion to encapsulate more businesses, and broadening the installment payment rules. There are other federal taxes which have high rates of tax. These include the federal unemployment tax (FUTA), alternative minimum tax on individuals and corporations, capital gains tax, accumulated earnings tax, personal holding company tax and various excise taxes (e.g., airline ticket tax, fuels tax). All of these federal taxes create an enormous financial drain on American individuals and businesses and dampen capital formation, job growth and work initiative. While it would be difficult for us to state with exact specificity the ideal tax rate for each type of federal tax, we do support lower and less steeply graduated tax rates for all individuals and businesses. ``Hidden'' Taxes Should be Eliminated In addition to the high maximum income tax rates, there are numerous provisions in the federal tax code which have the effect of increasing the effective marginal rates of tax on individuals and businesses. One of the more common forms of a ``hidden'' tax is the phase-out of various tax benefits (e.g., credits, deductions, and exemption amounts). Tax credits that phase-out include the earned income tax credit, dependent care credit, adoption credit, and the newly- enacted child and education tax credits. Tax deductions with phase-out ranges include those relating to individual retirement accounts (both deductible and non-deductible Roth IRAs), total itemized deductions, the $25,000 allowance for certain ``passive'' losses, and student loan interest expenses. Tax exemptions that phase-out include the personal exemption for both regular and alternative minimum tax purposes. The phase-out ranges for the above-mentioned tax benefits vary widely across the income spectrum. Some benefits, such as the earned income tax credit, phase-out at relatively low levels of adjusted gross income (AGI) (e.g., $30,095 for families with two children). Such phase-out levels are justifiable because the credits were intended specifically to benefit low-income taxpayers. Other tax benefits phase-out at middle- and upper-income levels. For example, in 1998, married couples who participate in employer-provided retirement plans are not eligible to deduct IRA contributions once their AGI reaches $60,000. Personal exemptions for single individuals begin to phase-out once their AGI reaches $121,200 in 1997 ($181,800 for joint filers). Certain itemized deductions begin to phase-out (up to 80 percent) once a single individual's or married couple's AGI reaches $121,200 in 1997. There appears to be no direct correlation between these benefits and the levels of income at which they phase-out. The phase-out ranges make no economic sense, and appear designed solely to reduce the benefits' costs to the federal government or to act as revenue-raisers for other provisions in the tax code. In addition, the tax code contains several percentage ``floors'' which must be exceeded before certain deductions can be claimed. For instance, qualified medical expenses are only deductible to the extent they exceed 7.5 percent of a taxpayer's AGI. Certain miscellaneous deductions, such as unreimbursed employee expenses and investment fees, must exceed 2 percent of a taxpayer's AGI before they can be deducted. These floors affect all taxpayers and should be reduced or eliminated to allow taxpayers to claim legitimate deductions. The Alternative Minimum Tax Must be Further Reformed One of the most counter-productive taxes ever created is the alternative minimum tax (AMT). Originally envisioned as a method to ensure that all taxpayers pay a minimum amount of taxes, the individual and corporate AMT penalizes businesses that invest heavily in plant, machinery, equipment and other assets. The AMT significantly increases the cost of capital and discourages investment in productivity-enhancing assets by negating many of the capital formation incentives provided under the tax system, most notably accelerated depreciation. The AMT cost-recovery system is among the worst of industrialized nations, placing our businesses at a competitive disadvantage internationally. To make matters worse, many capital-intensive businesses are perpetually trapped in AMT as they are unable to utilize their suspended AMT credits. The AMT is essentially a prepayment of tax which is substantially unrecoverable for most businesses. In addition, those not subject to AMT must still expend valuable time and resources in order to maintain several depreciation schedules and calculate the AMT. Significant reforms of the corporate AMT were enacted in the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. ``Small'' corporations (those with average gross receipts of less than $5 million in 1994, 1995 and 1996, $7.5 million in years thereafter) are no longer subject to the AMT. In addition, for all other corporations, depreciation recovery periods (e.g., 5-year property, 10-year property) used for AMT purposes are conformed to those used for regular tax purposes for property placed in service after 1998. The legislation, however, did not eliminate the AMT depreciation adjustment for recovery methods (e.g., accelerated versus straight-line depreciation). Therefore, depreciation will continue to be slower for AMT purposes than for regular tax purposes. Furthermore, the repeal of the depreciation adjustment for recovery periods only applies to assets placed in service after 1998. Therefore, all existing assets of corporate businesses will continue to be subject to this depreciation adjustment. Moreover, the recently-enacted tax law did not reform the AMT for individuals. A ``small business'' exemption was not created, the depreciation adjustment was not repealed or modified, and the AMT tax rates of 26 percent and 28 percent were not reduced. Furthermore, the AMT exemption amounts ($33,750 for single filers, $45,000 for married couples filing joint returns) were not increased to keep up with inflation or to take into account the new child and education tax credits. As a result, many individuals will soon find themselves subject to a tax they never even knew existed. Sole proprietors, partners and S corporation owners will continue to be exposed since their business income flows through to their individual income tax returns. According to the Joint Committee on Taxation, the number of individual taxpayers subject to AMT is expected to increase from approximately 600,000 in 1997 to 8.4 million in 2007, while the AMT tax burden is expected to grow from about $3.6 billion in 1997 to $18.4 billion in 2007. The best way to provide individuals and corporations with relief from the AMT would be to repeal it outright. If repeal is not possible, the AMT should be substantially reformed in order to reduce its harmful effects on businesses and individuals. Such reforms include: providing a ``small business'' exemption for individuals; eliminating the depreciation adjustment for both individuals and corporations; increasing the individual AMT exemption amounts; allowing taxpayers to offset their current year AMT liabilities with their accumulated minimum tax credits; and making the AMT system less complicated and easier to comply with. We urge you to enact these reforms as soon as possible. Additional Business Tax Relief is Needed The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 provided approximately $95 billion of net tax relief ($151 billion of gross tax relief) to families and businesses over the next five years. Gross business-related tax cuts, however, only accounted for about $19 billion of the total. While we commend Congress for enacting the legislation, we urge it to continue reducing the overall federal tax burden on the business community. We agree with you, Mr. Chairman, that federal taxes, as a percentage of GDP, need to be reduced, and appreciate your leadership in this area. There are many other tax issues of great importance to our members, and we look forward to working with you to further them in Congress. These issues include: Capital Gains Tax While the new tax law reduces the maximum capital gains tax rate for individuals from 28 percent to 20 percent (10 percent for those in the 15 percent income tax bracket), it also lengthened the holding period for long-term capital gains from 12 months to 18 months. This holding period should revert back to 12 months, and rates should be further reduced, if possible. In addition, capital gains tax relief is still needed for corporations, whose capital gains continue to be taxed at regular income tax rates. Equipment Expensing In 1998, businesses can generally expense up to $18,500 of equipment purchased. This amount will gradually increase to $25,000 by 2003. This expensing limit needs to be further increased, and at a faster pace, in order to promote capital investment, economic prosperity, and job growth. Foreign Tax Rules While the new tax law contains some foreign tax relief and simplification measures, our foreign tax rules need to be further simplified and reformed so American businesses can better compete in today's global marketplace. Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) While the new tax law expands deductible IRAs and creates nondeductible Roth IRAs, both types of IRAs need to be further expanded (e.g., increase contribution limits, eliminate phase- out ranges) in order to promote saving and personal responsibility. Independent Contractor / Employee Classification The current worker classification rules are too subjective and restrictive, and need to be simplified and clarified. We support the creation of a more objective safe harbor for independent contractors, while leaving the current 20-factor test and Section 530 safe harbors in tact. Internal Revenue Service Reforming and Restructuring The overall management, oversight and culture at IRS needs to be changed in order to make it a more efficient, accountable and taxpayer-friendly organization. We support legislation which the House overwhelmingly passed in November and look forward to working with you towards its enactment. Research and Experimentation (R&E) Tax Credit While the new tax law extends this credit through June 30, 1998, it needs to be extended permanently, and further expanded, so businesses can better rely on and utilize the credit. S Corporation Reform While the Small Business Jobs Protection Act of 1996 contained many needed reforms for S corporations, such as increasing the maximum number of shareholders from 35 to 75, there are many other important reforms which still need to be enacted, such as allowing preferred stock to be issued and creating family attribution rules. Self-Employed Health Insurance Deduction This deduction is scheduled to increase from 40 percent in 1997 to 100 percent in 2007. We believe this timetable should be accelerated to give self-employed individuals a full deduction as soon as possible. Work Opportunity Tax Credit This credit, which encourages employers to hire individuals from several targeted groups, needs to be permanently extended beyond its June 30, 1998 sunset date. Conclusion Our long-term economic health depends upon sound economic and tax policies. Our federal tax burden is too high and needs to be significantly reduced. In addition, our tax system encourages waste, retards savings, and punishes capital formation--all to the detriment of long-term economic growth. As we prepare for the economic challenges of the next century, we must orient our current tax policies in a way that encourages more savings, investment, productivity growth, and, ultimately, economic growth. Thank you for allowing me the opportunity to testify here today. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Dr. Regalia. Our next witness is Mr. Michael Mares. We're happy to have you here, and you may proceed. Mr. Mares. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF MICHAEL MARES, CHAIR, TAX EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE, AMERICAN INSTITUTE OF CERTIFIED PUBLIC ACCOUNTANTS Mr. Mares. Good morning. Good morning, Members of the Committee. I am Michael Mares, chair of the AICPA's Tax Executive Committee. We appreciate the opportunity to testify today on hidden tax rates and the individual alternative minimum tax, or AMT. Let me begin with the AMT, one of the most complex parts of our tax law. The AMT is designed to ensure that taxpayers pay a minimum amount of tax on their economic income. In many cases absent the AMT, taxpayers taking advantage of special deductions and exclusions would pay little or no tax. However, since the AMT exemptions and brackets aren't indexed for inflation, more and more taxpayers have been snared in the AMT's web over the past few years. In many cases, it is difficult or impossible to calculate the AMT without a great deal of added effort and time. Furthermore, the inclusion of adjustments and preferences from passthrough entities compounds the problem. Aggravating the situation is the AMT impact that the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 will have on middle-income taxpayers. For example, the child credit, the Hope credit, and the lifetime learning credit will not be able to reduce AMT. The result is that, as our examples in Appendix C show, a married couple with less than $70,000 of income can pay an alternative minimum tax or, worse, a single parent with only $45,000 in income pays an $800 AMT. Can these problems be reduced or eliminated? We believe so and would offer the following separate recommendations: first, index the AMT brackets and exemptions; second, eliminate itemized deductions and personal exemptions as adjustments for AMT; third, reduce the regular tax benefits of AMT preferences for all taxpayers--for example, by lengthening the depreciable lives for regular tax purposes, the AMT adjustment could be eliminated--fourth, allow certain tax credits against AMT, such as the child credit and the tuition tax credits; fifth, provide an exemption for low- and middle- income taxpayers from AMT if their adjusted gross income is less than $100,000; and, finally, consider the impact of AMT in all future tax legislation. Of course, repealing AMT would solve the entire problem for all individuals. We are also deeply concerned, as the Treasury pointed out, that AMT will apply to more and more taxpayers over the next few years, most of whom I could argue were never intended to be covered or affected by AMT. Since these taxpayers have little or no familiarity with the rules, it is likely that the IRS will need to allocate more resources to educate them and to answer their questions. The AMT also poses a compliance challenge to the IRS since many of the underlying adjustments or preferences appear nowhere else on a taxpayer's return. This makes verification of the calculation difficult. Another area of complexity is the hidden tax rate, also known as phaseouts of various benefits or credits over a wide range of incomes based on a variety of definitions of income. There is currently no consistency among phaseouts in either the measure of the income, the range of income over which the phaseouts occur, or the method of applying the phaseouts. Even filing status doesn't consistently affect tax phaseouts. For example, the individual retirement account deduction phaseouts vary for single individuals versus married couples filing a joint return. However, the phaseout range for the $25,000 passive loss allowance for certain rental activities is the same for both types of taxpayers. Further compounding the complexity is the fact that many of the phaseout ranges from married, filing separate taxpayers versus joint filers are not consistent. Simplicity can be achieved by eliminating the phaseouts altogether and, if necessary, making the politically difficult decision to raise tax rates to generate the needed revenue. However, significant simplification can be achieved by providing consistency in the measures of income, the range of income over which the phaseouts apply, or the method of applying the phaseouts. We suggest that there be three phaseout ranges: low-, middle-, and high-income taxpayers. Our written testimony in Appendices A and B contains our proposed ranges. We also suggest that the phaseout ranges for married, filing separate taxpayers, single taxpayers, and head of households be 50 percent of the phaseout range for joint filers. This would eliminate the marriage penalty as well. Finally, we recommend the deduction or benefit phaseouts evenly over the phaseout range. Phaseouts which are merely disguised tax rate increases create computational problems and frustrations at all levels of income. If they are to be retained, they should be standardized and applied consistently. This Committee has the opportunity as a result of these hearings to help the American taxpayer by eliminating or substantially reducing two areas of extreme frustration and complexity. The AICPA is willing to assist you in any way that we can to help resolve these issues. I will be happy to answer any of your questions. Thank you. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.083 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.084 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.085 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.086 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.087 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.088 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.089 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.090 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.091 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.092 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.093 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.094 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.095 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.096 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.097 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Mares. Our final witness is no stranger to the Committee. His leaving the Joint Committee was a great loss for the country, but we're happy to have him back in a different role. Ken Kies, you are now recognized. You need to identify yourself in your new role for the record, and you may proceed. Mr. Kies. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF KENNETH J. KIES, MANAGING PARTNER, PRICE WATERHOUSE LLP Mr. Kies. Actually, I think I am here in my role of cleaning up work that I did not finish when I left. So I'm here in my individual capacity having recently departed my position as Chief of Staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. My testimony centers on a study undertaken by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation on individual taxpayers concerning effective marginal tax-rate issues. The study was released yesterday. The study was requested by you, Mr. Chairman. You specifically asked that the Joint Committee staff identify situations where a taxpayer's effective marginal tax rate might differ from his or her statutory rate and the magnitude and impact of these differences. At the outset, let me explain what we mean by an individual's effective marginal rate. This concept differs from the Tax Code's five statutory marginal rates of 15 percent, 28 percent, 31 percent, 36 percent, and 39.6 percent, which apply to a taxpayer's taxable income within a specified range. The effective marginal rate seeks to measure the increase or decrease in an individual's tax liability that results from an additional dollar of income. An effective marginal rate of 40 percent would mean that a dollar of additional income would produce 40 cents of tax. In many cases, an individual's effective marginal rate will be higher than the so-called advertised statutory rate. This is because of various phaseouts, phase-ins, floors, and other provisions that limit the availability of deductions, credits, or exclusions based on an individual's taxable income. An example will help to illustrate. Take the case of the tax provisions requiring Social Security benefits to be included in taxable income as income rises above certain levels. For married taxpayers whose modified adjusted gross income exceeds $44,000, up to 85 percent of Social Security benefits are taxable. When this couple reaches the $44,000 threshold, each additional dollar of income will cause an additional 85 cents of Social Security benefits to be included in taxable income. This effectively raises the Federal marginal tax rate to 185 percent of the statutory rate because each dollar of additional income causes income to rise by a dollar while taxable income rises by $1.85. The Joint Committee study examines numerous provisions in the Tax Code that produce similar results. These include: phaseouts, phase-ins, and floors applicable to itemized deductions, personal exemptions, IRA contributions, and the child credits and educational tax credits added by the 1997 act among other provisions. All told, the Joint Committee study found that 33.2 million taxpayers, or one-quarter of all individual taxpayer returns, face effective marginal rates that are different from the statutory tax rates. Actually, taking into account the number of joint returns involved, approximately 50 million adult taxpayers are affected. The Joint Committee study also found that these differences are felt by taxpayers at all income levels. These differences have a real impact on individuals, as the Joint Committee study suggests. A chief concern is that high marginal effective rates can provide significant disincentives to work and save. For example, a retiree considering whether to take a part-time job may conclude that the payoff as subject to an effective tax rate that greatly exceeds the statutory rate is insufficient to offset the loss of leisure time and effort expended. Particularly harsh results can arise when a taxpayer is subject to more than one of the phaseouts at the same time. It is possible for the interactions of the phaseouts to create marginal tax rates that could be considered excessive. In one hypothetical example discussed in the Joint Committee study, a retiree with two children in college could face an effective marginal rate as high as 90 percent. Actually, as the footnote to the study indicates, when State taxes are taken into account, that taxpayer's effective marginal rate exceeds 100 percent. That particular taxpayer, by the way, was a taxpayer in the 15 percent marginal rate bracket. The Code's floors and phaseouts also raise equity issues. On the one hand, these provisions in many cases operate to increase the progressivity of the Tax Code by increasing average tax rates as income rises. On the other hand, almost all the provisions reviewed in the pamphlet of the Joint Committee create what economists refer to as horizontal inequities. Two different taxpayers may have the same income. One can be subject to a phaseout while the other is not, resulting in significantly different effective marginal rates for these otherwise similarly situated taxpayers. Another cause for concern is complexity. Many of the phaseouts and floors require additional computations, increasing compliance burdens, and enhancing the likelihood of error. These provisions also may make the Code less transparent, leading to taxpayer confusion regarding the nature of the income tax. The end result may be greater taxpayer disillusionment, a sense of unfairness, and reduced compliance. I commend the Joint Committee study for your review as you continue efforts to refine the tax system and provide tax relief. The report lends support to the view that hidden tax rates and their impact should be among the primary factors weighed by policymakers in evaluating future changes to the Code. I thank you for the time, and I would be happy to take any questions, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Kenneth J. Kies, Managing Partner, Price Waterhouse LLP Good morning, and thank you for inviting me to testify at this important hearing. I am appearing today in my individual capacity, having recently departed my position as chief of staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. My testimony centers on a study undertaken by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation on individual effective marginal rate issues, which was released yesterday. The study was requested last November by Chairman Archer. He specifically asked that the Joint Committee staff identify situations where the taxpayer's effective marginal tax rate might differ from his or her statutory tax rate, and the magnitude and impact of those differences. At the outset, let me explain what we mean by an individual's ``effective marginal tax rate.'' This concept differs from the Tax Code's five statutory marginal rates of 15 percent, 28 percent, 31 percent, 36 percent, and 39.6 percent, which apply to a taxpayer's taxable income within a specified range. The effective marginal rate seeks to measure the increase (or decrease) in an individual's tax liability that results from an additional dollar of income. In many cases, an individual's effective marginal rate will be higher than the advertised statutory rates. This is because of various phase- outs, phase-ins, ``floors,'' and other provisions that limit availability of deductions, credits, or exclusions based on an individual's taxable income. An example will help to illustrate. Take the case of the tax-law provisions requiring Social Security benefits to be included in taxable income as income rises above certain levels. For married taxpayers whose modified AGI exceeds $44,000, up to 85 percent of Social Security benefits are taxable. When this couple reaches the $44,000 threshold, each additional dollar of income will cause an additional 85 cents of Social Security benefits to be included in taxable income. This effectively raises the federal marginal tax rate to 185 percent of the statutory rate, as each dollar of additional income causes taxable income to rise $1.85. The JCT study examines numerous provisions in the Tax Code that produce similar results. These include phase-outs, phase- ins, and floors applicable to itemized deductions, personal exemptions, IRA contributions, and the child tax credits and education tax credits added by the 1997 Act, among other provisions. All told, the JCT study found that 33.2 million taxpayers--or one quarter of all individual taxpayer returns-- face effective marginal rates that are different from their statutory tax rates. (Actually, taking into account the number of joint taxpayer returns involved, approximately 50 million adult taxpayers are affected.) The JCT study also found that these differences are felt by taxpayers at all income levels. These differences have a real impact on individuals, as the JCT study discusses. A chief concern is that high marginal effective tax rates can provide significant disincentives to work and save. For example, a retiree considering whether to take a part-time job may conclude that the payoff--if subject to an effective tax rate that greatly exceeds the statutory rate--is insufficient to offset the loss of leisure time and the effort expended. Particularly harsh results can arise when a taxpayer is subject to more than one of the phase-outs at the same time. It is possible for the interactions of the phase-outs to create marginal tax rates that could be considered excessive. In one hypothetical example discussed in the JCT study, a retiree with two children in college could face an effective marginal tax rate as high as 90 percent. The Code's floors and phase-outs also raise equity issues. On one hand, these provisions in many cases operate to increase the progressivity of the Tax Code by increasing average tax rates as income rises. On the other hand, almost all of the provisions reviewed in the JCT pamphlet create what economists refer to as ``horizontal'' inequities. Two different taxpayers may have the same income and one can be subject to a phase-out while the other is not, resulting in significantly different effective marginal rates for these otherwise similarly situated taxpayers. Another cause for concern is tax complexity. Many of the phase-outs and floors require additional computations, increasing taxpayer burden and enhancing the likelihood of error. These provisions also may make the Code less ``transparent,'' leading to taxpayer confusion regarding the nature of the income tax. The end result may be greater taxpayer disillusionment, a sense of unfairness, and reduced compliance. The issue of effective marginal tax rates becomes even more complex--and can produce even greater distortions and inequities--when one also takes into account the alternative minimum tax, payroll taxes, and State income taxes. I commend the JCT study for your review as you continue efforts to refine the tax system and provide tax relief. The report lends support to the view that ``hidden'' tax rates, and their impact, should be among the primary factors weighed by policymakers in evaluating future changes to the Tax Code. Thank you for your time. I would be glad to answer any questions you might have. Chairman Archer. My compliments to all four of you. I think you have all given us superb testimony to focus on a part of the Tax Code that we have not looked at enough in the past. Allow me to comment on a few points. Dr. Foster, you said that over the last 17 years, we have reduced the rates. I guess you excuse 1990 and 1993. Mr. Foster. Well, we've reduced the rates compared to where they were 17 years ago, sir. Chairman Archer. Right. We did for a while, but then we went back up the ramp again. I wanted to make that very clear. Mr. Mares, do you have any estimates of the revenue impact of the phaseout recommendation? Mr. Mares. No, sir, we do not. Chairman Archer. That's going to be very, very important within the constraints that we're going to have as to what we can do in the way of tax reduction. Mr. Mares. Mr. Chairman, I think, though, it's important to note that we believe by establishing standard phaseout ranges for low-, middle-, and high-income taxpayers and adjusting those ranges to meet the revenue needs, that simplicity can be achieved to a large degree without a significant revenue detriment. Chairman Archer. Well, that's good to hear because the Committee should look at that type of simplification provided that we do not embrace an awful lot of revenue losses. Then you get into the politics of it. If you are trimming down the revenue losses, you very possibly are taking away something from a particular group. Mr. Mares. Yes, sir. Chairman Archer. It sounds a lot easier as you present it than it may be for the Committee to enact. I think you had a very complex recommendation as to what we ought to do on AMT. In the end, you said: Well, maybe it's better to abolish it. I am not sure that we gain, over the long term, an awful lot by simply chipping around the edges in implementing the kind, although meritorious, of suggestions that you made. I am wondering what all of you would think about eliminating the AMT and, in the process, carefully looking at those items that get thrown back into the formula for the AMT to determine whether they are legitimate in a bipartisan way as tax policy and then if they are legitimate, to let them continue to be used by all taxpayers and not come back in and thrown in this alternative minimum tax. It might very well mean that we'd have to shave back some of those deductions or apply them a little differently but, in doing so, be able to eliminate the alternative minimum tax. Do you want to comment on that? Mr. Mares. I will start, Mr. Chairman. I think when you look at the adjustments and preferences that create the alternative minimum tax, you can break them into two broad categories: what I will call the business deductions; that is, the difference in depreciation, the difference between percentage of completion versus completed contract and construction contracts; and what I will call the individual preferences, the elimination of the personal exemption, the State income taxes, which were mentioned here frequently, and so forth. One of the things I think it's important to point out is that for individuals, many, many of those individuals driven into the AMT find themselves being in AMT because of those individual preferences. And if you were to eliminate those individual preferences and allow the same deductions for AMT, such as interest, taxes, medical expenses, miscellaneous itemized deductions, and so forth, I believe you would solve a tremendous amount of the individual AMT problems. Now, as to modifying the various preferences or adjustments that make up the business aspects of AMT, that certainly---- Chairman Archer. I was speaking more of the individual side. Mr. Mares. Well, these are. These business preferences directly impact individuals. I have a number of individuals who operate through partnerships, S corporations that are directly affected by these. By reducing the regular tax benefits of these various preferences--again, depreciation is a good example--you could eliminate the need in those specific areas for an AMT to address the preferences that Congress believes should be addressed. Chairman Archer. Well, the Committee should look at that. We have a responsibility to continuously look at the Code from a policy standpoint and determine what is an appropriate deduction and what is not. I really have always felt that our responsibility should be devoted to that, rather than this arbitrary alternative minimum tax, where we tell people: Well, it's all right for you to tax this. I sit next to my friend Charlie Rangel from New York. In 1986, there was a proposal to eliminate the deductibility of State income taxes. That was the proposal put before this Committee on tax reform. The New Yorkers came in and strongly said: ``Well, wait a minute. We can't support tax reform if you don't give us deductibility of State income taxes.'' That's a major item of expense for their people. They succeeded in placing the deductibility of State income taxes into the tax reform bill. Now you're telling me State taxes are one of the major things that cause you to pay more Federal taxes. So, on the one hand, the New Yorkers thought they were doing something to give an appropriate--and they articulated it very well--deduction for income tax purposes. Now we find that it's a major factor in snapping back with a tax on those very same people through the alternative minimum tax. So they did not succeed. Now, that seems rather inconsistent to me. I hope the Committee will take a long look at how we can work to have a better Tax Code and get completely rid of this extra formulation, which is so arbitrary under the minimum tax. So I thank you for your input on that. Now, Dr. Regalia said that we have a 39.6 top marginal tax rate. After you listen to Mr. Kies, that is not so. I think on behalf of full disclosure and truth in legislating, we should put into every new proposal a requirement that it state the true effective tax rate. We do it on many other things. Of course, the purpose of these hearings is to dig into what really are the effective tax rates. One thing none of you mentioned which also gets into play on this is that if you have one spouse that is earning significant income and the other spouse is not gainfully employed and the other spouse decides, ``Well, gee, I want to go out and dabble and start my own little business,'' or whatever else, ``I want to have my place in the sun,'' the first dollar of their income comes in at the highest marginal rate of the other spouse. For no extra benefits, they also begin to pay the 15.3 percent payroll tax. Now, paying that tax when you earn a benefit is one thing, but the other spouse will not receive an added benefit. He or she will receive the benefits through the other spouse's activities. So the marginal rate is in an approximate 60 percent range for the activities of the second spouse. Now, is that a deterrent against somebody trying to gainfully produce something? Of course, in most instances, the extra spouse would be a woman, not always, but in most instances. Is this not denying women, married women, a real equal opportunity to earn something in their own right? Am I missing something or do you---- Mr. Kies. One of the things that the study of the Joint Committee on Taxation did in terms of looking at the marginal tax rates, at least indirectly, was to focus on the impact on incremental work effort, whether by the primary income earner or a secondary income earner. Certainly in the case of the second spouse, the disincentive to be economically productive, to go out into the work force is quite substantial because of the high marginal tax rate that may immediately impact the second earner. Chairman Archer. Particularly if they're self-employed when they go into the workplace. I again want to just add to this idea that the top marginal rate is 39.6 percent. I wonder if Michael Jordan believes that because his Medicare premium is $1 million a year. No matter how much he earns, he is going to continue to have to pay an additional 2.9 percent. And that's certainly in income tax. He's not getting an additional benefit for doing that. I thank you very much. I now yield to Mr. Rangel for any inquiry he might like to make. Mr. Rangel. I have no questions, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Any other Member of the Committee wish to be recognized? Mr. McCrery. Mr. McCrery. Thank, Mr. Chairman. I don't have any questions, but in looking over the Joint Committee's report, I just want to highlight for the Committee's attention some of the numbers that were brought out by the report. They were alluded to but not mentioned specifically. For the AMT, Mr. Chairman, in 1998, it's expected that 856,000 citizens will file returns that will be affected by the AMT. Ten years from now, though, only 10 years from now, that number will be 8.8 million Americans, from 856,000 to 8.8 million in only 10 years. That's an appalling figure to me. We're talking about in other forums right now changing the Tax Code. The reason that I'm interested in changing the Tax Code is because of the huge compliance costs of the current tax system and the drag on our economic production that it creates. Imagine--and you mentioned, Mr. Chairman, the reformulation that we have to go through on our tax returns to figure the AMT. Imagine that if we expand it by--I don't know. I can't even figure the math it's so high, 10 times perhaps over the next 10 years. I mean, that's just a mind-boggling calculation. The compliance costs are going to get so much worse in this country. It's something that we really need to pay attention to. And I'm glad that the Chairman asked these witnesses to highlight the AMT in their testimony. I think it's a part of the Tax Code that just begs for attention. And we ought to do away with it, but, short of that, we certainly ought to raise the exemptions or tie the exemptions to inflation so we don't catch all of these millions of Americans that aren't affected now. Chairman Archer. Mr. Kies, would you like to comment? Mr. Kies. Mr. McCrery, can I just add one other thing to that? To underscore the concern you have raised, it should be noted that the growth that's going to occur in the number of taxpayers subject to the AMT will occur in what I think has traditionally been thought of as relatively middle-income classes of taxpayers. In 1998, the $50,000 to $75,000 expanded income class--so that's not taxable income. That's beyond gross income in many cases. The number of taxpayers will go from 68,000 returns or 0.3 percent of all returns subject to the individual AMT, in 1998 to 1.3 million returns, or 5.8 percent of all returns in 2007 subject to the individual AMT. In the $75,000 to $100,000 income class, it will grow from 1 percent of all returns subject to the individual AMT in 1998 to 19.7 percent of all returns in 2007. So it's a 20-fold increase in the number of taxpayers in those income classes, which has not traditionally been thought of as taxpayers that would be the targets of the AMT. Mr. McCrery. Absolutely. That clearly demonstrates that this thing is out of control. It's affecting people that were never intended to be affected by the AMT, Mr. Chairman. And I'm hopeful that you'll continue in your effort to---- Mr. Levin. Would the gentleman yield? Mr. McCrery. I'd be glad to yield. Mr. Levin. Just, Mr. Kies, maybe you know the answer because I think that the figures are striking. What's the cost of remedying? Mr. Kies. Well, Mr. Levin, one approach to solving this problem that we've talked about a lot is just indexing the exemption amount because that would substantially restrain this migration of taxpayers from the regular tax to the AMT. The cost we estimated a year ago, or the Joint Committee estimated a year ago, over 10 years was $33 billion. The key to this, Mr. Levin, is the longer you wait to try and correct the problem, the more expensive it will be because it's in the out years that there's this very dramatic up turn of the number of taxpayers. Mr. Levin. So it goes up every year, but it's $33 billion over time? Mr. Kies. Yes, it goes up every year, but in the out years, it's going up much faster. Mr. Levin. Right, right, right. Mr. Kies. So each year you wait, those out years get more expensive. Mr. Levin. Thanks for yielding, Mr. McCrery. Mr. McCrery. You bet. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. None of you mentioned specifically, but last year on a bipartisan basis, the Congress and the President gave a significant child credit in the Tax Code to help families meet the expenses of rearing their children, $500 per child, which they are free to spend and invest in their children's education or anything else that they wish. It was agreed after considerable deliberation that for a joint return, it would be given in full up to $110,000 of adjusted gross income a year. It would then begin to phase out, depending on the number of children, for AGI up to roughly $150,000. The credit would be given in full to families who had taxable income of under $110,000 of adjusted gross income on a joint return. Now, what is the reality of the impact of the alternative minimum tax on the ability of those families to be able to get what the Congress promised them? Mr. Kies. Mr. Chairman, because the child credit cannot be used against the AMT, there are millions of taxpayers who will either not get the credit or will get less than the full credit who are below that phaseout range at the top. This will occur because of the fact that either they will be pushed into the AMT or they won't be pushed into the AMT but because their regular tax liability can't drop below what they would pay under the AMT, the credit is useless to them because it cannot be used against their regular tax either. So each year it will become a larger number, but it's in the millions of taxpayers that will be affected. The Joint Committee pamphlet does lay out some of the statistics on that, but I think as many as 15 million taxpayers will receive either a zero child credit or less than the full child credit, much of which is because of the AMT effect. By the time we get to 2008, There will be 21.7 million taxpayers affected by this. So that's going to grow over time as well. Chairman Archer. Thank you. Mr. Portman. Mr. Portman. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to start by congratulating the Ways and Means Committee for having these hearings and for taking seriously the prospect of moving forward with what I consider to be real simplification of our current Tax Code that makes sense but makes it more honest. Mr. Chairman, given your propensity to want to pull the Tax Code out by the roots, I want to commend you particularly for, despite your strong views on that, looking seriously at this and kind of peeling back the layers of the onion to try to figure out what the real problems are in our current Tax Code. Mr. Mares, as you know, we looked into these hidden taxes a lot in the context of the IRS Commission, really from the perspective of the IRS, and also, of course, from the perspective of the taxpayer. But it's a nightmare for the IRS to administer the phaseouts. The AMT is the same way. And, as Ken has pointed out consistently over the last year or so, as the AMT, as Mr. McCrery says, begins to affect more and more middle-income taxpayers, that complexity will only be increased, not just for the taxpayer but for the IRS. And it's a tremendous challenge. We've got a good report here from Joint Tax that I think gives us a lot of the intellectual framework to be able to move forward with this. And, again, I want to really thank the Chairman for bringing this up to the surface. The President has given us about 100 to 150 billion dollars' worth of new spending. So we're in an interesting position, really, for the first time since I've been here, in 5 years, maybe the first time in a couple of decades, where we actually have the ability to talk about some of these tax law changes because so many of them are so costly. Ken pointed out that it will cost $30 billion over 10 years just to index the exemption for personal AMT, not even getting to repeal it or adjust the corporate side. So I hope we'll take advantage of that, the little bit of a buffer we have now, and maybe talk a little less about spending and a little more about how to get people real relief. My question is: How do we get at this? Does it make sense assuming that we can't use that $100-$150 billion in total or that it's not enough, which is I think a pretty good assumption? Does it make sense, instead of having phaseout, Mr. Mares, from your point of view to do something else in terms of gaining back some of that revenue such as adjusting rates or is that too controversial to get into? Mr. Mares. I think clearly that's the Congress' decision as to how to spend the budget surplus, whether it's through tax deductions, debt reduction, or additional spending---- Mr. Portman. Let's assume for argument's sake--I mean, I agree with that, I hope we can use some of that so-called surplus we don't have yet but at least use some of that new spending the President has in his budget and put it into tax relief through simplification along the lines of what you're talking about. Let's assume, though, that we don't have all of that to use, that we need to come up with new revenue in order, let's say, to take care of either the personal AMT or to do something with these phaseouts; in other words, to make the Tax Code more honest so people are actually paying the rate they're supposed to pay. Would you recommend, if necessary, raising marginal rates in order to take out the hidden taxes? Mr. Mares. That is the most direct and honest way to tell the taxpayers what they will be paying. And if that were the price of eliminating the complexity within the phaseouts, where the taxpayers are already paying the rates---- Mr. Portman. Some taxpayers are. Mr. Mares. Pardon me? Mr. Portman. Some are, and some aren't. Mr. Mares. A great number of taxpayers are. With the alternative minimum tax affecting, even as Mr. Kies pointed out, middle-income taxpayers, there are already hidden rates built in there. By eliminating those phaseouts and putting the rates where they need to be to generate the revenue, I think you're telling the American public: Here's what we need to operate the government. Here's the rate that we feel is appropriate in a straightforward manner and at the same time simplifying the tax preparation jobs of millions of taxpayers. Mr. Portman. Mr. Kies, you're no longer in public service. You can now speak honestly. Do you have a comment on that? Mr. Kies. I thought I always did speak honestly. Mr. Portman. On that specific idea. Mr. Kies. Yes, on this one. Raising the marginal rates to eliminate the phaseouts. Mr. Portman. And AMT. Mr. Kies. I think you should---- Mr. Portman. Be honest about it. Mr. Kies. [continuing]. I recommend you proceed very cautiously with that solution. Mr. Portman. Politically I know that's difficult. Mr. Kies. No. But the problem is if you do what is proposed, it could invite bringing back the phaseouts later on. And all you would do is just get higher effective marginal rates in the long run. I think you really need to just basically consider whether these phaseout provisions really make sense and whether they're necessary and appropriate given what they do in terms of creating high hidden marginal tax rates. And the AMT question is to some extent--it's part of the problem, but it's to some extent a separate problem because it's really a question of: Who do you want the AMT targeted at? Clearly when you have a nonindexed exemption amount, you are going to over time sweep in a whole bunch of people that really have no business being in the AMT at all, no matter what their marginal tax rate is. I see them as, while related, somewhat separate issues. Mr. Portman. So if your choice was to slightly raise the marginal rate and eliminate the AMT or keep the AMT and index for inflation, you would take the index? Mr. Kies. I think I would take the index. Mr. Portman. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Mr. English. Mr. English. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Regalia, in your testimony, you talked about the need to make further changes in the AMT. You also referenced the work opportunity tax credit. I wonder how you or your association would feel about placing the work opportunity tax credit and/or the welfare-to-work tax credit in a position where it would be available for use by AMT companies if we come up short of actually abolishing the AMT. Mr. Regalia. Well, at the risk of more complexity, I think that certainly the more exemptions you bring into the AMT to lower the effective rate of that tax by making the type of credits that you talk about available to those companies would be of benefit. I think that as an economist, I would have to look at that solution kind of as the second order of smalls. I mean, it really is a very modest approach to addressing a problem that I think requires a more substantial fix. Mr. English. Well, and, as I point out to my wife, sometimes modest is affordable, too. I mean, that's another angle on it. And on the point of harmonizing the phaseouts, Mr. Mares, can you summarize for us what effect the phaseouts have on the marriage penalty currently in the Code? Mr. Mares. We think it has a relatively significant impact because not all of the phaseouts for married filing separate are 50 percent of the married filing joint. Likewise, the phaseouts in many cases--and, again, because there's no consistency, it's difficult to sit here and say this phaseout is consistent, this one isn't. The phaseouts for single and heads of household are often but not always about 75 percent of the phaseout for married filing joint returns. So by standardizing the phaseouts, by making single phaseouts, head of household phaseouts, and married, filing separate phaseouts, 50 percent of married filing joint phaseouts, you would help reduce the marriage penalty and provide consistency. Mr. English. Dr. Foster, in your testimony, you said something that I think in Washington is considered radical, although I think it makes a lot of sense to me, and that is that savings rates are to some extent sensitive to tax rates. What is the body of scholarly economic opinion on that? And are there economic studies that you can offer to this Committee to support the notion that when you change the incentives in the Tax Code, you can dramatically increase the savings rate? Mr. Foster. Yes, sir. The body of scholarly knowledge is all over the map. You find a pretty uniform distribution from those who think there's almost no effect to those who think it's absolute and complete. There are a lot of studies that will show that savings do respond to changes in effective tax rates on saving. There are a lot of studies to show that labor will respond dramatically to changes in effective tax rates. And then there are a lot of studies that show just the opposite. It's amazing to me that much of economics is based on the assessment and analysis of the price mechanism and how people will react and then so many economists go out of their way to find studies to show just the opposite. Mr. English. Dr. Foster, let me just say that since I support your view on this, I'd welcome any studies that you could throw our way that would support the position that I intuitively support. And I appreciate your testimony. Mr. Kies, I was wondering: Do you have any recent revenue estimates on the exemption in the current law for State and local taxes since the Chairman brought that up? Mr. Kies. I believe, Mr. English, in the tax expenditure pamphlet published by the Joint Committee on taxation there is some information about the impact of the State and local tax deduction, which was published, I believe, this past December. So there is some current information on that. And certainly the Joint Committee could you provide you with any updated information as well. Mr. English. Thank you. And I want to compliment you in your testimony on your explanation of marginal tax rates. Do you feel that marginal tax rates have a significant impact on work effort? Mr. Kies. Mr. English, my own personal view is that they clearly do. As Mr. Foster pointed out, there are people that fight over this issue. Some believe that the higher the marginal tax rate goes, that some people will work harder to be able to hold themselves economically where they were before the rate was raised. However, clearly at some point, people will prefer leisure time over further work if the return from work is so small. The one example that's illustrated in the Joint Committee study, where an ostensibly 15 percent marginal rate taxpayer could actually be subject to an effective marginal tax rate in the excess of 100 percent is a pretty graphic example of where it's extremely unlikely that such a person is going to try to work harder because you can't catch up if you're subject to a tax rate of over 100 percent. Mr. English. Thank you, Mr. Kies. That's a powerful insight. And I appreciate this panel and the perspective you have brought. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Mr. Weller. Mr. Weller. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Again I want to commend you for this series of hearings, which is looking at ways of not only simplifying the Code but also to find ways to allow working, middle-class families to keep more of what they earn. I think these hearings continue to work in that direction. I'd like to direct my questions to Dr. Foster. I was looking with interest at your testimony. And you were somewhat critical of some who have been involved in the effort to eliminate the marriage tax penalty. I noticed in your testimony that you are essentially arguing that we should be looking to eliminate the bonus or so-called bonuses, which would be a tax increase for those couples. I find when I talk in the district that I represent and I'm out listening to the folks in the portion of Chicago that I represent or the south suburbs of Chicago, that sometimes their ability to grasp the concept makes it difficult for us to explain it. The marriage penalty is an issue they relate to. And they understand a large number of married couples pay, 21 million couples, on average about $1,400. When it comes to a discussion of rates and changing the rates, they have a harder time understanding how it will affect their pocketbooks because their first concern is: If we adjust the rates, how will that affect my family? What will we see as a net or a negative impact? I've used as kind of an example in the district that I represent a machinist at Caterpillar and a schoolteacher with a combined income of about $61,000 who on average pay a $1,400 marriage tax penalty when they file jointly. I was wondering if you could tell me what type of rate reduction would be necessary to eliminate that $1,400 marriage tax penalty for that machinist and schoolteacher in my district who make about $61,000. Mr. Foster. I'm quite sure it's a significant rate reduction. The marriage tax penalty is without a doubt a terrible thing to have in the Tax Code. And it's a product of a number of factors. My point with the marriage tax penalty is only that by focusing on it to such an extent, we're ignoring vast legions of taxpayers. Tax relief I believe ought to be general and not specific to specific groups. The marriage tax penalty when you focus on it and fix it, you're focusing an awful lot of tax relief on a fairly narrow group of people. So that's the reason I brought the marriage tax penalty up in that discussion, not that we shouldn't address it. We should. But you can address it in a lot of ways. You may not fix it entirely. In fact, I'll be surprised at the end of the day when legislation finally passes if we've fixed the marriage tax penalty to the point where that entire $1,400 penalty is gone. There will probably be a modest fix to it. I'd rather get the modest fix through a rate reduction than through something that will further complicate the Tax Code. Further, I would be surprised if in general taxpayers have any more difficulty understanding a rate reduction than any other tax reduction you can imagine. The marriage tax penalty is somewhat difficult to calculate for the taxpayers involved. If I tell them ``I'm going to reduce your tax rate, statutory tax rate, from 15 to 14 percent'' or ``28 to 27'' or perhaps even ``eliminate these phaseouts,'' it's hard to imagine anything that would be easier to understand. Mr. Weller. The question that I get is: What does a change in 1 percent mean for me? I mean, that's the type of question I'll get in a response, whether I'm at a union hall or the VFW, a chamber of commerce, a business and professional women's club, the type of response. I was just wondering: To eliminate that average marriage tax penalty of $1,400, can you give me a projected rate reduction that would be necessary to achieve that? Mr. Foster. No, I can't. I think Ken probably can. Mr. Weller. Mr. Kies, could you? Mr. Kies. If the family's gross income is approximately $60,000, and assume their taxable income, just to take a rough number, might be around $40,000. That family is probably in the 28 percent marginal rate bracket. Thus, a 1-percent reduction from 28 to 27 would save them approximately $400 of income tax. So you'd have to take them down about 4 percentage points to eliminate at $1,600 marriage penalty, roughly speaking. Mr. Weller. Thank you very much. That's the answer I was looking for. Thank you Chairman Archer. Mr. Nussle. Mr. Nussle. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My questions go more toward what I have been learning in the town meetings I have been holding over the last 3 months in my district. I was pretty proud of the work that we had done as a Committee last year on some tax relief. When I went home and actually discovered what the negotiations and compromises and deals and agreements with the White House ended up in meaning as far as complications in the Tax Code, I discovered that maybe we could have or should have left well enough alone with all of the complaints that I received. I don't agree with that. I am very proud of the work that we did. But my point is this: There's a big difference between targeted tax breaks and tinkering. I guess that's what I'm concerned about. Targeted and tinkering is what I think we run the risk of doing. I know that part of the reason why we're having these hearings is because we're in the context of a possible budget surplus and we're looking for ways to deal with that surplus. I'm just wondering from all of you if it's worth the effort to go through this again in a very small, targeted, tinkering sort of way, as opposed to putting all of our efforts into what Mr. Foster described as certainly the ideal world of tax reform and total simplification. I would much rather see in this endeavor--in a year when we're not sure what the surplus is going to be, when unintended consequences and complications continue to be the hallmark of any reforms that we seem to go through, is it better to just leave well enough alone, store away the surplus as a squirrel would store away the nuts during winter, and wait for a better playingfield to play on, and work more toward tax reform and simplification, as opposed to tinkering? That's kind of my overall question. And I guess, Mr. Kies, since we don't get to pick on you anymore behind closed doors, we'll pick on you first in front. I just want to congratulate you on your service and wish you the best of luck in your new endeavors. And I'll give you the hot potato first. Mr. Kies. Thank you, Mr. Nussle. I think the answer to your question is that there isn't only one squirrel. And one squirrel may put the nuts away, but there's a bunch of other squirrels that are going to come after him. So you'd better be prepared to figure out what you want to do with the nuts. I guess my recommendation to the extent you're going to focus on tax relief is you try to focus on things that either address problems like this alarming individual AMT problem, which will be a simplification move because to the extent you can reduce the number of taxpayers that are going to be pushed onto the AMT, that's an improvement. And the other recommendation is that you then try and to the extent that you're designing tax relief to keep simplification in mind. For example, on the marriage penalty, one element of the marriage penalty is the fact that the standard deduction for a married person is less than twice that of a single person. You could increase the standard deduction for a married person to equal twice the single person standard deduction and add no complexity whatsoever to the Code because it would simply increase their standard deduction, no new complexity. Another obvious example of where you could deliver broad- based tax relief without adding complexity is to widen the 15 percent marginal rate bracket, which would be an across-the- board benefit to all taxpayers generally speaking, but it wouldn't add any new complexity. I would recommend you consider those types of approaches, as compared to the kind of more targeted things that have phaseouts associated with them, that have complex new sets of rules that the IRS will be required to administer, that taxpayers will have to deal with and that tax return preparers need to learn and apply. I think it really is time to step back and not direct tax relief in that manner because I think people need to be able to digest what happened in the 1997 Act. Mr. Nussle. My only point--you know, I agree with you. There are certainly more squirrels that have different ideas of what to do with the surplus. My only concern is that we've got the House. We've got the Senate. We have the White House. We've got all sorts of interest groups and people that have special concerns about the Code. And by the time we get done with a very simple idea, which could take a page for you to write this, we're off into some--and it's amazing to me how many people came up to me in my town meetings and just said: Look, folks, thank you for the very nice little tax relief you gave us. Certainly it will add a lot more paperwork and complication. Please this time, please don't simplify it any more than you already have. Keep it. Store it. Put it toward the debt. Don't spend it. And let's not worry about tax relief. Focus on tax reform. I was amazed how many people that would automatically, you would think, in a very knee-jerk sort of way move toward tax relief. I was very surprised at their comments. So I appreciate your testimony today. And I think you're right. If we can't keep it simple, we ought to just forget about it and store those nuts for the rainy day that we know is coming. Chairman Archer. We do have to vote. I think we have probably pretty well worn you out now. So unless there's objection, you're excused. And we will go vote. Then we will come back rapidly after we vote on the last 5-minute vote and attempt to get the next panel before the Committee. The Committee will stand in recess. [Recess.] Mr. McCrery [presiding]. If we could have everybody's attention? We have completed testimony and questions of the first panel. If the second panel could come forward and take their seats, I believe Chairman Archer will be here momentarily. And as soon as he arrives, we can begin. If we can get everybody to come forward and have a seat from the last panel? Thank you all for coming forward and having a seat. We're trying to find Chairman Archer or some other Members. I feel lonely up here. I don't want to be your only audience. We expect more Members to be here momentarily. We just had a vote on the floor. We were supposed to have a second vote on the floor, but it did not occur because we voice-voted that issue. And I'm afraid some Members may be confused on the floor. So we're waiting to give them a chance to get back. OK. At this time, we'll hear from the last panel on the hearing concerning reducing the tax burden. We're pleased to have with us today: June O'Neill, the Director of the CBO; Stephen Moore, director of fiscal policy for the CATO Institute; Abram J. Serotta, partner, Serotta, Maddocks, Evans and Co. from Augusta, Georgia--and I believe Congressman Norwood is going to further introduce Mr. Serotta in just a moment--Robert A. Blair, chairman and president of S Corporation Association; Wayne Nelson, president, Communicating for Agriculture. I'm told that Ms. O'Neill has another engagement this afternoon where she has to give testimony. So she may have to excuse herself before this panel has completed its testimony. And, Ms. O'Neill, certainly feel free to leave to satisfy your other obligations. At this time, we'll begin with Ms. O'Neill. STATEMENT OF JUNE E. O'NEILL, DIRECTOR, CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE Ms. O'Neill. Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, I thank you very much for inviting me to testify on the issue of marriage penalties and bonuses today. As you know, the Congressional Budget Office published a study of marriage and the Federal income tax last summer. This morning I will summarize the highlights of the study. I will also very briefly summarize the highlights of my prepared testimony, which I would like to submit for the record. Mr. McCrery. Without objection, all written testimony will be submitted for the record. Ms. O'Neill. The current U.S. tax system is not marriage- neutral. More than 20 million married couples pay higher taxes than they would if they were single. They incur a marriage penalty averaging $1,380 per couple. However, another 25 million couples get a marriage bonus. As a consequence of marriage, they save about $1,300 per couple in taxes. In recent years, a growing number of married couples have paid marriage penalties, raising questions of fairness. But it is also important to consider other issues, such as effects on work and marriage, that arise from the tax treatment of families and individuals. Marriage penalties and bonuses are byproducts of attempts by the Congress to balance the tax treatment of families and individuals while preserving other desired features of the tax system. On the one hand, the Tax Code seeks to levy the same tax on couples with the same money income. On the other hand, it tries to minimize the effect of marriage on a couple's tax liability. However, a tax structure with progressive rates cannot attain both goals. The incompatibility of progressive rates, equal treatment of married couples, and marriage neutrality results in a continuing tension within the Tax Code. Before 1948, the income tax was levied on individuals, so marriage had no effect on tax liabilities. But in 1948, the Congress enacted joint filing for married couples, who were now taxed on their combined income. Progressive tax rates and income splitting served to lower the tax liability of most couples at that time. Thus, the marriage bonus was created. Two decades later, in 1969--in response to complaints from unmarried taxpayers about singles' penalties, the other side of the coin--the Congress made the tax schedule more favorable to single filers. That action established marriage penalties. Changes in tax law since that time have shifted the balance between penalties and bonuses. In the late seventies, the size and incidence of the marriage penalty increased as inflation pushed marginal tax rates higher. In 1981, Congress made an explicit effort to reduce marriage penalties by enacting the two-earner deduction, which allowed two-earner couples to deduct 10 percent of the earnings of the low-earning spouse, up to $3,000. The Tax Reform Act of 1986 eliminated the two-earner deduction, but at the same time it sharply reduced the importance of marriage penalties and bonuses by flattening the tax rate structure. The pendulum swung in the opposite direction with the addition of three rate brackets in 1990 and 1993. Those and subsequent changes in 1997 had the effect of increasing the size of both penalties and bonuses. Along with changes in the Tax Code, the dramatic rise in married women's work participation and earnings over the past two decades has increased both the fraction of couples paying penalties and the average size of those penalties. Between 1969 and 1995, the fraction of working-age couples in which both spouses had paid employment increased by half, from 48 percent to 72 percent. Over the same period, the incomes of husbands and wives in two-earner couples became more nearly equal. Greater equality of earnings between spouses makes marriage penalties more likely and larger. Three-quarters of all two- earner couples now incur a marriage penalty. By contrast, ninety percent of one-earner couples get a bonus. Penalties affect two different sets of taxpayers, but for different reasons. At the middle and top of the income distribution, the progressivity of the tax rate structure, tax rate brackets, and limits on credits and deductions cause most penalties. For low-income couples, however, the earned income tax credit generates most penalties. The EITC, begun in 1975, provides tax relief for low-income working families with children, but it is also a source of marriage penalties for those families. Subsequent increases in the credit have only worsened its impact. Much of the current concern about marriage penalties revolves around the question of whether it is fair for two people to pay higher taxes just because they are married. However, marriage penalties affect how much couples choose to work and even whether they marry or divorce. CBO estimates, for example, that because of the work disincentives associated with joint taxation, the total earnings of married couples are roughly 1 percent less than they otherwise would be. Increases in the incidence and size of marriage penalties have brought renewed interest in reducing them. The problem is difficult to fix, however, and satisfying every goal is not possible. Furthermore, changes that reduce marriage penalties can have unintended impacts. Options to reduce marriage penalties range from relatively minor alterations in the current Tax Code, such as restoring the two-earner deduction, to more significant changes, such as allowing couples to file single returns, all the way to comprehensive tax reform. Any change that reduces or eliminates marriage penalties faces an inevitable tradeoff. Lower taxes for some couples entail either reduced Federal tax revenues or higher taxes for other taxpayers. Revenue-neutral options necessarily redistribute taxes from people now incurring penalties to other taxpayers, either couples who now receive bonuses or single filers. Avoiding such redistribution could result in large revenue losses, but at the same time, some options would lower marginal tax rates, thereby inducing some couples to work more and pay additional taxes that would offset the revenue losses. Despite the thorny issues raised, public discussion of the subject, such as this Committee's hearings provide, is helpful in identifying tradeoffs within the tax system and the importance of such considerations in possible designs for fundamental tax reform. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of June E. O'Neill, Director, Congressional Budget Office [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.099 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.100 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.101 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.102 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.103 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.104 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.105 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.106 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.107 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.108 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.109 Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Ms. O'Neill. I know you have some time constraints. So at this time, if any member has questions for Ms. O'Neill, ask now or let her go. [No response.] Mr. McCrery. Thank you very much, Ms. O'Neill. We understand you have---- Ms. O'Neill. Thank you. Mr. McCrery [continuing]. Some more testimony to give at another meeting. So you're excused. Next we have Mr. Serotta. I'm going to jump Mr. Serotta ahead so that Congressman Norwood can introduce his constituent and then---- Mr. Norwood. Thank you very much, Mr. McCrery. I do appreciate you and all the Members of the Committee and Chairman Archer holding this very important hearing that is near and dear to all of the working people of America. And we are grateful for you focusing on this today. Mr. Chairman, it's a real honor for me to introduce to the Committee today one of Augusta, Georgia's finest: Abram Serotta. Besides being a very dear friend of mine, Mr. Serotta currently serves as the president of Serotta, Maddocks, Evans and Co. in Augusta, Georgia. He works in all areas of taxation and is in charge of SME's health care services. He is a frequent lecturer on college campuses and he has published several articles, and is currently a contributing writer and editorial adviser to the Practicing CPA, which is published by the AICPA. Accounting Today elected Mr. Serotta as one of the hundred most influential CPAs in the United States. And I'm pleased to tell you that they did that before he made that large contribution to their magazine. Seriously, Mr. Chairman, it is an honor for me to introduce my good friend to your Committee this morning. And I am confident that his testimony and responses to the panel's questions will make everyone in this room today a little wiser. And though, Mr. Chairman, I know I need not say this, you do know, all of you know, April 15 is coming very soon. And I ask you to be very kind and gentle to my CPA. That's the last thing I need is a CPA mad at me. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Norwood. And with that buildup, Mr. Serotta, it had better be good. You may proceed. STATEMENT OF ABRAM SEROTTA, SEROTTA, MADDOCKS, EVANS & CO., AUGUSTA, GEORGIA Mr. Serotta. I appreciate, Mr. Chairman, the opportunity to testify before the Committee today on alternative minimum tax and hidden rates. I'm a member of the American Institute of CPAs, but I'm here in conjunction with conversations that I've had with Congressman Norwood about ideas of tax reform and tax simplicity. As he stated, I'm a CPA in Augusta, Georgia. We file about 3,000 tax returns. I consult and teach other CPAs. So my views are shared by many other CPAs as well as thousands of taxpayers that we represent. I'm here today to represent the CPA in the field, not in the academic world, the one that's administering, implementing the tax laws that you in Congress are passing. We all want tax simplification. We all want a less Tax Code. We ask that you, the Congress, prioritize simplicity, unlike the complex tax laws of 1997. We're happy with the tax reduction in these laws. We're not as happy with the simplicity. The alternative minimum tax was a tax on preferences and adjustments to make sure certain taxpayers who had their taxes reduced due to tax shelters, heavy depreciation, special preferences, like stock options, would pay some tax. It was not conceived to penalize taxpayers who had more than two children, credits under the 1997 Tax Relief Act, employee business expenses, or State income taxes. Are taxpayers going to get what Congress promised was a statement made earlier? And that's what I'm here to ask. My suggestion is to simplify the alternative minimum tax. I'm not opposed to doing away with it, by the way, but to simplify it. And there are many solutions out there. You could take in my attached testimony the alternative minimum tax form, 6251, and you could just use lines 8 through 14 and eliminate the other lines. And you will eliminate many of the taxpayers that Mr. Kies mentioned earlier. Tax credits are not computed in alternative minimum tax. And they should not be used as a penalty on taxpayers. Those single mothers that send a child to college are going to be hit with that. Mr. Chairman, I do have practical solutions. I've submitted those to your staff. I've submitted those to Congressman Norwood. In fact, he has sent some forward to the Joint Committee to get them scored so that you will have the answers to the questions about how much this is going to cost me. There are simple solutions, and then there are political solutions. I'm here on the practical side and will not address the political side. Last year I only had about 50 clients hit with AMT. This year I estimate about 250. And next year I estimate about 500 clients. However, every one of my clients has to compute whether they're subject to the AMT. Let's look at those taxpayers that are doing their returns by hand, doing them themselves. They're going to get hit with the AMT, not know it, send their return in. They're going to get a letter back from the IRS with penalty and interest. And then they're going to call their Congressman. And I don't want to be a party to those calls. I've given you an example of a jewelry traveling salesman who travels on the road who is on a W-2 of $107,000. He's hit with AMT, 50-percent reduction for meals, 2-percent reduction for miscellaneous itemized deductions, and so forth. He is being hit, and his effective tax rate has just been hit bad. The 3 percent of adjusted gross income on the itemized deductions was a hidden tax. I've given you testimony as to why that happened. It was a way to raise taxes 1 percent with hidden rates. Now that's 1.19. But the thing of that, line 28, where that number goes, the IRS has refused to put the computation on the form. Not only is it hidden, but they've refused to disclose it. We think that's an affront. We ask that hidden rates be disclosed. And I think earlier somebody said we should disclose the hidden rates in every tax law. I'm here to say at least do that so that I don't get the calls that ``I cannot add up itemized deductions'' and I have to tell them that Congress passed this 3 percent and didn't want you to know that it was an additional rate. I have many other examples enclosed from $30,000 to $330,000 of hidden rates, of hidden loss of deductions, IRAs, tax credits. They're all in my testimony. I ask you and the staff to look over it. And finally I urge Congress to pass laws that are easy to administer that will increase compliance if they're easy to administer and decrease frustration. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of Abram Serotta, Serotta, Maddocks, Evans & Co., Augusta, Georgia I want to thank you for the opportunity to testify before you today on alternative minimum taxes and hidden tax rates. I am a CPA in a firm in Augusta Georgia. I represent approximately 3,000 tax return filers. I consult with other CPA firms and also teach taxation. My views are shared by many other CPAs representing many thousands of taxpayers. I represent the CPAs ``in the field'' who must comply with the complex tax laws you are passing. We all want tax simplification. We want a less complex Tax Code. We ask that you, the Congress, prioritize simplicity, unlike the complex laws you passed in 1997. Since you have heard testimony from others on alternative minimum tax, let me expand on it from a hidden rate standpoint. The alternative minimum tax with preferences and adjustments was created to make sure taxpayers who had their taxes reduced due to tax shelters, heavy depreciation, and special preferences, such as stock options, etc., would pay some tax. It was not conceived to penalize taxpayers who had more than two children, credits under the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, employee business expenses, or state income taxes. My suggestion is to simplify the alternative minimum tax (or do away with it) by limiting it to just special preference items, especially those items from line 8 to 14 (post 1986 depreciation, adjusted gain or loss, incentive stock options, passive activities, beneficiaries of estates and trusts, tax- exempt interest from private activity bonds, and other) of the Form 6251. Tax credits should be allowed for alternative minimum tax purposes and should not be a penalty to taxpayers. I had approximately 50 individual clients in 1996 who were affected by this tax, but I had to compute it for all of my clients. I predict that in 1998, over 250 of my clients will pay alternative minimum tax--several who make under $60,000. Enclosed is a 1997 tax return summary for a traveling salesman, who earns just over $107,000. His business expenses totaled $32,215. Because of: (1) his alternative minimum tax of $4,778, (2) his 50% loss of meals of $2,838, and (3) the 2% adjustment to miscellaneous itemized deductions of $2,218, he loses a total of $9,834 of deductions (more than 30% of his expenses), which at a 28% rate is $2,754 of lost tax savings. The 3% of adjusted gross income in excess of a base amount for itemized deductions was a planned hidden rate. Congress debated between a 31% and 33% tax rate. The compromise was a 31% rate with a 3% adjustment for itemized deductions (31% times 3%) and a hidden rate of .93%. Today with a 39.6 rate, the hidden rate is (39.6% times 3%) 1.19%. The 3% adjustment for adjusted gross income does not appear on the itemized deduction form, Schedule A. Line 28 of Schedule A has no place for the mathematical computations. I receive many calls a year from clients saying that I cannot add correctly because their total deductions on the form do not match the total allowed deductions at the botom of the page. The IRS's answer; there is not a big demand to have this shown on the return. I have enclosed other examples of hidden rates, showing the loss of exemptions, and phase-outs based on adjusted gross income. In my opinion, any phase-out serves as a hidden rate. CONCLUSION: I urge Congress to pass laws that are easy to administer; and will therefore, increase compliance and decrease frustration. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.110 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.111 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.112 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.113 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.114 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.115 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.116 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.117 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.118 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.119 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.120 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.121 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.122 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.123 Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Serotta. I assure you we share your goals. And we appreciate very much your bringing to the Committee practical common sense solutions to some of these, and we will take a look at them. Now Stephen Moore, the director of fiscal policy for the CATO Institute. Mr. Moore. Mr. Moore. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF STEPHEN MOORE, DIRECTOR, FISCAL POLICY, CATO INSTITUTE Mr. Moore. I'm grateful for the opportunity to testify this morning. Let me say that the CATO Institute gets no government grants or contracts, and neither do I personally. I was very much pleased with Chairman Archer's proposal that was released last week for a roughly $200 billion tax cut over the next 5 years. I'm very much in favor of a very large tax cut being enacted this year precisely because we're looking at very large budget surpluses. And those surpluses should be returned to the taxpayers. I would simply have two caveats. First, if we're going to do a tax cut this year, which we should, it should be consistent with the idea of simplicity and fairness. It should move us in the right direction, either toward a consumption tax or a flat tax. Unfortunately, I have to say, Mr. Chairman, that last year's tax bill did not pass that test. We made the tax system more complicated. What I want to talk to you this morning about is an idea that we have been promoting, which is the idea of expanding the 15-percent tax bracket so that it applies to more middle-income workers. As way of background, let me say that one of the tax acts that's passed in this Committee over the last 15 years that was probably one of the single best pieces of legislation in my opinion was the Tax Reform Act of 1986. We cleaned out a lot of the pollution in the Tax Code. We got those rates down. We got them to 15 and 28 percent. And I'm with Jack Kemp on this. If we could move back to that system we had back in 1986, I think the economy would grow much faster and we'd be moving significantly in the right direction. We actually have a plan at the CATO Institute called the alternative maximum tax idea that would say that no taxpayer should have to pay more than 25 percent of their gross income in Federal combined payroll and income tax and if they want to short-circuit this complicated 9,000-page Code, they could simply fill out a postcard, return, pay 25 percent of their gross income in taxes, and be done with it. This would in a sense because of the 15 percent payroll tax creates a two-rate system of 10 and 25 percent. If we can't do that this year, then let's move toward this system of at least providing broad middle-class tax relief in a way that actually reduces tax rates. And what I'm talking about here is expanding the 15 percent tax bracket. Now, if you look back at the 1986 Act, what you find is that the intent of Congress was that we would create two rates. The 15-percent rate would be applicable to all low-income workers and to all earners that were in the middle class. And the 28-percent rate would apply to wealthier taxpayers. Unfortunately, because of real income growth over the last 12 years or so, we have seen a system where more and more middle-income taxpayers are now being forced into the 28- percent and in some cases the 31-percent tax bracket. This is a simple matter of tax fairness. There are now 21 million Americans in America today that make between roughly $25,000 and $50,000 income. And, believe it or not, Mr. Chairman, these are the Americans who pay the highest combined payroll and income tax bracket of any Americans in the entire economy. That is to say, a $40,000 single worker pays a higher marginal tax rate than Bill Gates does. To demonstrate this point, I want to, if I could, show you a couple of charts to demonstrate this point. What this chart is essentially showing you, this is essentially showing the combined payroll tax and income tax rates that are applicable to Americans at various income levels. What it shows is that if you look at the people who--this is for single filers, incidentally--make over $25,350--that's where the 28-percent bracket kicks in for single workers--those folks are paying the highest rates. And so what I am suggesting is that we take this line here and we bring this over like this so that those middle-income workers are paying 30 percent, 15 percent on their income and 15 percent on their payroll, not a combined 43 percent, which is what they are paying now. Again, this would apply to roughly 21 million working Americans. If we want to provide broad-based tax relief to the middle class and we'd want to do it in a way that is in a supply side progrowth direction, let's bring rates down for those folks. Eventually I'd like to have that 30-percent rate go across the board, but at least start with those middle- income workers. Quickly, this, Mr. Chairman, is the same rate chart but for married couples. Now, you can see the situation is a little better for married couples, but again you see that big hump, camel hump, there. Again, let's flatten that out. Let's get rid of that 28-percent bracket for folks in that income range between roughly $42,350 and $64,000. That is the proposal, Mr. Chairman. I think it's consistent with sound progrowth tax policy, but it also would provide very significant tax relief for voters in that income range. Thank you. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of Stephen Moore, Director, Fiscal Policy, CATO Institute In 1986 Congress passed and President Reagan signed a landmark and heroic piece of legislation: the 1986 Tax Reform Act. The 1986 TRA closed economically inefficient tax loopholes and dramatically reduced income tax rates for all Americans. The result of the 1986 Tax Reform Act was to create a simple two-rate income tax system: 15 percent and 28 percent. It should be emphasized that the 1986 TRA was a bipartisan measure and was sponsored by Democrats Rep. Richard Gephardt and Senator Bill Bradley and Republicans Rep. Jack Kemp, and Senator Bob Packwood, with important contributions from the now Chairman of this Committee, Bill Archer. A major objective of the 1986 Act was for the 15 percent income tax bracket to apply to all low income and the vast majority of middle income workers. The 28 percent bracket was primarily to apply to wealthier workers. In the post-1986 TRA era, we have passed several bad tax bills, most notably the 1990 budget deal and the 1993 budget deal, both of which unraveled tax simplification and created a new multitude of tax rates climbing to a high of 39.6 percent. I agree wholeheartedly with Jack Kemp and others that a very good start to tax reform would be to get us back to the two bracket system of 15 and 28. We have a plan that we are promoting at the Cato Institute called the MAXTAX that would be even more pro-growth. It would create two income tax rates at 10 and 25 percent wrapped around the payroll tax. I have attached to my testimony an explanation of that plan, which involves giving taxpayers the freedom to choose between this low rate gross income tax or the complex current system. Another pernicious trend since 1986 should be rectified by this Committee to restore tax fairness for the middle class. More and more middle income workers have now been pushed into the 28 percent tax bracket--and some are now paying the 31 percent bracket. This phenomenon is occurring because the tax brackets are not indexed for real income growth, just nominal income growth. Today, there are roughly 21 million workers with earnings between $30,000 and $50,000 a year most of whom pay marginal income tax rates of 28 percent. Believe it or not, these workers pay the highest marginal tax rates under our federal tax system. Why? Because they pay a 28 percent federal income tax rate on top of a 15 percent payroll tax. The combined rate of 43 percent is higher than the top income tax bracket for even the wealthiest Americans at 39.6 percent. The two charts that I have attached to my testimony show the problem graphically. The middle class workers--particularly single workers--face punitive tax rate burdens. And as Reagan taught us: taxes matter most at the margin. Nixon once called these neglected citizens the ``silent majority.'' Both parties lay claim to speaking for these working class Americans, but neither party seems to be listening to them. Ever since the sweeping Reagan tax cuts of 1981, neither political party has done much to directly benefit the middle class in the pocketbook. The latest figures from the nonpartisan Tax Foundation highlight that since 1980, despite a Republican in the White House for 12 of those 17 years and a Republican-controlled Congress for 3 of the 5 others--the tax bite on median-income families has continued to ratchet upward to 38.5 percent. Federal taxation is now at its highest peacetime level, as a share of Americans' incomes, since the height of World War II. Much of the escalating tax burden has, of course, been attributable to hikes in the regressive payroll tax. For most Americans, payroll tax increases have canceled out, nearly dollar for dollar, the benefits of the Reagan income tax cuts. Meanwhile, the federal gas tax has been tripled since 1980, state and local property taxes continue to climb and so does a multitude of obnoxious fees and assessments. Last year Rep. Dick Armey (R-Tex.) called this plight of American workers, ``the middle class squeeze.'' Exactly the right diagnosis. But what is either party doing about it? Last year Republicans passed a niggling tax cut about one-third as large as what they had promised in 1994. Yes, for families with young kids this is blessed relief--a $1,000 tax cut for a family of four. There are still millions of middle-class households without kids at home and without capital gains income that will angrily learn come April 15th that they get essentially nothing out of this tax bill. Jack Kemp and Ronald Reagan taught us that tax rates matter, too. Combining payroll tax, federal income tax, and state income taxes, many middle income families are approaching a 50 percent marginal tax burden. If a stay-at-home mother wants to get back in the workforce, full- or part-time, she's paying nearly 50 percent tax on her first dollar of income earned. Counting the costs of child care, she may only bring home 20 cents on the dollar. Often she can't afford to work. Republican Senator Paul Coverdell of Georgia has proposed relieving the middle-class squeeze. He would raise the income threshold on the 15 percent income tax bracket. I understand that Mr. Archer will propose to do so as well. Under current law the 28 percent tax bracket creeps up on single workers at an income level of $25,350 and on married couples at $42,350. The 15 percent bracket should be stretched to $35,000 income for singles and $50,000 for married couples. This would reduce federal revenues on a static basis by $25 billion a year--or roughly the amount of the budget surplus now being projected. The principle here is simple: all middle-class families in America should be in the 15 percent tax bracket-- not the 28 percent bracket. In fact, eventually, Congress should expand the 15 percent tax bracket to apply to all Americans with earnings below $65,000 a year--the income level where people stop paying payroll taxes. This is not a plan that is vulnerable to attacks as a ``tax cut for the rich.'' It is designed to benefit the workers who earn between $30,000 to $50,000 a year. This plan would provide middle-class workers, not symbolic, but meaningful tax relief. A single filer with an income of $32,000 a year would receive an $864 tax cut. A married couple with taxable income of $48,000 a year would receive a tax cut of $734. Preliminary estimates indicate that the plan would result in a static revenue loss of $20 to $25 billion annually. This is less than the projected budget surplus. Dynamic analysis would suggest that as much as one-third of the static revenue loss would be recouped through more work and savings. Newt Gingrich and Trent Lott have announced that Republicans will cut taxes again in 1998. The bigger the tax cut, the better. But I urge this committee that whatever is done: cut taxes and aim to simplify. No more ``targeted'' education tax credits, no more loopholes and complexities. The President's tax plans are deeply flawed in this area. H&R Block is the primary beneficiary of the White House proposal. Tax cuts in 1998 should make the tax code simpler and the tax burden lighter. Consistent with these principles, I am very much in favor of two other ideas that have been presented before this Committee: indexing capital gains for inflation and relieving Americans from the burden of the Alternative Minimum Tax. Inflation is a thief. It is not fair to tax Americans purely on phantom gains. In this low inflation environment, indexing capital gains would not impose much of a cost on the Treasury, but would provide investors an insurance policy against a return to a high inflation regime. Bill Archer and Paul Coverdell's ideas are sound. Marginal rate cuts are necessary to improve American competitiveness in the global economy. It is noteworthy that almost all nations in the world have been cutting tax rates since 1981--see tables. We should broaden the 15 percent tax bracket this year. In 1999 or 2000 we should vastly simplify the tax system by flattening the income tax, or better yet, by adopting a national consumption tax. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.124 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.125 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.126 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.127 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.128 Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Moore, for that very interesting proposal. Now we'll hear from Robert Blair, chairman and president of the S Corporation Association. Mr. Blair. Mr. Blair. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you, Members of the Committee. STATEMENT OF ROBERT A. BLAIR, FOUNDER AND CHAIRMAN, S CORPORATION ASSOCIATION Mr. Blair. My name is Robert Blair. I am the founder and chairman of the S Corporation Association, an association that I established because I found that many entrepreneurs throughout the United States found themselves unrepresented here in Washington. We are about 45,000 companies strong among the 2 million S corporations that exist in the United States. It's a small beginning, but 45,000 strong is a strong voice. I want to talk today about the inequity that applies to the S corporations owners of the United States, and I applaud this Committee for looking at inequities that apply across the spectrum, whether to married couples or to others. The essential issue that I am here to talk about is entrepreneurship. In our youth, all of us studied in our books the great entrepreneurs of yesteryear. Whether it was Eli Whitney or Robert Fulton, we looked back, and we saw great vision, people taking great risks, and succeeding against the odds. The modern media bombard us with the great successes of today's entrepreneurs. Bill Gates or Mary Kay or Ted Turner. These people not only took risks and achieved greatness, but in many instances, they created whole new industries. Of course, behind all of those big stories that hit the front pages of the newspaper, regrettably, are the many more unreported stories of entrepreneurs who took the risks but did not achieve great success. For every great success, there are many failures. I know of which I speak. I come from a family of entrepreneurs. At the time of the Great Depression, my father, Tom Blair, had to leave the employment of his father's road construction company because jobs were stripped away. With an eighth-grade education and a passel of kids--I'm number 11 of 13--he moved from the North Carolina region to where there might be work. He found that work in Virginia. He went there seeking work, and what he also took with him was an entrepreneurial spirit that has flowed through our family at least since the 1850s. He created with his eighth- grade education a road construction company, intending to do what all of us want to do: have great success. I wish I could tell you my father's version of the Bill Gates success story now. I can't. Success did not come easy. He went up, and he went down. He suffered through two bankruptcies. He suffered when I was 15 years old a complete disability that took him completely out of commission for 5 years when he simply could not work. By that time, in his early sixties, what did he face? He had 13 children. He had to put food on the table. He was receiving a mere $30 a week in disability insurance. Times were not exactly pretty. But he eventually got up from his bed and he worked. And from that work, many of his sons, myself not included, and his grandsons have gone off to create other road construction businesses which are prospering today. Why do I tell you a family story? Because, while it makes me feel terrific, the burdens and the obstacles that life puts in your path--whether it's the Great Depression or whether it's simply a tough technical hurdle--an entrepreneur, even one with seemingly endless spirit and zeal, doesn't need the U.S. Government placing additional burdens and obstacles in his way. In 1954, the Congress saw the wisdom of creating something called the S corporation, or Subchapter S of the Internal Revenue Code. By doing this, Congress permitted American entrepreneurs who created their small and family businesses to operate at least under the shield of limited liability from plaintiffs' attorneys, who obviously were scouring the landscape for opportunities on behalf of their clients. Congress permitted these S corporation owners to be taxed at a partnership tax rate. That was the good news of what the Congress saw and did in the fifties. As a result of that vision, Congress spawned entrepreneurship throughout the country, in every sector of the economy, be it rent-a-car companies or florists or heavy manufacturers. You name the industry, and I will bring you an S corporation. That's success, job-creating success, people taking risks, but fair and reasonable risks of the market, rather than risks that are imposed artificially by the government. To understand what I mean by that, let's revisit 1993, about which the 1993 distinguished Chairman of this Committee spoke earlier. In the 1993 Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act, tax increases went up to 39.6 percent. Why do I speak of that in the context of S corporations? Because those individual rates apply to the S corporation owners who had seized on and in him, build on the platform established by Congress in the fifties. With that as a backdrop, the tax hike of 1993 was disastrous. Allow me to flesh this out with another real-life example. A dear friend of mine started a company in 1975 with a handful of employees. By the early nineties, he had grown to 6,000 employees, succeeding against great odds, in a tough business with narrow margins of profit of perhaps 3 percent. What happens in a company where you've self-capitalized, where you have to put most of your money back in your business? You'd better watch that margin, or there will be nothing left to reinvest. So along comes the huge tax increase of 1993. Now my friend has to take more money out of the company to pay his higher tax bill to the U.S. Treasury. He needs money to continue to capitalize, but he doesn't have it anymore. So he goes into the debt markets, and he borrows. Now he has higher taxes debt, which comes with the added costs of debt service. By 1995, his back is against the wall because, as an entrepreneur who operates in the form of an S corporation, he faces the fact that he must personally apply to every financial institution which lends him money, and personally guarantee what is becoming unmanageable debt. For my friend whose story is all too common among S corporations today, it became too much. Back against the wall, facing the prospect of personal bankruptcy because the debt would overwhelm him, he did the opportune thing. He sold out to a public company. And what did that public company proceed to do? Not surprisingly, it downsized the business, reversing the job- creating machine my friend had established, sweated to grow, and worked to sustain. That's the personal side of what has happened to S corporations. Let's look at the more empirical evidence now. National Association of Manufacturers' polls discovered that, in the aftermath of the 1993 tax hike, 43 percent of their S corporation members, a significant portion of the trade association, would not increase capital investment as a direct result of the higher tax rates and other obstacles placed on them by the government. Forty-seven percent of those surveyed said they would not hire more employees as a result. And 23 percent said they would actually have to engage in layoffs. These are real numbers and they are numbers that only tell us how common my dear friend's dilemna now. What is the solution? The beginning of the answer has been submitted by Mr. Crane, who has introduced a bill, the Small Business Investment and Growth Act (H.R. 2884), to try to rectify part of the problem. I thank Mr. English for being one who has recently come on as a cosponsor of this important legislation. What does Mr. Crane's bill recognize? It recognizes that yes, the S corporation companies of America deserve not a major break, but certainly not the illogic of the tax ``penalty'' placed on them in 1993. Mr. Crane's bill recognizes the entrepreneurial spirit which is in their veins, and helps ensures that it will continue to be the job-creating force that this country historically has been able to depend upon. The Crane bill says: If you are going to reinvest in your company, Mr. or Ms. S corporation owner, or if you have to take money out of your business in order to pay these increased taxes, we'll stop penalizing you for doing what we need you to do. We'll roll back the 39.6-percent rate you pay to the highest C corporation rate, provided you leave that money in the company. When and if you take any of that reinvestment out at a future point, you then would have to pay the highest applicable individual rate. While this is unquestionably a reasoned approach, we limited it so that the lower rate would only apply to $5 million of the company's Federal taxable income. And that cap, together with strong antiabuse provisions, ensure that we keep this proposal not only fair and logical, but also at a reasonable cost to the Treasury. Needless to say, we are confident that whatever small investment is made ``up front'' by the Treasury will be repaid many times over, because Congress would simply be facilitizing reinvestment--not penalizing it--spurring even more growth, productivity and job creation from the entrepreneurs who have proven themselves capable of delivering throughout the economical history of our Nation. Mr. Chairman, I will wrap up by saying that the S Corporation Association has made this its top priority on behalf of its own members and affiliates, as well as two million S corporations around the United States. I am pleased to report that the National Association of Manufacturers' Small Manufacturers' Group has also made this one of their top priorities. And the numerous trade associations with whom we work have made or are making this one of their major goals as well. We hope that you will work with us to pass that legislation. We thank you for holding this hearing today. [The prepared statement and attachment follow:] Statement of Robert A. Blair, Founder and Chairman, S Corporation Association Good morning, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. My name is Robert Blair, and I am the founder and Chairman of the S Corporation Association, or S-CORP as we are known, a group which speaks for more than 45,000 S corporations in virtually every industry nationwide. On behalf of our members and our affiliates, I wish to thank the Chairman for taking time today to address some of the tax rate inequities facing key segments of the U.S. population, and to explore some of the ways in which we can begin to rectify them. I applaud the Chairman's leadership in pursuing this important topic, and am grateful that you have allowed me to come before this body today to share my views with the Committee. I am certain that today's proceedings will help lay the critical groundwork for focusing on strategic and reasonable means by which we can redirect the tax system, through the legislative process, to encourage the type of economic activities that we as Americans have long valued. Recognizing the Entrepreneur The essential issue that I will talk about today is a value that is more a part of American economic history and tradition than perhaps any other: that value is entrepreneurship. We have, as a society, long heralded and embraced the entrepreneur, and our culture reflects this value in every way imaginable. Our children are taught from grade school about the vision of entrepreneurs like Eli Whitney, Robert Fulton, Alexander Graham Bell, and Henry Ford, and how these men took risks that changed the way America competes in and leads the world. Our magazines, films and television news shows regularly trumpet the genius of entrepreneurs like Bill Gates, Warren Buffet, Mary Kay and Ted Turner, and remind us of the personal and professional risks that they took to literally create industries like computer software, investment banking, cosmetics and broadcast media. Quite simply, America is in love with the entrepreneur, and for good reason. Ours is the one country in the world where the Horatio Alger story can come true, where one person can have a vision, take a risk, and make that vision into a monumental reality, all within a single lifetime. But all entrepreneurs do not achieve the great success of a Bill Gates or a Ted Turner. Most fail. Many who fail pick themselves up and try again. I know of which I speak. I am the eleventh of thirteen children. My father was forced to leave his father's road construction company when the great Depression stripped away many of the jobs that my father and others had. With an eighth grade education, he traveled to southeast Virginia to find employment and then to start his own road construction company. But success did not come easy. Over a period of three decades he rose...and he fell. He went bankrupt twice--he was disabled from a construction accident for more than five years. But he never quit. The entrepreneurial blood that flowed in his veins flows today in the veins of his sons, several of whom started their own road construction businesses. While some may say that I got lost along the way and became a Washington lawyer, I can assure you that that entrepreneurial blood flows in my veins as well. My creation of the S Corporation Association is a testament to the entrepreneurial spirit of Tom Blair, to my grandfather, Thomas Blair, who went from building railroads to building roads for cars, to my great grandfather, William Robert Blair, who left Ireland and found work building the railroads of the Midwest. But why, do you ask, do I raise a family story? Because the spirit of the entrepreneur is challenged enough without the government placing burdens and obstacles in the path. I watched the Congress do just that when it passed the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act in 1993. Congress had a decidedly different view in 1954. S Corporations: Congress Seeks To Foster Entrepreneurship In 1954 the Congress knew a good thing when it saw it. The Congress recognized the value of entrepreneurship and sought to create a way to encourage and promote the economic spirit on which our country was built by creating the concept of the S corporation. The S corporation was launched as a means of ensuring that when a person has a business vision, takes personal risk to launch that vision and helps to fuel the economy by making that vision into economic reality, he or she does not get penalized by the tax system while they are doing something fundamentally good and important for the American economy. Because for an S corporation, where the shareholders are the business, these companies were permitted by Congress to limit the personal liability of the owners, but be taxed like partnerships. What did Congress do when it created special companies in 1954? The answer is simple: It spawned entrepreneurship. In 1978, S corporations made up only about 20 percent of U.S. corporations. By 1995, there were 2 million S corporations operating in virtually every industry and in every state across America, and these businesses accounted for half of all corporations in America. While a small handful of these companies have realized truly great success, the IRS tells us that the vast majority of these companies are small businesses, with average assets of less than $10 million. But while principally small, these companies account for about 40 percent of the U.S. tax base. These are not the IBM's and Microsofts of the world; they are mostly family businesses, or companies started by small groups of families or by friends from the same school or town. They are corner stores and the kinds of businesses that employ significant segments of entire communities. They are the businesses that create local wealth as well as national wealth. In order to launch these businesses, we should remember, their owners have risked large amounts of their own personal assets, often putting up all of their savings to see whether they can make their vision work. Most of them, no matter how successful their company has become, still must guarantee personally every penny of debt that their businesses take on. These businesses are not concentrated in any geographic region, nor are they aggregated in a particular industry. Rather, they are evenly spread across the U.S. industrial base, with about a third operating in the service sector, a third in the retail trade and financial sectors, and a third in manufacturing, mining, agriculture and other traditionally ``heavy'' industries. Some of these businesses have been lucky enough to grow and employ a few hundred workers, while others have stayed small but productive, and just as critical a part of the national economic landscape. In short, in 1954 Congress had its own vision--it wanted to create a way to enable businesses to organize, reasonably limit the liability of the individuals who started the company, acknowledge the extraordinary risks and challenges these individuals faced, and impose taxes fairly and appropriately. Congress sought to promote entrepreneurship, and it succeeded. The S corporations of today stand for entrepreneurship, the most basic American economic ideal, and they have fulfilled their mission by becoming the engines of economic growth and job-creation that Congress hoped that they would be. The Disaster of 1993 Then, of course, came the disaster of 1993. That was the year that Congress may have forgotten about its S corporations, and its desire to foster and support entrepreneurship. Congress most certainly did not intend the consequences that struck many S corporations, but intent is not relevant when you are the entrepreneur fighting in a viciously competitive market, who must also overcome government improved burdens and obstacles. What am I talking about? When Congress raised tax rates to 39.6% in individuals, it forced S corporation owners, most of whom self-capitalize, to take substantial additional monies out of their businesses simply to pay taxes. A dear friend took his S corporation from a handful of employees to over 6,000 employees in just twenty years. His margin of profit was at best 3 to 4 percent. That big 1993 tax increase took dollars that he would have re- invested in his corporation and deposited them with the IRS. Short on capital, he was forced to go to the capital markets to borrow large sums of money. Now he had debt service and higher taxes to pay. By the end of 1995, he was on the verge of losing everything--after all, as the owner of an S corporation, he had to guarantee his corporation's debt. He saved himself by selling to a public company which immediately downsized his twenty-year-old creation. A simple example will further illustrate my point: Let us say that an owner's share of her S corporation is $250,000 this year. Of that amount, the owner pays herself $125,000 in salary and non-wage distributions, and invests the remaining $125,000 to buy one new machine and hire one new employee. With the tax hike of 1993, she will pay federal income taxes at an astonishing rate of 64 percent of her actual take-home pay. More importantly, she will pay the same tax bill as another business owner of a standard or ``C corporation'' who took home $250,000 in salary and distributions and chose to reinvest nothing in his business. I cannot conceive of a greater disincentive for reinvestment and economic growth for this critical class of businesses. In polls of S corporations since their shareholders' tax rates increased, these companies regularly report that the added tax burden is the primary reason they cannot reinvest as much money into their companies as they did before their taxes went up, and that they would put more money back into their businesses and into the economy if they were freed up by tax laws to do so. In recent surveys by the National Association of Manufacturers of their small manufacturers, about 40 percent of which are S corporations, the increase in tax rates on S corporations was a key reason that 43 percent of these businesses said they would not increase capital investment, or that they would reduce investment in their businesses. During this time of great economic expansion, in fact, 47 percent of these companies said that the higher tax burden on S corporations, together with other government mandates, would keep them from hiring more employees. Twenty-three percent said they planned to lay off workers as a direct result. If we believe that the economic good times of the past few years have been universal, imagine what gains we could have realized if S corporation tax policies were not so misdirected as they now are. The Crane Bill: A Critical Beginning In November 1997, Congressman Phil Crane introduced the Small Business Investment and Growth Act, a bill to encourage the entrepreneur and to help our economy derive the benefits from that entrepreneur's work and risk. On behalf of all S corporations, I hope that the Committee will advance Congressman Crane's important measure as a means of trying to bring fairness for the entrepreneur back into the tax code on a permanent basis. The Crane bill has a simple objective: to reduce the inequities imposed on S corporations as a result of the tax rate increase of 1993, and to begin to help America's S corporations to put money back into their companies so they can continue to expand and create more U.S. jobs. Congressman Crane's bill acts on what history--not to mention our own business owners--tells us to be true: If we empower our entrepreneurs with sound policy, rather than punish them for investing and for growth, if we recognize the risk these entrepreneurs take every day rather than make it even riskier for them to stay in business, we will reap the benefits of these policies through more corporate spending, more jobs, and more productivity. Congressman Crane's bill is an investment in a proven entity--the entrepreneur--for our own economic future and that of our children. To accomplish these important objectives, Congressman Crane's bill would lower the federal tax rate paid by S corporation shareholders to no more than the highest applicable C corporation rate when the shareholders reinvest their earnings in their businesses, and/or when the company distributes earnings for the sole purpose of making tax payments. To ensure that virtually every S corporation in every sector benefits from this measure, companies of every size would be able to participate, but the reduced rate would be applicable only to the first $5 million in federal taxable income of the S corporation. This ensures that the Congress supports and promotes entrepreneurship, but does not do so at a level that adversely affects the federal treasury. The Crane bill extends to S corporations in every industry group imaginable, but it also has limitations to protect against abuses. For example, the measure only allows so-called ``personal service corporations'' to benefit from the reduced tax rate to the extent that they are not only reinvesting in their businesses, but making demonstrable investments in true capital expenditures such as plant, property and equipment. And as I mentioned, because we want to see this critical change be made available to all S corporations rather than a select handful, we support the notion that the rate reduction can only be made widely available if it is limited in its amount, in this case to $5 million of the S corporation's taxable income. I am proud to say that the S Corporation Association, together with the National Association of Manufacturers, has worked closely with Congressman Crane and his office on this important measure, and our Association will make this our top priority for 1998. I know that this is also a priority for NAM, whose Small Manufacturers reported last year that eliminating the S corporation ``shareholder penalty'' is their second-most- pressing legislative priority. I need hardly tell the Committee that many other trade associations--and particularly those whose members are typically small and/or family businesses--are eager to see this proposal advance. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Members of this Committee, for permitting me to come here today. The Small Business Investment and Growth Act, (H.R. 2884) Need for the Legislation As a result of the tax increases of 1990 and 1993, S corporation shareholders are unfairly burdened by a higher tax rate than is applied to any other corporate entity in America. S corporations--which represent more than 2 million businesses in virtually every sector and in every state nationwide--are especially penalized when they reinvest in the growth and preservation of their businesses, and when they distribute earnings for the sole purpose of paying taxes. S corporations, which are predominantly small and traditionally family-owned businesses, have originally been the engines of America's economic growth. But because of the disincentives of current tax laws, these entrepreneurial establishments are hindered from reinvesting in their businesses and continuing their strong tradition of economic expansion and job creation. Goals of the Legislation The Small Business Investment and Growth Act promotes investment among America's S corporations in jobs and business growth; provides for targeted rate reduction for all S corporation owners, regardless of industry or size, when they invest in their businesses; allows certain personal service corporations which make substantial investments in capital improvements to benefit from the targeted rate reduction; and ensures against potential abuses by certain companies. Key Provisions The bill would lower the federal tax rates paid by S corporation shareholders to no more than the highest applicable C corporation rate when the S corporations reinvest earnings in their businesses (rather than distribute the profits) and/or when they distribute earnings for the sole purpose of making tax payments. The lower tax rate would be applicable only to the first $5 million in federal taxable income of the S corporation. Any combination of reinvested earnings and earnings distributed solely for making federal tax payments would qualify. To avoid potential abuses of the reduction, an exclusion applies to some personal service corporations (PSCs). In general, PSCs (defined by IRC 448) would be eligible for the rate reduction only to the extent that their reinvested earnings are offset by capital expenditures. The $5 million taxable income cap would still apply, though a PSC would be allowed to use a three-year carry forward account for reinvestment to offset its capital expenditures. Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Blair, for excellent testimony. Mr. Nelson, I'm told that our clock and the lights are broken. So if you'd try to summarize your written testimony in about 5 minutes, we'd appreciate it. Thank you. Mr. Nelson. I sure will. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Members of the Committee, for our invitation to testify on important tax issues. STATEMENT OF WAYNE NELSON, PRESIDENT, COMMUNICATING FOR AGRICULTURE Mr. Nelson. My name is Wayne Nelson. I'm president of Communicating for Agriculture, an association of farmers, ranchers, and rural small business people with members in all 50 states. our national headquarters are in Minnesota. CA's worked on tax fairness issues affecting farmers, ranchers, and small business for many years. And we want to commend Congress for taking several positive steps last year on tax reform. We also believe that with the U.S. economy and the Federal budget appearing to be in better shape than at any time in recent memory, there is an opportunity to do more. We believe that a balance can be achieved that would allow for Federal debt reduction, maintaining a balanced budget, and providing for tax reduction. Mr. Chairman, I operate a farm in southern South Dakota. It seems that every year, income taxes get more complicated with most farmers and small businesses unable to do their own tax returns. Simplification of the Tax Code would go a long way toward helping farms and small businesses. Communicating for Agriculture supports the IRS reform measures presently moving through Congress. Recently it seems that the IRS has been using the TAM, technical advice memorandum, in a more frequent manner and in a manner that seemingly skirts or goes beyond the intent of the tax laws that Congress has previously enacted. It seems unfair that when Congress works hard to deliberate and pass tax legislation that a new interpretation growing out of one court case can change the outcome for thousands of taxpayers. An example has been the deferred payment contract problem for farmers last year. The IRS issued a technical advice memorandum that said farmers could no longer use deferred payment contracts to sell grain and livestock in one tax year and receive the proceeds in the next year. Thankfully, Congress fixed this with the legislation last year. We are concerned that one of the most recent TAMs again seeks to reinterpret tax policy to go beyond the intent of Congress. It involves self-employment taxes for farmers on rental income. In 1996, the IRS issued a TAM that effectively repealed the longstanding law that allowed farmers to choose whether their rental income would be subject to self-employment taxes now set at 15.3 percent. Congress allowed farmland owners to make the election by arranging their affairs to intentionally pass or fail a three- part test. Farmland owners accomplished this election through the use of their farm lease agreements. The election has been offered since the fifties when Social Security benefits were first offered to farmers, enabling retired farmers to choose to pay self-employment taxes on cash rental income to become eligible for Social Security. The recent memorandum now reverses this option and states that farmland owners that also materially participate in the farming activity and rent to a farmer or a family farm business entity, they must pay the 15.3 percent tax on their rental income. It doesn't seem fair that farmland owners are now being singled out to pay self-employment taxes on certain cash rental income. The self-employment taxes should apply to income from labor. And the cash rent income is value and equity in the land and does not represent labor. It seems extremely unfair to allow an owner of an apartment complex or other commercial people to be able to not pay self- employment tax on their cash rental income but farmers still have to do this. On my farm in South Dakota, we also have problems, as with many farms in America, with weather and with prices. So we have ups and downs in farm income. In the seventies and the early eighties, income-averaging was available to help level out this income from year to year. This last year in the budget bill, income-averaging for farmers in a limited basis was included. It is sunsetted in the year 2000, and we would like to see that extended. Additionally, another useful self-help tool has been proposed. This is called the FARRM, or the farm and ranch risk management, accounts. These accounts would let qualified individual farmers and ranchers set aside up to 20 percent of their farm income each year. These individuals would have to materially participate in farming with the amount to be set aside calculated from their Schedule F portion of their tax return. The contribution would be tax-deferred, but any interest earned on the account would be included in the individual's annual gross income. The distributions would be treated as taxable income in the year that they were received. Any money left in the account over the 5-year limit would be subject to a 10-percent penalty. Individual farmers that don't meet the participation guidelines for 2 consecutive years would have to immediately distribute the funds in the account. We think this and other ideas are ones that are fair from a tax standpoint. And they provide a useful financial management tool. Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, thank you for letting us share our views with you, we appreciate it. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Wayne Nelson, President, Communicating for Agriculture Chairman Archer and members of the Committee, thank you for the invitation to testify on important tax issues. My name is Wayne Nelson and I am President of Communicating for Agriculture, an association of farmers, ranchers and rural small business people with members in all 50 states with our national headquarters in Minnesota. Communicating for Agriculture celebrated its 25th anniversary last year, and CA has worked on tax fairness issues affecting farmers, ranchers and small businesses throughout nearly all of those years. We want to commend Congress for taking several positive steps last year, notably on estate tax reform. We believe, with the U.S. economy and the federal budget appearing to be in better shape than anytime in recent memory, there is opportunity to do more. We share the view that Americans are paying more overall in taxes than they'd like to, and more than is necessary, for our government systems to run as efficiently as it can. We understand that taxes are necessary to maintain our country's infrastructure, our educational systems, and provide services citizens depend on. However, we believe a balance can be achieved that would allow for federal debt reduction, maintaining a balanced budget, providing for tax reduction, and still improving services. Mr. Chairman, I operate a farm in southern South Dakota so I deal with taxes on a frequent basis. It seems that every year income taxes get more complicated with most farmers and small businesses unable to do their own tax returns. I know on my farm I spend a good deal of time and money with my accountant who does a good job of charting a course through the maze of complex rules to prepare a tax filing on my operation. Simplification of the tax code would go a long way toward helping farms and small businesses and Communicating for Agriculture supports IRS reform measures presently moving through Congress. Hopefully, this reform can be quickly enacted to not only offer better understanding of the laws but also to put tax payers in a stronger position when disputes arise with the IRS. Recently, it seems, the IRS has been using the Technical Advice Memorandum (TAM) in a more frequent manner, and in a manner that seemingly skirts or goes beyond the intent of the tax laws that Congress has previously enacted. It seems unfair when Congress works hard to deliberate and pass tax legislation, which is interpreted and applied by the IRS for many years, only to have it changed for thousands of taxpayers by a new interpretation growing out of one court case. An example is the deferred payment contract problem for farmers last year. The IRS issued a Technical Advice Memorandum that said farmers could no longer use deferred payment contracts to sell grain and livestock in one tax year and receive the proceeds in the next tax year. Thankfully, Congress fixed this with legislation last year, but it should not have been necessary to fix a long standing law that had been interpreted by the IRS to allow deferred contracts in the years past only to have the interpretation changed by the TAM. We are concerned that one of the most recent Technical Advice Memorandums again seeks to reinterpret tax policy to go beyond the intent of Congress. It involves self employment taxes for farmers on rental income. In 1996 the IRS issued a TAM that effectively repealed the long standing law that allowed farmers to choose whether their rental income would be subject to self employment taxes now set at 15.3 percent. Congress allowed farmland owners to make the election by arranging their affairs to intentionally pass or fail a three part test. The law provides that if a farmland owner receives cash rental receipts from: (1) an ``arrangement'' whereby the farmland is used to produce farm commodities, (2) when the arrangement requires material participation by the farmland owner in the production or management of the farm commodities, and (3) when the farmland owner actually materially participates in the production or management of the farm commodities, then the farm land owner becomes liable for the self employment tax and participates in the social security system. Farm land owners accomplished this election through the use of their farm lease agreements. The election has been offered since the 1950s when social security benefits were first offered to farmers enabling retired farmers to choose to pay self employment taxes on cash rental income to become eligible for social security. The recent IRS memorandum now reverses this option and states that farmland owners that also materially participate in the farming activity and rent to a farmer or family farm business entity must pay the 15.3 percent tax on the rental income. The tax code does not require commercial or residential property owners to pay self employment tax on cash rents. It is not fair that farmland owners are now being singled out to pay self employment taxes on certain cash rental income. Self employment taxes should apply to income from labor. Cash rent income shows the value of the equity in the land and does not represent labor. It seems extremely unfair to allow the owner of a large apartment complex to not pay self employment taxes on the cash rental income but the farmland owner who might only rent a few acres has to pay 15.3 percent self employment taxes on their cash rental income. Legislation has been introduced in both the Senate and House to remedy this matter. H.R.1261 and S.529 would reinstate Congressional intent by restoring the election by farmland owners. Communicating for Agriculture is working toward the enactment of this legislation, and we encourage you to include it in a tax package this year. On my farm in South Dakota, as well as farms and ranches all over America, it is common for there to be wide swings in income from year to year. Agriculture is inherently a volatile business. The weather plays such a critical role in production, and most farmers are at the mercy of mother nature. Weather problems, coupled with uncertain prices for most farm commodities, makes for widely varied income levels that can push farmers to a high income tax bracket one year yet leave them with no income or even a loss the next year when mother nature and the markets don't cooperate. In the 1970s and early 80s income averaging was available to help level the income taxes paid by farmers from year to year. Last year's Budget Bill brought back income averaging on a limited basis for farmers and ranchers and only until the year 2000. This useful tool needs to be extended past the next three years. Additionally, another useful self-help tool has been proposed that would enable farmers and ranchers to even out tax payments. The proposal is called FARRM or Farm and Ranch Risk Management accounts. FAARM accounts would essentially allow farmers and ranchers to set aside tax deferred income in good years and draw money back out of the FARRM account in the lower income years offering a reasonably balanced income from year to year. These accounts would let qualified individual farmers and ranchers set aside up to 20 percent of their farm income each year. These individuals would have to materially participate in farming with the amount to be set aside calculated from their schedule F portion of their tax return. The contribution would be tax deferred but any interest earned on the account would be included in the individual's annual gross income. There would be a 5-year limit on deposits to the account so a distribution would have to be made. Distributions would be treated as taxable income in the year they were received. Any money left in the account over the 5-year limit would be subject to 10 percent penalty. Individual farmers that don't meet the participation guidelines for two consecutive years would have to immediately distribute the funds in the FARRM account. We think the FAARM account proposal is a good idea--one is fair from a tax standpoint, and one that provides a useful financial management tool that would help producers contend with the risky, volatile farm economy they face every day. We thank you for inviting Communicating for Agriculture to share our ideas and views with you. Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Nelson. And thank all of you for your testimony today. I'm sorry we got a little behind schedule. We do have another meeting going on at the Capitol. And, for that reason, we're going to suspend questions. But if any Member has a question, I would invite them to submit those questions to witnesses in writing. Mr. Johnson has a comment, though, that he would like to make before we move on. Mr. Johnson of Texas. Thank you. I just can't resist making a comment. You know, Mr. Blair mentioned Amarillo. And the agricultural community is talking, but don't forgot our Nation's cattle growers who are currently dealing with Oprah Winfrey. Mr. Serotta, I'm glad you're with us today. And I agree that the individual alternative minimum tax ought to be reformed, if not abolished. And I think our Chairman and the one sitting in the chair now agree with that because the AMT now is starting to affect hardworking families by penalizing them for having children. That's the middle-income bracket that Mr. Moore talked about. Today after this hearing, I'm going to introduce a bill to allow families to deduct their personal exemptions when calculating the AMT, which they can't do under current law today. It makes no sense to me that Congress granted families an exemption for their children but then took it away to calculate the AMT. It was imposed to make the rich pay some taxes, as you know, and it wasn't meant to penalize middle- income American parents and children. With your permission, I will introduce the rest of my remarks into the record. Thank you all for being here today. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Sam Johnson, a Representative in Congress from the State of Texas Mr. Serotta--I'm glad you're with us today and I agree the individual alternative minimum tax (AMT) should be reformed, if not abolished. The AMT is starting to affect our hard working families by penalizing them for having children. Today, after the hearing, I am going to introduce a bill to allow families to deduct their personal exemptions when calculating the AMT which they cannot do under current law. It makes no sense to me that Congress gives families an exemption for their children but then take it away when they calculate the AMT. The AMT was imposed to make sure rich people paid some taxes. It was not meant to penalize middle-income America. So I want to make sure our families are not penalized by the AMT for having children. The message of my bill is simple-- children should not be taxed. Families with children must be recognized as the future of America and should not be penalized. Families should continue to receive personal exemptions when they calculate their taxes. While I think the best thing to do would be to eliminate the entire AMT provision, I believe that, until we can do that, we should protect our parents and children from higher taxes. Congress must take a close look at the tax code and make it as simple as possible, removing provisions like this one that only make it harder to save and plan for their families'future. We granted certain personal exemptions to lower the tax burdens on families. This was the right thing to do because hard working Americans pay too much in taxes. Mr. McCrery. Without objection. Thank you, Mr. Johnson. And thank all of you very much. The meeting is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 12:30 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] REDUCING THE TAX BURDEN ---------- THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 12, 1998 House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, Washington, DC. The Committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:13 a.m., in room 1100, Longworth House Office Building, Hon. Bill Archer (Chairman of the Committee) presiding. Chairman Archer. The Committee will come to order. Today we are holding the third in a series of hearings on proposals to reduce the tax burden on the American people. Taxes as a percentage of gross domestic product are currently at their highest peacetime level in history, and I am committed to bringing that rate down. High taxes represent a moral and a social challenge to families that are struggling to make ends meet. High taxes on savings and investment represent a direct economic challenge, a challenge that especially threatens people who are planning for their retirements. When the government taxes away people's savings, they'll have nowhere to turn but to the government, creating even more pressure on the Social Security system. If you want to save Social Security and help people realize their retirement dreams, you have to stop the government from taxing away people's savings. This is why tax relief is a vital part of saving Social Security. I believe that we can make changes to the current income tax and create incentives to save and invest. While we should not tax capital gains at all, the least we can do is simplify the current capital gains rule by eliminating the 18-month holding period. For 16 million Americans, capital gains is a capital headache. Eliminating the 18-month holding period would be a major simplification. When this Committee begins its consideration of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1998, I plan to include an elimination of the 18-month holding period in my mark, making assets held for more than 1 year eligible for the 10-percent and 20-percent rates. I would refer, now that we head into the income tax preparation time, the people of this country to the new Schedule D form. As everyone knows, I continue to do my own income tax, and I have not begun to try to come to grips with the complexities in this new Schedule D form on capital gains. But, believe me, it is going to pose a real headache for the American people, and we need to change that and simplify it by reducing the holding period from 18 months to 12 months. We also need to look at reducing taxes on investment income, especially for middle-class families. An exemption for interest and dividend income, such as the one proposed by Mr. Hulshof, is of particular interest. It would help turn people who don't save into people who do and encourage those who save only a little bit to save a little more. It would be a huge simplification for those 30 million taxpayers who would no longer have to keep track of 1099 and other investment records. Finally--I've said this before, and I'm going to say it again--as the Committee weighs the merits of various tax proposals, I will be conservative, and I do not intend to over- promise. I will never, I repeat, tip the budget out of balance. And now, I am pleased to recognize Mr. Rangel for any opening statement that he might like to make. Mr. Rangel. Mr. Rangel. Thank you so much, Mr. Chairman. I share your concerns about complexities that we have to deal with in whole or in part in the Tax Code. I'm very concerned as to whether or not the Committee is just going to focus on possible simplifications as relates to capital gains or how much of the Committee's time is actually going to be examining taxes or sales taxes or pulling up the Tax Code by the roots and putting in a new Tax Code. Because if we are not going to do it in the short time that we have, I think that the Committee would be better able to concentrate on the schedule that you drafted rather than the rhetoric that we hear with those that are on the bus rides around the country. Certainly, if there is going to be a serious consideration of replacing the Code, I want to be a part of that. But it is difficult to do when we have so many different opinions in the Minority, as well as in the Majority, as to the best way that we can do that. Having said that, I will add to complexity by introducing legislation with Mr. Ensign that would increase the State volume limit on low-income housing tax credits. Also, I'll be introducing legislation that the President has suggested, hoping that we can get bipartisan support in a variety of other areas that I hope that our staffs can work on together. So that when we are in agreement with the President's recommendations, we can do it in a bipartisan way, and so that in areas that there are disagreements or that the issue will not reach our calendar, that we would know that. But most of all, I'm concerned with how much time, since I understand that we have such a short legislative period, we would be concentrating on a new system or whether we would just move forward in trying to make it less complicated than it is in view after the last tax bill, and wait until the next session to deal with a broader attempt to substitute or reform the Tax Code. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The opening statements follow:] Opening Statement of Hon. Charles B. Rangel, a Representative in Congress from the State of New York Mr. Chairman, I would like to inquire about our Committee agenda and whether we will see a proposal on tax restructuring this year. I keep being asked about tax restructuring. Until I see some details, it is very difficult to respond. The President has proposed that we use any potential budget ``surplus'' to Save Social Security First. The Democratic Members of this Committee will introduce legislation today to act on the President's wise counsel and reserve any surplus for Social Security. It is important that we maintain the fiscal discipline that has led to our improved budget outlook. In addition, the President's budget recommendations contain a variety of tax provisions which are fully offset and for which there is fairly broad bipartisan support. I believe that we should also hold hearings on those issues and have an opportunity to legislate on those issues this year. For example: Low-Income Housing Tax Credit Mr. Ensign and I have introduced legislation to increase the State volume limitation on the low income housing tax credit. I was very pleased that the President's budget contained a similar increase. There is much bipartisan support for the low income housing credit. Education The President's budget includes an expansion of the education zone program that we were able to include in last year's Taxpayer Relief Act. This expansion would provide needed assistance to State and local governments in meeting the need to repair and construct public schools. I intend to introduce legislation soon that includes the President's education tax incentive and hope there will be bipartisan support for addressing the issue of school construction. Addressing this issue through an expansion of last year's Act will minimize bureaucracy which should alleviate some of the Republican concerns. Some have argued that the Federal government has no role in this area. I would point out that the Federal government has historically assisted school construction through low-interest rates on tax-exempt bonds. The President's proposal is another way of assisting local governments in raising low-cost capital. Child Care The President's budget includes tax provisions to assist working families in meeting child care expenses. Again I believe there will be bipartisan interest in this issue and I hope we will be able to have hearings to develop a bipartisan response. Extenders The President's budget proposes an extension of expiring provisions such as the research credit, work opportunity credit, welfare-to-work credit, and brownfields tax incentives. I am hopeful we can work together to address these issues. Mr. Chairman, I would also like to inquire as to whether this Committee will consider tobacco legislation this year. Many of the proposals being discussed have fees that look a lot like an excise tax. This Committee has a strong jurisdictional claim on those aspects of the proposed legislation and we should assert our jurisdiction. In addition, our authority to establish trust funds enables us to have a voice in how the proceeds of those taxes will be spent. We should have hearings. Finally, Mr. Chairman, I would like to say a few words about the issue of today's hearing. In our rush last year to provide benefits for capital gains and savings, we lost track of the need to have simple tax laws. The capital gain tax reductions in last year's bill are unnecessarily complex. Eliminating the 18-month holding period requirement as suggested by the Chairman will not eliminate any line of the very complex capital gains schedule. Eliminating that requirement would reduce the amount of gains in the 28- percent capital gains category but it would not eliminate that rate category. The really distressing aspect of the capital gains provisions of last year's bill, is that they will get worse in the future. In 2001, another rate category will be added. The complexities of that new rate will make the calculations taxpayers are struggling with now look simple. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.198 Chairman Archer. The Chair would be most pleased if the gentleman from New York would give his suggestions on how we might simplify the Code or how we might, as he said, ``tear it up by its roots,'' and any recommendations that you have will be received and thoughtfully considered. The Chair knows of none so far, but the Chair would certainly welcome them at any time. Our first witness today is Mr. Hulshof, a Member of the Committee---- Mr. Rangel. May I respond to that, Mr. Chairman? Chairman Archer. Mr. Rangel. Mr. Rangel. Am I to believe from your remarks that, unless I introduce a reform bill, we will not be considering one? Because that's not the first time that you have responded that way. Chairman Archer. What I said to the gentleman, I think is clear: that whether you introduce a bill or whether you make informal suggestions as to how we might simplify the Code or completely reform the Code, the Chair will give them full consideration, whether they be done privately or publicly and in whatever form. I would be more than happy to receive any suggestions that you might have. Mr. Rangel. The Chair is not responsive to my question as to whether or not the leadership was coming forth with a bill, but I appreciate your answer that you will entertain any recommendations that I have, and I thank you for that. Chairman Archer. The Chair will always be in a position to prepare a mark for the Committee, and that mark will take into consideration any suggestions that you might have. As the gentleman knows, this need not be in formal legislative form. The mark that the Chair presents to the Committee traditionally, is not a statutory-language, pre-prepared bill, but one that is put together after consultation with Members of the Committee. The Chair would like to include the Minority in those consultations, but so far has received no suggestions or recommendations from the Minority. Mr. Hulshof. STATEMENT OF HON. KENNY C. HULSHOF, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF MISSOURI Mr. Hulshof. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Mr. Rangel, Members of the Committee, thanks for the opportunity to testify before you today about a piece of legislation that you, Mr. Chairman, alluded to, and that is the SAVE Act, and that is the Savings Advancement and Enhancement Act, legislation that my friend from Ohio, Mr. Kucinich, and I plan to introduce today. I also appreciate the chance to have these series of hearings. You mentioned several times, Mr. Chairman, that the percentage of taxes of GDP, now nearly 20 percent, is at the highest rate since World War II, and I have appreciated the chance to participate in the series of hearings that we've had on reducing the Federal tax burden on the American people. As you alluded in your opening comments, as a general principle, individuals and families in this country need to be encouraged to save and invest. In fact, the U.S. national savings rate, as you know, ranks among the lowest of the industrialized countries, especially among the G-7 countries. Many economists believe that the reason for this low rate of savings is because of tax laws that discourage saving in favor of consumption. Mr. Kucinich and I believe that this bill is something that will remedy, at least for the small investor, that bias. As families sit around the kitchen table this coming April to do their tax returns, money that they have earned on their interest-bearing savings account, interest-bearing checking accounts, money-market accounts, or even wise investments are included in income for tax purposes. And many of these individuals who have been slugging away their nickels and their dimes each year find themselves subject to this tax. Many of them are middle- and low-income taxpayers. We should be rewarding their thrift rather than punishing their thrift. The bill is very simple, and I would invite other Members of the Ways and Means Committee to cosponsor this legislation. I think we have 5 Members on right now. But the SAVE Act is very simple. It would allow an individual taxpayer to exclude $200 of interest and/or dividend income for tax purposes, or for joint filers, $400. This exclusion could be made up of a combination of interest income and/or dividend income. You know, many of the constructive comments that I heard back in Missouri in the Ninth District after our tax-relief act of last year, people were very happy that we enacted the first tax relief in 16 years, but one of the constructive comments was the targeted nature of the tax relief, and, as we've already heard this morning, the discussion about the simplification issue. The SAVE Act, I think, accomplishes both of those two goals. In the tax year of 1995 there were 66 million individual tax returns that included interest income for tax purposes. In that same taxable year, 26 million returns included a small amount of dividend income, and most of those were small investors. This is not a bill where those on the other side would say that we're simply giving tax breaks for the wealthy. Twenty-three percent of those who would get the benefit of this SAVE Act have incomes between $1 and $15,000, and clearly two- thirds have incomes between $1 and $50,000. So, we're really trying to focus on the small investor in the low- to middle- income families. If this modest proposal were enacted--and I think that it is very doable, Mr. Chairman--in total over 30 million tax returns would no longer have a tax on savings and investment. Thirty million taxpayers would not be taxed on their thrift with this $200-$400 exclusion. As is customary, Mr. Chairman, I would like to have my entire statement in the record. I have an example that you can look at particularly as it is compounded interest and certainly the savings would be modest in the short term, but, again, I think if you are looking over the long term--and Mr. Chairman, you mentioned in your opening remarks, as we look at retirement plans and Social Security and ways that we can help the American people plan for their retirement, this is the way to do that especially if we reduce the tax burden over the long term. The other point that I'd like to make as far as the across the board relief is the simplification measure. For a majority of working men and women, their taxable income consists of their wages and a small amount of interest or dividend income. Allowing this $400 exclusion for joint filers eliminates the need for many individuals below the interest and dividend thresholds to include this income when they fill out the returns reducing the number of calculations and also the hassle of gathering all the 1099 forms from multibanking and checking accounts--all of that would be greatly reduced with the introduction and passage of this bill. And finally, I think that it is consistent with--as was discussed--major, fundamental tax reform. I know the Chairman's feelings as far as the consumption tax. This is consistent with that philosophy as well as even the flat-income tax, encouraging savings and investment. Again, taxpayers should be encouraged, not punished for being thrifty. And I think that this proposal falls right in line with the major tax reforms that we have been considering. To anticipate a question from my colleagues as far as the cost, Joint Tax tells us that the 5 year cost of this particular provision would be $15.2 billion. Again, so I think it is very doable. We would urge other Members to cosponsor this legislation. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for giving me and Mr. Kucinich the opportunity to talk about this bill. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Kenny C. Hulshof, a Representative in Congress from the State of Missouri Mr. Chairman, I would like to thank you for the opportunity to testify on behalf of the Savings Advancement and Enhancement Act (SAVE Act), legislation that Representative Dennis Kucinich (D-OH) and I plan to introduce today. Likewise, I would like to thank you for holding the series of hearings on the need to reduce the federal tax burden. With federal taxes making up 19.9% of Gross Domestic Product in 1998, taxes are now higher than any point since World War II. These hearings have helped highlight this fact, and I appreciate the ability to share with the committee one of my ideas on how to let taxpayers to keep more of their hard-earned money. As a general principle, individuals should be encouraged to save and invest. However, every April, when a family gathers around the kitchen table to do their tax returns, the money they have earned from an interest bearing savings or checking account or from a wise investment is included in their income for tax purposes. Many of the individuals who find themselves subject to this tax are low and middle-income taxpayers. It is wrong to punish these people for their thrift. That is why Representative Kucinich and I are introducing the SAVE Act. The bill is quite simple. It allows an individual taxpayer to exclude the first $200 in interest and dividends, $400 for joint filers, from their income for tax purposes. The exclusion could be made up of any combination of interest and dividends. Consider the following. In the 1995 tax year, over 66 million tax returns reported interest income. 26 million returns reported dividend income. All of these individuals would receive relief under the SAVE Act. Likewise, the Joint Committee on Taxation estimates that 19 million joint returns have less than $400 in interest and dividend income. For these families, their tax on savings and investment would be eliminated. In total, over 30 million tax returns would no longer include a tax on savings and investment. Let me give you a real-life example of how the SAVE Act can help a family save for the future. Lets assume that a family in the 28% tax bracket receives a $4,000 gift upon the birth of a child. They deposit this money in a savings account earning 5% annually in interest. Under current law, after 18 years, the family would earn $4,944.78 in interest on their $4,000 in savings. Likewise, they would pay $1,384.54 in tax on the interest they earn. However, under the SAVE Act, the same family under the same set of circumstances would earn $5,625.51 in interest, $680.73 more than under current law. More importantly, instead of paying $1,384.54 in tax, the SAVE Act would limit the family's tax on savings to $30.74 over the course of the 18 years, and the family would not incur a tax on thrift until the 16th year of the 18 year time span. Overall, under the SAVE Act, this family would save $2,034.53 when compared to the current law tax treatment of interest and dividend income. For the average family in Missouri's Ninth District, this $2,034.53 is a significant amount of money. The SAVE Act also simplifies the tax code. For the vast majority of taxpayers, taxable income consists of wages and minimal amounts of interest income. Allowing the $400 interest and dividend exclusion for joint filers, $200 for single filers, eliminates the need for individuals below these interest and dividend thresholds to include this income when filling out a tax return. Reducing the number of calculations that a taxpayer must make when completing their tax return is certainly a step in the right direction. Also, the hassle of a taxpayer gathering various 1099 forms from multiple banking and checking accounts when filling out a tax return will be greatly reduced. The SAVE Act is also consistent with the major fundamental tax reform proposals currently under consideration. Under the Flat Tax proposed by Majority Leader Dick Armey (R-TX), the 17% Flat-Tax would apply only to wage, salary and pension income. A national sales tax would tax consumption, not income. Whether you support a Flat-Tax or a consumption tax, there is a consensus. Taxpayers should not be punished for being thrifty. Mr. Chairman, I thank you for the opportunity to testify before the committee on behalf of the SAVE Act. As I mentioned earlier, I stand ready to help you relieve the American people of their crushing tax burden. I would be willing to answer any questions members of the committee may have at this time. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Hulshof. Our next witness is Congressman Dennis Kucinich of Ohio. We're happy to have you before the Committee. I think that this may be the first time you have testified before---- Mr. Kucinich. Yes, it is. Chairman Archer [continuing]. This Committee, and I hope that you will feel welcome, and you may proceed. STATEMENT OF HON. DENNIS J. KUCINICH, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF OHIO Mr. Kucinich. I do, and thank you very much, Mr. Chairman, for the opportunity to come before the Committee. I am pleased to be here with Congressman Hulshof because I believe that together we have laid the groundwork for a bill that can be supported on both sides of the aisle. I am certainly pleased to work with you on this because I think that the opportunity is here to come up with a Tax Code that will benefit millions and millions of Americans and at the same time simplify the tax process. Those are two tests that I think that the Chairman would certainly appreciate--I would hope so. I represent a substantial part of the city of Cleveland and its southern and western suburbs. In the past I have challenged the wisdom of certain tax cuts. Last year I opposed tax cuts because I believe they were designed primarily to--to benefit primarily the wealthiest while shrinking vital government services and guarantees. But this SAVE Act is different and it has a lot going for it. The SAVE Act is fair, it benefits a lot of people, and it can be offset with other improvements to the Tax Code. Now, consider the SAVE Act's fairness. The SAVE Act exempts from taxation an individual's first $200 in dividend and interest income, $400 for couples filing jointly. Obviously it is most valuable to those people whose interest from earnings and dividends are below the exemption threshold. These are small savers, and they tend to be people with middle and lower incomes. Sixty-seven percent of the returns claiming taxable- interest income were filed by taxpayers with adjusted gross incomes below $50,000. And 57 percent of returns reporting dividend income were filed by taxpayers with adjusted gross incomes below $50,000. For many small savers, the SAVE Act will exempt all of the earnings of their savings from taxation. For many others, the SAVE Act will exempt a large portion of the earnings of their savings from taxation. Through the SAVE Act, they can keep what they save. The SAVE Act will benefit many people. Now, according to the Joint Committee on Taxation report I have here, half of all taxpayers reporting taxable interest income in 1995 would not have had to pay any tax on their interest if the SAVE Act had been in place. That is a substantial number of people. Now, JCT calculates, as Mr. Hulshof pointed out, that 30 million taxpayers would have earned a tax-free rate of return on their interest and dividend-yielding assets. Again, the majority of these people are small or modest savers earning low or middle incomes. Finally, the SAVE Act can and should be an element in improving the Tax Code, a project which should find offsets by closing persistent, unfair tax loopholes. I would hope the Committee would consider it--closing loopholes that create the wrong incentives on trade, job creation, and job retention in the United States. For example, there is a loophole that exempts U.S. corporations from paying taxes when they move out of the United States and then ship their goods back to the United States for sale. That loophole could be closed. The President has also recommended closing several loopholes. For instance, the loophole for hybrid transactions that created unfair advantage for U.S. companies to make foreign investments rather than domestic investments in job, plants, and equipment. The President also recommends that this Committee prepare the country for justice and environmental cleanup by reinstating superfund taxes so as to make polluters pay for the cost of cleaning up rather than innocent taxpayers. Closing these loopholes adds greater fairness to our Tax Code. In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, the SAVE Act is viable, fair, and will benefit middle- and low-income savers the most. The SAVE Act is perfect for my constituents on the west side of Cleveland and in the surrounding suburban communities who save for a car, tuition, and vacation. They have saved now in order to consume later. The SAVE Act gives them a little more of their savings' earnings, so they can purchase that car a little sooner or afford a little more tuition. The SAVE Act rewards them for their thrift. So, I appreciate the opportunity to work with Mr. Hulshof and others in this, and am hopeful that you, Mr. Chairman, will give this favorable consideration and that we can move this bill forward in this session. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Hon. Dennis J. Kucinich, a Representative in Congress from the State of Ohio Mr. Chairman, Ranking Member Rangel, and members of the Committee. Thank you for the opportunity to come before you to speak in favor of the Savings Advancement and Enhancement Act (SAVE act). I represent a substantial part of the City of Cleveland and its southern and western suburbs. In the past, I have challenged the wisdom of certain tax cuts. Last year, I opposed tax cuts that were obviously designed to benefit primarily the wealthiest, while shrinking vital government services and guarantees. But the SAVE act is different, and it has a lot going for it. The SAVE act is fair, it benefits a lot of people, and it can be offset with other improvements to the tax code. Consider the SAVE act's fairness. The SAVE act exempts from taxation an individual's first $200 in dividend and interest income; $400 for couples filing jointly. Obviously, it will be most valuable to people whose earnings from interest and dividends is below the exemption threshold. These are ``small savers'' and they tend to be people with middle- and low- incomes. Sixty-seven (67) percent of returns claiming taxable interest income were filed by taxpayers with adjusted gross incomes below $50,000. And 57 percent of returns reporting dividend income were filed by taxpayers with adjusted gross incomes below $50,000. For many small savers, the SAVE act will exempt all of the earnings of their savings from taxation. For many others, the SAVE act will exempt a large portion of the earnings of their savings from taxation. Through the SAVE act, they can keep what they save. The SAVE act will also benefit many people. According to the Joint Committee on Taxation, half of all taxpayers reporting taxable interest income in 1995 would not have had to pay any tax on their interest if the SAVE act had been in place. That is a substantial number of people. JCT calculates that 30 million taxpayers ``would have earned a tax-free rate of return on their interest and dividend yielding assets.'' Again, the majority of those people are small or modest savers earning low-or middle-incomes. Finally, the SAVE act can and should be an element in improving the tax code, a project which should find offsets by closing persistent, unfair tax loopholes. The Committee should consider closing loopholes that create the wrong incentives on trade, job creation and job retention in the U.S. For instance, there is a loophole that exempts U.S. corporations from paying taxes when they move out of the U.S. but then ship their goods back to the U.S. for sale. That loophole should be closed. The President has also recommended closing several loopholes. This Committee can prepare the country for justice in environmental clean-up by reinstating Superfund taxes so as to make polluters pay for the cost of cleaning up, rather than innocent taxpayers. Closing those loopholes adds greater fairness to our tax code. In conclusion, the SAVE act is viable, fair and will benefit middle- and low-income savers the most. The SAVE act is perfect for my constituents on the West Side of Cleveland and surrounding communities, who save for a car, tuition, and vacation. They save now in order to consume later. The SAVE act gives them a little bit more of their savings' earnings, so they can purchase that car a little sooner, or afford a little more tuition. The SAVE act rewards them for their thrift. Chairman Archer. I compliment both you gentlemen for your work on this SAVE Act. Mr. Kucinich, are you aware of the fact that if we reinstate the superfund tax that all that money will have to go to cleanup waste sites? Mr. Kucinich. Well---- Chairman Archer. How could that be used to offset your tax suggestion? Mr. Kucinich. I would say that if you did reinstate that to clean up waste sites, that would create further offsets in other areas that would benefit the taxpayers. Chairman Archer. That is new spending, additional spending that's not going on right now. The tax is earmarked and designed specifically for the purpose of cleaning up. I'm surprised that you would suggest that as an offset for a tax reduction when it is already committed to and earmarked for other spending. Mr. Kucinich. The suggestion was made in the spirit ofpointing out how we can force more accountability in the Tax Code and at the same time achieving some benefits for the constituents. Chairman Archer. Well, I would simply say to the gentleman that before this Committee we really have to be very precise as we talk about offsets. If the gentleman would like to submit a list of the specific offsets--not including the superfund tax which clearly is committed to a specific spending program that the people of this country believe is needed--we'll be happy to receive them. If the gentleman is referring to the list that the President has set up---- Mr. Kucinich. I am. Chairman Archer. Then I would simply tell him that even the Washington Post had an article last week that says it slams the middle class, hits widows with annuities and taxes savings which are inside buildup of life-insurance policies which hit the holders of those policies--and those are the major areas of revenue raising. If you call those loopholes, I think that you are going to find an awful lot of people in this country, including widows with annuities, will come out and say, ``Hey, wait a minute, that's not a loophole.'' Mr. Kucinich. I don't think that I disagree with you on that, but when I spoke to superfund, I was relating directly to the President's comments on the--on revenue suggestions. Chairman Archer. Well, those are most certainly revenues, but they are committed and spoken for revenues that will have to go into the payment for the cleanup which will not occur without those revenues. Certainly the gentleman would not want to see those moneys go for tax reduction and not cleaning up the waste sites? Mr. Kucinich. Well, I have been a strong supporter of that, Mr. Chairman, and at the same time, I think that the President's revenue suggestions would not deny the concerns that you have, but at the same time there is a suggestion that the revenue would be there with those offsets. Chairman Archer. Well, let me be sure that I understand you. If we get a superfund reform bill that structurally cleans up waste sites instead of putting money into the hands of lawyers, then we will consider reinstating the superfund taxes so that money can then be spent to cleanup waste sites. Now, do you think it can be spent twice? Do you think it can be also spent to pay for tax reduction in the SAVE Act? Mr. Kucinich. I'd be willing to consider the Chairman's views on this. Mr. Hulshof. I think, Mr. Chairman, you point out the very difficult prospect that we face as a Committee. And I think that the American people don't understand the fact that if, in fact, we have true, honest surpluses, that those surpluses can't be used for tax reduction. And I think that certainly, under current budget laws being as they are with PAY-GO, and coming up with revenue offsets, that's the difficulty. When we try to craft and cobble together additional tax relief for the American people under present budget laws it is very difficult, and I think it is a misnomer because folks in my district believe that if there is a surplus that those moneys can be immediately used to reduce taxes. And we need to help make that case to the American people--if that is the way that we want to go--that the budget rules would have to be changed. But certainly--I hope that whatever we decide as far as revenue offsets and additional tax reductions and where that money should come from, I don't think that it in any way prejudices the idea of the SAVE Act. And again, we think that as we focus on savings and investment, particularly for the small investor, that the concept of the SAVE Act is good. It is doable in the sense that it is a $15 billion--over 5 years, which is, granted, significant, but I think it is still an attainable goal. And I certainly would hope that if we are able to put together a tax bill in this session, that you would look favorably, Mr. Chairman, and include this in the mark. Chairman Archer. Well, I think that the gentleman's response is a good one, and certainly, as I have said in my preliminary comments, I compliment both of you for what I think is a constructive proposal. But I'm not sure that it is realistic to say that we're going to pay for this by closing loopholes and reinstating the superfund tax. That just doesn't mesh. Hopefully when we do have a tax bill we will be able to offset it by using surplus, which is a result of people paying in more taxes. But the only reason that we will have a surplus is the dramatic increase in tax we take out of the American people's pockets. And surely they should be entitled to get some of that back since they are the ones providing the surplus in the first place. Let me ask you one specific technical question, and then I'll move on to recognizing other Members of the Committee. Is it your intention to give an exemption to everyone irrespective of the amount of interest and dividends that they have, or will it only apply to those with under $200 and $400? Mr. Hulshof. No, sir. Our intent is for this to be complete, across-the-board relief, no phaseouts. And so certainly those that recognize great amounts of investment income would be allowed to have this exclusion as well, but clearly those on the low-income spectrum are the ones that proportionally gain. And the $400 exclusion for an investor who derives great amounts of investment income, it would not be that significant. It would be less significant to that investor. Chairman Archer. Thank you. Does any other Member wish to inquire? Mrs. Johnson. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Just briefly. Thank you for your testimony. Do you protect this from the alternative minimum tax, or is it given preference under the alternative minimum tax, so that the alternative minimum tax can't deny people this protection of their savings? Mr. Hulshof. Mrs. Johnson, that is a great question, and as it is presently drafted, no, there is no particular protection against the alternative minimum tax, but I would be happy to look at that because I think---- Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. I think we have to be much more conscious of that in future legislation. I thank you for a very thoughtful proposal. I would, Mr. Kucinich, I would just share with you that some of the proposals in the President's tax bill this time are proposals that he made last time, and they have no support by Members of either party because some of them, in fact, would force jobs offshore. His proposal to tax annuities this time is particularly destructive to middle-income women for whom it is a key component of retirement security. So, unfortunately, we cannot look at his tax proposals to fund proposals like this that frankly are very thoughtful and in our interest. And I appreciate your proposing them. Thank you. Chairman Archer. Mr. Ramstad. Mr. Ramstad. Mr. Chairman, just very briefly. First of all, I want to thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your leadership in calling this hearing on these critical savings and investment-tax issues, and I want to compliment my colleagues at the witness table for what is really a straight forward proposal with twin benefits as I see it. A broad-base tax relief without complexity that encourages savings and investments. However, I must say to Mr. Kucinich--I do share my colleague's concerns about what the administration calls ``unwarranted benefits.'' I know in your testimony you state that the cost of the SAVE Act could be offset with improvements in the Tax Code. You allude to the loopholes. But I think that we all have to take heed of the study not too long ago by Professor Feldstein at Harvard--former chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors. He very carefully and very studiously, after exhaustive research, documented the fact that were we to convert all of our current savings to plant and equipment, our savings rate is so abysmally low that we could not sustain any long-term economic growth. That is a frightening indictment of our savings rate in this country which rates, as we all know, a distant last among our G-7 trading partners. So, I certainly share the Chairman's concern and Mrs. Johnson's concern about the administration's proposals which really attack long-term savings vehicles that are so important to the middle class and those who are trying to save in this country. So, I hope that you will review, Mr. Kucinich, all of these so-called ``unwarranted benefits'' because I believe that they are very counterproductive to our goal of encouraging savings in this country. Chairman Archer. Mr. Collins. Mr. Collins. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you two gentlemen for this proposal. I've always been opposed to taxing interest earned on savings. I think it is a disincentive to save. Mr. Kucinich, Mr. Hulshof mentioned some real problems that we face when it comes to the budget law and restraints there based on the fact that that the PAY-GO versus the fact that we can't use savings in discretionary areas for tax relief. Do you have a position or any input on the suggestions that Mr. Hulshof has indicated need to be addressed or looked at in the budget law itself? Mr. Kucinich. As part of this process of working on this bill, I am getting more and more into some of these issues the kind that Mr. Hulshof has addressed. And I think that these are issues that are worthy of discussion. I keep an open mind on it. The Chairman has made some comments which I am grateful for. I have some of my own ideas about how we come to a situation where--for example, on the superfund, if you will-- which is something that I am very concerned about--how the taxpayers' money ends up--taxpayers end up paying a substantial amount of money for the bailout, and I happen to come from the persuasion that we should have done more to have the industries pay more for that instead of taxpayers. Now, I have a different--you know, I come to this recommendation with a different point of view than some of you may. But through my presence here, I demonstrate that though we may be on different sides of the aisle there are issues that we might be able to agree on even though we may have different conclusions as to why--or different reasons why we would take this particular position. And so, as I work in a bipartisan manner, I am understanding a little bit more of your point of view about some of these issues, and I hope that this will be an opportunity to present my point of view as well. And through that dialog, perhaps, maybe we can both--certainly on my part, maybe I can learn a little bit more about your views. Mr. Collins. Well, it's always good to have an open dialog and debate, but I do recommend that you heed closely the concerns that Mr. Hulshof mentioned in the area of restraints that we have when it comes to budget law, and how we can--as we save funds through different programs, we are not allowed to use those funds for tax relief to the taxpayer. Mr. Kucinich. I understand it---- Mr. Collins. I urge you to pay close attention to that. Mr. Kucinich. I will do that, and I appreciate your word of caution on that. Chairman Archer. Mr. Weller. Mr. Weller. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and again, I want to commend you for your leadership on this series of hearings on reducing the tax burden on middle-class families. I also want to commend Representatives Hulshof and Kucinich for your initiative here. When I was in legislature, I had a similar piece of legislation at the State level, so I think that any incentive to increase savings, particularly for retirement--I know that Representative Hulshof and I have had conversations, and one of the concerns that I have is that so many Americans have so little in savings for their retirement. I saw a statistic this past fall where the average 55-year-old had less than $10,000 in savings for retirement. And frankly, that is scary when you think about it. And that is why ideas such as this legislation are good ones that we should be looking at. I also want to commend the sponsors, too, for recognizing the need to avoid the marriage-tax penalty. Because, in your legislation, by doubling the exemption for a married couple by $200 to $400, you avoid any marriage-tax penalties, and that has been one of the problems with the President's ideas of targeted tax cuts because every time he proposes a targeted tax cut, he always seems to create another marriage-tax penalty. So, I want to commend you for that. And I have a question that I would like to address to Mr. Kucinich, as part of, I guess, my friend from Georgia, Mr. Collins had mentioned. You know, this--your proposal here, of course, is an idea that we hope will encourage people to be able to save for their retirement. And the President, in his budget this past week, proposed a new tax on a retirement vehicle used by many middle-class Americans, annuities, which are, of course, an insurance product that many Americans purchased for their retirement plan. I was wondering, how do you feel? Do you support the President's new tax on annuities? Mr. Kucinich. I have--from what I have read about it and understand about it, I haven't advocated that position. I'm-- I'd like the chairman to understand that in this last budget I was one of the people from the other side of the aisle. I voted against that last budget and the last tax proposal because I didn't agree with it. And I'm not in favor of this particular point that Mr. Weller is bringing out. I--while I consider myself supportive of many of the President's proposals, I don't agree with him on that one, and I'm willing to say so publicly. Mr. Weller. So, you oppose his tax on annuities? Mr. Kucinich. The one that you just talked about, I would say that I'm not in favor of it at this time; I don't favor it. Mr. Weller. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Does any other Member wish to inquire? Mr. Collins. Mr. Chairman, if I could---- Chairman Archer. Mr. Watkins. Mr. Collins [continuing]. Just make one quick statement. I was in Japan 3 weeks ago with a group, and the parliament members of the Japanese Government as well as some of the other officials reiterated several times that the personal savings in Japan is equivalent to between $10 and $11 trillion, far exceeding what we save here in this country. So, I appreciate what your doing. Chairman Archer. Mr. Watkins. Mr. Watkins. I'd like to thank the Members. We just got back from a retreat some would say that they like to think of it as being an advance--and I think that one of the advance things that we've got to do is increase savings. We're the lowest industrialized nation in the world with regard to savings, I think about 3.5% or so. And one of my closing remarks down at the retreat, or advance, was the fact that if we didn't increase our savings, it was going to be hard for us to maintain and sustain the economic growth that we have. And I think the Chairman talked about a couple of ways that might be considered along with other things that could be done. And what concerns me is--the gentleman from Georgia just mentioned Japan. The Asian countries, Japan specifically, has underwritten a lot of our government securities over the last few years, in the early eighties, and they have somewhere between $150 billion and a $200 billion invested already in some of the other Asian areas. If a serious problem develops there, they will be pulling their investments and moneys out of our country and trying to shore up, I think, a lot of their other investments. I think they won't have much choice. And we've seen what the depressed real estate values in Thailand did to Hong Kong. It dropped that market by 10 percent, and it is dropping our GDP, all estimates would be, about a half percent of the GDP. And so that doesn't encompass the entire Asian problem. And we have got to increase, I think as rapidly as we can, the savings of this country so we can be in control of our own destiny, so to speak, a lot more. So, I commend everyone for trying to work on that area. Thank you. Chairman Archer. Thank you, gentlemen. Mr. Hulshof. Thank you, Chairman. Mr. Kucinich. Thank you. Chairman Archer. We appreciate your presentation. Our next panel, Mr. Bloomfield, Mr. Entin, and Mr. Stevenson, would you come to the witness table? Welcome, gentlemen. The rules of the Committee are as follows. We would be pleased if you would limit your oral presentation to 5 minutes or less. The lights in front of you will tell you--when the yellow light comes on, it will be 1 minute to go, and when the red light comes on, it is 5 minutes. Your entire written statements, without objection, will be included in the record. And we are very pleased to have all three of you before the Committee. If you will identify yourselves at the beginning of your testimony for the record, then you may proceed. Mr. Bloomfield, would you lead off, please? STATEMENT OF MARK BLOOMFIELD, PRESIDENT, AMERICAN COUNCIL FOR CAPITAL FORMATION, ACCOMPANIED BY MARGO THORNING, SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT AND CHIEF ECONOMIST Mr. Bloomfield. Mr. Chairman, my name is Mark Bloomfield. I am president of the American Council for Capital Formation, and I'm accompanied by Dr. Margo Thorning, our senior vice president and chief economist. Let me make five brief points today. First, an overview: The ACCF strongly supports the emphasis Ways and Means Chairman, Bill Archer, has placed on the significant impact of tax policy on savings and investment that is so critical for our continued economic growth. Although the current economic news is good, I share the concerns of the new GAO report that even though Federal budget deficits have declined recently, total national savings and investment remain significantly below the average of the sixties and seventies and continue to compare unfavorably with our that of international competitors. Tax policy should be supportive of capital formation if real wages of U.S. workers are to increase, living standards are to advance at a faster pace, and the United States is to maintain the economic strength necessary to sustain its lead in world affairs. Second, the impact of tax policy on savings and investment and economic growth. This Committee is to be commended for its role in the capital formation provisions in the Taxpayers' Relief Act of 1997. In particular, we need to build on the recent progress in capital gains, IRAs, pension, and estate tax relief and reform of the alternative minimum tax. We must now move forward to further prosaving and proinvestment tax policy initiatives in order to maintain strong economic growth. As we move into the 21st century, we need to address new challenges such as demographic changes, more stringent environmental regulations, and the inadequate level of U.S. savings and investment. Third, Mr. Chairman, the impact of fundamental or structural tax reform on economic growth. In my testimony today, I have summarized several analyses that suggest that substituting a broad-based consumption tax for the current Federal income tax could have a positive impact on economic growth and living standards. I am particularly intrigued by a relatively new study, Taxation and Economic Growth, by Professor Jonathan Skinner of Dartmouth and Eric Engen of the Federal Reserve who examined the correlation between the type of tax system--income versus consumption tax--levels of economic growth over the period of 1965 to 1991 for a large sample of countries. The conclusion was that income taxation is more harmful to growth than a broad-based consumption tax. The key question, of course, is whether it would be worth the inevitable disruption, cost, and confusion that switching to a totally new tax system would create. I believe that the answer is yes. More reliance on consumption tax could have a profound, positive effect on long-term economic growth. And even small changes in economic growth rates can make a big difference to living standards. Fourth, the short-term agenda before this Committee. While the long-term goal of U.S. Federal tax policy should be the shift toward a broad-based consumption tax under which all income that is saved is exempt from tax, in the short term there are steps forward that the Committee should take and steps backward that the Committee should avoid. Steps forward: We applaud Chairman Archer for his announcement today that the Chairman's mark will propose to eliminate the 18-month holding period. We also urge the Committee to further cut individual capital gains tax rates, cut the corporate capital gains rate to restore the historic parity between the individual and corporate capital gains, expand further IRAs, and strengthen the pension system. We also want to strongly commend Congressman Hulshof for his proposal to restore the dividend-interest exclusion. And I also want to take note of the Individual Investment Accounting Act of H.R. 984, introduced by Mr. McCrery, which is an unlimited IRA. I also want to stress that all of these initiatives must be made in a fiscally responsible manner. Steps backward: We urge the Committee to weigh carefully the proposals, including the revenue raisers, President Clinton has made to ensure that any negative impact on savings and investment is avoided. Fifth, long-term goals. Voter discontent with the income tax, recognition that today's balanced budget is likely to be short-lived, growing awareness that the U.S. Tax Code is biased against savings and investment, increasing concern with tax impediments to the ability of U.S. firms to compete in the new global marketplace and the growing expert opinion that tax reform could raise total output, all argue that fundamental tax reform should be a key long-term goal of U.S. policymaking. In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, you have served on the Ways and Means Committee for some 28 years. We, at the American Council for Capital Formation, are celebrating our 25th anniversary. We want to take this opportunity to thank you for many years of trying to fix the income tax, whether it was the Archer-Wagner capital cost recovery initiative in the early years or the Archer capital gains tax initiative or the capital formation measures in last year's tax bill. We now look forward to working with you and this Committee on more basic, structural changes in U.S. tax policy to enable this country to face the economic challenges of the 21st century. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Mark Bloomfield, President, American Council for Capital Formation Introduction My name is Mark Bloomfield. I am president of the American Council for Capital Formation (ACCF). I am accompanied by Dr. Margo Thorning, our senior vice president and chief economist. The ACCF represents a broad cross-section of the American business community, including the manufacturing and financial sectors, Fortune 500 companies and smaller firms, investors, and associations from all sectors of the economy. Our distinguished board of directors includes cabinet members of prior Republican and Democratic administrations, former members of Congress, prominent business leaders, and public finance experts. The ACCF is now celebrating its twenty-fifth year of leadership in advocating tax and regulatory policies to increase U.S. saving, investment, and economic growth. Our testimony today begins with a discussion of trends in U.S. capital formation and the impact of tax policy on economic growth. Next, we outline a short-term tax policy agenda, including shortening the 18-month capital gains holding period, reducing individual and corporate capital gains tax rates, expanding saving incentives such as Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), restoring the dividend and interest exclusion, and strengthening the pension system. We conclude with options for long-term, fundamental tax reform. These policies will promote increased U.S. saving and capital formation and lead to strong and sustainable economic growth as our nation enters the twenty-first century. We vigorously support the emphasis that Chairman Archer has placed on the significance of saving and investment for economic growth. Tax policy should be supportive of capital formation if real wages for U.S. workers are to increase, living standards are to advance at a faster pace, and the United States is to maintain the economic strength necessary to sustain its leading role in world affairs. The Impact of Tax Policy on Saving, Investment, and Economic Growth The Ways and Means Committee is to be commended for its role in the pro-capital formation provisions in the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, including the reduction in individual capital gains tax rates, expansion of IRAs, estate and gift tax relief, and reform of the corporate alternative minimum tax. We must now move ahead to further pro-saving and pro- investment tax policy initiatives. Although the short-term outlook for the U.S. economy suggests continued growth, long- term strength and economic stability require well-thought-out changes in tax policy. In order to maintain strong economic growth as we move into the twenty-first century, the United States must address new challenges such as the demographic changes that will leave the United States with a smaller ratio of workers to retirees, more stringent environmental regulations, and inadequate levels of U.S. saving and investment over the long term. Without sufficient saving and investment and cost-effective regulatory policies, the United States cannot continue indefinitely to enjoy one of the highest living standards in the world. Investment spending in the United States in recent years compares unfavorably with that of other nations as well as with our own past experience. From 1973 to 1995, gross nonresidential investment as a percent of gross domestic product (GDP) was lower for the United States than for any of our major competitors (see Table 1). The U.S. net saving rate during the same period is also low relative to that of most other industrialized countries, averaging 5.9 percent compared to 18.8 percent in Japan, 10.4 percent in West Germany, and 8.0 percent in Canada. Though the U.S. economy is currently performing better than the economies of most other developed nations, in the long run our low saving and investment rates will inevitably result in a growth rate far short of our true potential. International comparisons aside, even more disturbing is the fact that net business investment in this country has in recent years fallen to less than 60 percent of the level of the 1960s and 1970s. Net private domestic investment averaged 8.9 percent of GDP from 1960 to 1980; since 1991, it has averaged only 5.6 percent (see Table 2). The U.S. net private domestic saving rate, a key determinant of U.S. investment, has also fallen sharply from an average of 8.1 percent in the 1960-1980 period to only 5.7 percent of GDP in the 1990s. Numerous scholarly studies by top-flight experts such as Harvard University's Dale Jorgenson, University of California's J. Bradford De Long, Treasury Deputy Secretary Lawrence Summers and others conclude that investment in plant and equipment is the key factor in increasing productivity and economic growth. Thus, tax policy to promote higher levels of saving and investment is critical to the United States' future prosperity. Recent Evidence on the Impact of Tax Policy and Economic Growth To those who favor a truly level playing field over time to encourage individual and business decisions to save and invest, stimulate economic growth, and create new and better jobs, savings (including capital gains) should not be taxed at all. This view was held by top economists in the past and is held by many mainstream economists today. This is primarily because the income tax hits saving more than oncefirst when income is earned and again when interest and dividends on the investment financed by saving are received, or when capital gains from the investment are realized. The playing field is tilted away from saving and investment because the individual or company that saves and invests pays more taxes over time than if all income were consumed and no saving took place. Taxes on income that is saved raise the capital cost of new productive investment for both individuals and corporations, thus dampening such investment. As a result, future growth in output and living standards is impaired. While fundamental reform of the U.S. federal tax code continues to interest policymakers, the public, and the business community, the key question is whether it would be worth the inevitable disruption, cost, and confusion that switching to a totally new or substantially revised system would create. Several new analyses by academic scholars and government policy experts suggest that substituting a broad- based consumption tax for the current federal income tax could have a positive impact on economic growth and living standards. The macroeconomic models used by the scholars in the studies described below incorporate feedback and dynamic effects in simulating the impact of adopting either a broad-based consumption tax or a ``pure'' income tax. For example, in Simulating U.S. Tax Reform, Professors Alan Auerbach of the University of California and Laurence J. Kotlikoff of Boston University, Drs. Kent A. Smetters and Jan Walliser of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), and David Altig of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland analyze the impact of fundamental tax reform on equity, efficiency, and economic growth.'' \1\ The authors use a general equilibrium model developed by Professors Auerbach and Kotlikoff to examine five tax reforms spanning the major proposals now under discussion. Each of the reforms replaces the federal personal and corporate income taxes, and each is simulated assuming the same growth-adjusted levels of government spending and government debt. The reforms are a ``clean'' income tax and four types of consumption taxes. These consumption taxes are: a) ``clean'' consumption tax; b) a Hall-Rabushka flat tax; c) a Hall-Rabushka flat tax with transition relief; and d) Princeton University Professor David Bradford's ``X tax.'' The clean income tax eliminates all personal exemptions and deductions, and taxes labor and capital income at a single rate. The clean consumption tax differs from the clean income tax by permitting expensing of new investment (meaning that the total cost of the investment is deducted in the first year). This tax is implemented as a tax on wages with all saving exempt from tax at the household level, and as a cash-flow tax on businesses. The Hall-Rabushka flat tax differs from the consumption tax by including a standard deduction against wage income and by not taxing the rental value of owner-occupied housing and the value of services provided by consumer durables. The flat tax with transition relief permits continued depreciation of capital in existence as of the reform. Finally, the Bradford X tax combines a progressive wage tax with a business cash-flow tax where the business cash-flow tax rate equals the highest tax rate applied to wage income. Auerbach et al. conclude that switching to a consumption tax can offer significant economic gains. The Bradford X tax, to which the authors give the highest marks for its impact on equity, efficiency, and economic growth, raises long-term output by 7.5 percent and provides no transition relief from its expensing provisions. It also hits the rich with higher marginal tax rates than the poor. It is not surprising, then, that in the long run the X tax helps those who are poor by more than it helps those who are rich, the authors note. Still, under the X tax there are no long-run losers; even the rich are better off. Transition relief and adjustments that prevent adverse distributional effects lessen the positive impact of tax reform on the economy. Another recent study, the Joint Committee on Taxation's Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, summarizes the results of a number of scholars who compared the macroeconomic consequences of a broad-based unified income tax (a ``clean'' income tax in Auerbach's terminology) to those of a broad-based consumption tax.'' \2\ Participants included Roger E. Brinner, DRI/McGraw-Hill; Eric M. Engen, Federal Reserve Board of Governors; Jane G. Gravelle, Congressional Research Service; Dale W. Jorgenson, Harvard University; Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Boston University; Joel L. Prakken, Macroeconomic Advisers; Gary Robbins, Fiscal Associates; Diane Lim Rogers, CBO; Kent A. Smetters, CBO; Peter J. Wilcoxen, University of Texas; Jan Walliser, CBO; and John G. Wilkens, Coopers & Lybrand. The economic impact of a ``pure'' income tax compared to a ``pure'' consumption tax is shown in Table 3. The effects of the consumption tax proposals on GDP are generally positive over the medium and long terms, although the magnitude of these effects varies widely. For example, the Jorgenson-Wilcoxen model predicts that under a consumption tax, real GDP would be 3.3 percent higher each year in the long run compared to 1.3 percent higher under a unified income tax. The Auerbach, Kotlikoff, Smetters, and Walliser model predicts even greater gains in the long run (7.5 percent) under a consumption tax and losses (-3.0 percent of GDP) under a unified income tax. Similarly, the Engen-Gale analysis shows that the capital stock would be 9.8 percent higher in the long run under a consumption tax but 1.6 percent smaller under a unified income tax compared to current law. The consensus seems to be that the economy would fare better under a ``pure'' consumption tax than under a ``pure'' income tax or under current law. In still another new report, The Economic Effects of Comprehensive Tax Reform, the CBO analyzes the effect of switching from the federal income tax to a comprehensive consumption-based tax using a general equilibrium model developed by University of Texas's Don Fullerton and Diane Lim Rogers of CBO.'' \3\ CBO's analysis shows that substituting a broad-based consumption tax for an income tax would probably increase national saving and ultimately raise the living standards of future generations. It would increase the capital stock and raise the level of national output by between 1 percent and 10 percent, although CBO concludes that increases at the upper end of that range are unlikely. The reform might be expected to increase economic efficiency as well as output for a number of reasons, according to the CBO study. First, the switch to a consumption base would eliminate the influence of taxes on the timing of consumption. Second, the new system might treat different sources' uses of income more uniformly by including more of them in the tax base and subjecting all of them to similar tax rates. Third, a broader base would allow lower overall marginal tax rates, reducing the amount by which taxes affect relative prices and hence all kinds of economic decisions. CBO notes, however, that efficiency is not the only criterion to use in judging the desirability of tax reform. Administrative and compliance costs are other important factors. If a consumption tax offered substantial gains from reduced complexity, then even a minimal gain in economic efficiency would be an added bonus. Another relatively recent study, Taxation and Economic Growth, by Professor Jonathan Skinner of Dartmouth College and Eric M. Engen of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, examines evidence on taxation and growth for a large sample of countries.'' \4\ The type of tax system a country chooses significantly affects that nation's prospects for long-term economic growth, according to Skinner and Engen. Figures 1 and 2 show the correlation in the OECD countries between income taxes and economic growth and between consumption taxes and economic growth over the period 1965-1991. These scatter plots, largely confirmed in regression analysis, suggest that income taxation is more harmful to growth than broad-based consumption taxes, the authors note. Skinner and Engen's study also suggests that tax policy does affect economic growth and that lower tax rates do enhance economic growth. For example, a major tax reform plan which reduces marginal tax rates by 5 percentage points will increase growth by 0.2 to 0.3 points. Even modest growth effects can have an important long-term impact on living standards, Skinner and Engen note. For example, suppose that an inefficient structure of taxation has, since 1960, retarded growth by 0.2 percent annually. Accumulated over the past 36 years, the lower growth rate translates to a 7.5 percent lower level of GDP in 1996, or a net reduction in output of more than $500 billion annually. Thus, the potential effects of tax policy, although difficult to detect in the time-series data, can have potentially very large effects over the long term. The new studies described above reach the same conclusion about the beneficial effect on economic growth of switching to a broad-based consumption tax as earlier research by scholars such as John Shoven and Lawrence Goulder of Stanford University and Dale Jorgenson of Harvard University and Joel Prakken of Macroeconomic Advisers in St. Louis, Missouri.'' \5\ Unfinished Business in Tax Policy Reform: Short-Term Agenda The long-run goal of U.S. federal tax policy should be to shift toward a broad-based consumption tax under which all income that is saved is exempt from tax. In the short term, there are steps forward the Ways and Means Committee could take and steps backward the Committee should avoid. With regard to the latter, President Clinton has made proposals, including revenue raisers, that the Committee must weigh carefully to ensure that they minimize any negative impact on saving and investment. As to the former, we will comment on new saving and investment incentives and modifications to the capital gains law, as requested in the notice of this hearing. Shorten the Eighteen-Month Holding Period for Capital Gains The 1997 tax act contained a substantial reduction in individual capital gains tax rates. For example, The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 reduced the top capital gains rate from 28 to 20 percent on assets held for 18 months or longer. Under prior law, the holding period for a long-term gain was only 12 months. While the capital gains tax rate reduction with a 12- month holding period was estimated by Allen Sinai of Primark Decision Economics and David Wyss of DRI/McGraw-Hill to reduce capital costs by three to four percent, the requirement that assets be held for 18 months rather than 12 months as under prior law tends to diminish the effectiveness of the tax cut. The longer the required holding period before an investor can realize a capital gain, the greater the risk. A higher risk premium means a higher cost of capital; thus less investment will be planned than if the holding period were 12 months. The 18-month holding period also adds an unnecessary layer of complexity to the code. For example, prior to the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, Schedule D, the IRS form for reporting capital gains and losses, had only 23 lines. The Schedule D for 1997 contains 54 linesmore than double the previous number. In addition, most of our international competitors have a holding period for long-term capital gains of one year or less (in fact, many exempt long-term gains from tax). Restoring the 12-month holding period would be a positive step toward lightening taxes on saving and investment. Individual Capital Gains Tax Rates Additional capital gains tax reductions would help move the U.S. tax code toward a consumption tax base and enhance economic growth. Previous studies by Allen Sinai and David Wyss show that individual capital gains tax rates in the 14 percent to 15 percent range have stronger positive effects on capital costs, saving, and investment than does a top rate of 20 percent. Further reductions in the individual tax rate reduce the cost of capital and increase investment, GDP, productivity growth, and employment. In addition, such a tax cut would essentially be revenue neutral, when unlocking and macroeconomic consequences are included. In addition, a 1997 CBO report documents the widespread ownership of capital assets among middle-income taxpayers. According to the CBO report, in 1989, 31 percent of families with incomes under $20,000 held capital assets (not including personal residences) and 54 percent with income between $20,000 and $50,000 held capital assets. Reduce Corporate Capital Gains Tax Rates The 1997 tax reforms failed to include a reduction in the corporate capital gains tax from the 35 percent rate in effect since the 1986 Tax Reform Act, although such a measure was included in the bill reported out by this Committee and later passed by the House. Reducing corporate capital gains tax rates would also help move the U.S. tax code toward a consumption tax base by lightening the burden on income from investment. It could also help increase the Federal revenues needed to assure projected budget surpluses, according to reputable econometric analyses. The failure to reduce corporate capital gains tax rates in conjunction with the 1997 individual rate cuts heightens the inequities already inherent in the double taxation of corporate profits under current law, leading to excessive tax planning, and may accentuate the trend away from the traditional corporate form of organization. Compared to other industrialized nations, the United States taxes corporate capital gains very harshly. The United States taxes corporate capital gains at the ordinary income rate of 35 percent, does not provide for indexation of such gains for inflation, and does not allow capital losses to be used to offset ordinary income. These last two factors increase the risk, and therefore the cost of capital, for corporate investments expected to yield capital gains. Fourteen out of sixteen countries surveyed tax corporate capital gains more favorably than does the United States, either through lower tax rates, by allowing capital losses to offset ordinary income, or by indexing gains for inflation. For example, Germany, the Netherlands, Japan, and Korea permit corporate capital losses to be deducted from ordinary income, and France taxes corporate capital gains at 18 percent. In several of the Pacific Basin countries such as Hong Kong, Singapore, and Malaysia, corporate capital gains are exempt from taxes. We therefore urge the committee to restore the historic parity between individual and corporate capital gains tax rates. Expand Individual Retirement Accounts Under the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, the traditional ``front-loaded'' (tax-deductible) IRAs were substantially expanded and were made more flexible through the addition of penalty-free withdrawal options. In addition, two new types of ``back-loaded'' IRAs were created--the Roth IRA PLUS and the education IRA. Specifically, income limits on the traditional deductible IRAs were phased-up over time. The income limits for the $2,000 IRA deduction, which under prior law phased out between $40,000 and $50,000 of adjusted gross income for joint returns and $25,000 and $35,000 for individuals, are increased gradually beginning in 1998 when the income phase-out range will be between $50,000 and $60,000 of adjusted gross income for joint returns and $30,000 and $40,000 for individuals, until 2007, when the income phase-out range will be between $80,000 and $100,000 for joint returns and $50,000 and $60,000 for individuals. Further expansion of the income limits and contribution ceilings for both front and backloaded IRAs--in particular the education IRA, which is limited to only $500 per yearwould help move the U.S. tax system toward a consumption tax base by lightening the tax burden on saving. Prominent public finance economists and scholars, including former Council of Economic Advisers Chairman Martin Feldstein; Treasury Deputy Secretary Lawrence Summers; and Professors David A. Wise of Harvard University; James M. Poterba of Massachusetts Institute of Technology; Steven E. Venti and Jonathan Skinner of Dartmouth College; and Richard A. Thaler of Cornell University, have concluded that IRAs--especially tax-deductible IRAs--do result in new saving. More than a dozen scholarly studies, using a variety of data sources and employing several different statistical approaches, have examined whether targeted saving vehicles such as IRAs impact saving. For example, Professor Steven Venti's testimony before a Senate Finance Subcommittee in 1994 examined saving data from a Survey of Income and Program Participation for three different age groups (families reaching age 60-64 in 1984, 1987, and 1991). Professor Venti found a striking increase in saving the longer the family has been exposed to the targeted retirement programs: IRAs, 401(k)s, and Keoghs. The growth in IRA asset balances is astounding, Professor Venti noted. The typical member of the youngest age group family--with nine years of exposure to targeted retirement saving programs--has nearly three times the targeted retirement assets of the oldest group. There is a comparable increase in total assets as well. In contrast, among families without IRAs, the youngest families have only about 75 percent the financial assets of the older families ($1,691 vs. $2,247 in constant dollars). Professor Venti concluded that since total financial assets, including balances in IRAs, are much larger for the younger group in 1991 than for the older group that reached age 60-64 in 1984, targeted retirement saving programs did stimulate new saving over the period. Restore the Dividend and Interest Received Exclusion The Tax Reform Act of 1986 repealed the deduction for the first $100 of dividends received by individual shareholders ($200 by a married couple filing jointly) on the grounds that the provision did little to reduce the double taxation of corporate income because its monetary limit was so low. In addition, the Joint Committee on Taxation concluded that the deduction benefited high-bracket taxpayers more than those in low brackets. The 1984 Deficit Reduction Act repealed the 15 percent interest-received exclusion that allowed a taxpayer to exclude up to $3,000 of net interest ($6,000 on a joint return). The reason for the change was that revenue losses under the IRA provisions were higher than expected and also that the provision might direct saving away from equity investment and toward debt. Restoration (and expansion) of the dividend and interest received deductions would be a positive step toward shifting the tax base from income to consumption. By reducing the double tax on corporate income, even if only by a small amount, those provisions would tend to reduce capital costs and encourage saving and investment. Strengthening the Pension System With over $3 trillion in accumulated retirement assets, the employment-based pension system provides a critical part of national savings. But the effectiveness of that system as a savings generator continues to be hampered by layer-upon-layer of unnecessary regulation. Regulations limit who can save, where and when they can save, how much they can save, and when and how they must withdraw savings. Over the last two years--with the creation of a new SIMPLE plan for small business and the repeal of a variety of pension rules--Congress has begun the process of peeling away some of those unnecessary layers of regulation. There is still a long way to go. A good place to start would be continued simplification, including especially the limits on the amount that can be saved and the rules that force withdrawal of existing savings. Unfinished Business in Tax Policy Reform: Long Run Goals Fundamental reform of the U.S. federal tax code remains a key goal for many policymakers. I want to take advantage of this opportunity to express special thanks to Chairman Bill Archer for his dedication and valuable leadership in this regard. Other prominent members of Congress, including House Majority Leader Richard Armey (R-TX) and Senator Richard Shelby (R-AL); Senator Pete Domenici (R-NM); and Representatives Dan Schaefer (R-CO) and Billy Tauzin (R-LA), have all introduced legislation to replace the federal income tax with a broad- based consumption tax. House Minority Leader Richard Gephardt (D-MO) has proposed broadening the current income tax base while lowering rates. In addition, other reform plans are being developed. For example, Senator John Ashcroft (R-MO) has proposed reforming the income tax by reducing marginal rates and providing a deduction for payroll taxes. Also, Americans for Fair Taxation, a private group based in Texas, has proposed replacing the federal income, social security, medicare, and estate taxes with a 23 percent national sales tax. In addition to political factors such as voter discontent with the income tax, several factors contribute to the current interest in tax reform: The recognition that today's balanced federal budget is likely to be a relatively short-lived phenomenon. A new study by the General Accounting Office (GAO) predicts that, absent improvement in GDP growth rates or policy changes such as reduced social security benefits, budget deficits will reemerge by 2012 as baby boomers begin to retire. Tax reform, by encouraging more saving and investment, could be an important tool as we seek to ensure a strong economy in the twenty-first century. A growing awareness that the U.S. federal tax code is biased against the saving and investment that is crucial to improving U.S. economic growth. The new GAO study observes that even though federal budget deficits have declined recently, total national saving and investment remain significantly below the average of the 1960s and 1970s (see Table 2). In addition, the United States has one of the highest tax rates on new investment in the industrialized world. According to a 1994 study by the Progressive Foundation, the think tank affiliate of the Progressive Policy Institute, the effective combined corporate and individual federal tax rate on new investment in the United States is 37.5 percent, compared to an average of 31.1 percent in other G-7 countries (see Figure 3).'' \6\ U.S. multinationals' goal of competing in the global marketplace. Fundamental tax reform could enhance the ability of U.S. firms to compete in global markets by reducing the competitive disadvantage that they face. For example, as a 1997 study sponsored by the ACCF Center for Policy Research, the public policy affiliate of the ACCF, showed, U.S. financial service firms face much higher tax rates than do their international competitors when operating in a third country such as Taiwan (see Figure 4).'' \7\ A twelve-country analysis shows that U.S. insurance firms are taxed at a rate of 35 percent on income earned abroad compared to 14.3 percent for French-, Swiss-, or Belgian-owned firms. As a consequence of their more favorable tax codes, foreign financial service firms can offer products at lower prices than can U.S. firms, thereby giving them a competitive advantage in world markets. Under the broad-based consumption tax reform proposals discussed above, all foreign-source income is exempt from tax. The conclusions of new economic studies by academic and public-sector tax policy experts that fundamental tax reform could raise rates of saving, investment, and output. As discussed earlier in this statement, a number of new academic and government studies conclude that switching to a consumption-based tax system would increase national saving, reduce the cost of capital, and lead to higher levels of capital formation and GDP. Conclusions Persistent low U.S. saving rates, despite recent good economic growth and low unemployment, suggest the need for short-term policy measures to reverse this pattern. In particular, we need to build on the recent progress in capital gains taxation, IRAs, pension and estate tax relief and the AMT. The restoration of an exclusion for dividends and interest received would also further the goal of lightening the taxation of saving. In addition, a substantial body of research suggests that fundamental tax reform and more reliance on consumption taxes could have a profound positive effect on long-term economic growth. Even small changes in economic growth rates can make a big difference in living standards. As the United States faces the economic challenges of the twenty-first century, fundamental tax reform that moves the U.S. tax system toward greater reliance on consumption taxes can be an important policy lever for achieving stronger economic growth and higher living standards. Endnotes 1. Alan J. Auerbach, David Altig, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Kent A. Smetters, and Jan Walliser, ``Simulating U.S. Tax Reform,'' NBER Working Paper No. 6248 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, October 1997). 2. Joint Committee on Taxation, Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, November 20, 1997. 3. Congressional Budget Office, The Economic Effects of Comprehensive Tax Reform, July 1997. 4. Eric M. Engen and Jonathan Skinner, ``Taxation and Economic Growth,'' NBER Working Paper No. 5826 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, November 1996). 5. Dale W. Jorgenson, ``The Economic Impact of Taxing Consumption,'' testimony before the Committee on Ways and Means of the U.S. House of Representatives, March 27, 1996. Joel L. Prakken, ``The Macroeconomics of Tax Reform,'' The Consumption Tax: A Better Alternative? (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1987). Lawrence H. Goulder, ``Deficit Reduction through Energy, Income, and Consumption Taxes: Impacts on Economic Growth and the Environment,'' Tax Policy for Economic Growth in the 1990s (Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research, March 1994). 6. Enterprise Economics and Tax Reform, Progressive Foundation, Progressive Policy Institute, Washington, D.C., October 1994. 7. The Impact of the U.S. Tax Code on the Competitiveness of Financial Service Firms, (Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research, July 1997). [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.129 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.130 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.131 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.132 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.133 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.134 Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Bloomfield. Our next witness is Stephen Entin. After you identify yourself, you may proceed. STATEMENT OF STEPHEN J. ENTIN, EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR AND CHIEF ECONOMIST, INSTITUTE FOR RESEARCH ON THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION Mr. Entin. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My name is Stephen J. Entin. I am executive director and chief economist of the Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation. Thank you for the opportunity to discuss the tax treatment of saving with you today. The issue has taken on an added importance as baby boomers approach retirement with inadequate savings and as the Social Security system totters toward insolvency. As the Committee is well aware, the income tax is heavily biased against saving. Income is taxed when first earned. If it is used for consumption, it is free of additional Federal income taxes. If it is saved, however, the returns on the saving are taxed again. This is the basic tax bias against saving. In addition, the corporate income tax and the Federal transfer tax compound the problem. Removing the basic bias and eliminating the added layers of tax should be a key goal of fundamental tax reform. I am glad to see, Mr. Chairman, that you are still very determined to proceed in that area. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1977 eased the basic income tax bias against saving somewhat by liberalizing the restrictions on deductible IRAs and adding the Roth and education IRAs. But more needs to be done. Two proposals, in particular, would improve the tax treatment of saving for low income or young households that have relatively few current assets. Senator Breaux and Representative McCrery have introduced the Individual Investment Account Act. The bill would permit taxpayers to defer taxes on saving without restrictions as to the amount of saving, the time of withdrawal, or the income level of the saver. All saving would be covered by the proposal, so all savers would receive incentives, at the margin, to save more. My colleagues and I at IRET are preparing a paper on the total overhaul of the tax system incorporating this approach. I would like to share the paper with the Committee when it is finished. Representatives Hulshof and Kucinich are preparing a bill that would exclude the first $200 to $400 in interest and dividends from taxable income for single and joint filers, respectively. The Joint Tax Committee estimates that, as of 1995, the exclusion would have covered all interest and dividend income on returns filed by more than 32 million households. Those returns involved more than 50 million taxpayers. At a 5-percent rate of interest or dividend, the exclusion would protect all the income from up to $4,000 or $8,000 in financial assets of individuals or married couples. Households with larger amounts of assets would receive no incentive, at the margin, to add to their savings. However, tens of millions of low income or young households have less than these levels of savings. These proposals are better than other saving incentive plans for low-income households because they have no strings attached--no tax penalty for withdrawal regardless of how long the saving has been held or the age of the taxpayer or the purpose of the withdrawal. By contrast, most saving provisions of the current law apply to retirement income and impose a penalty as well as a tax for most withdrawals before age 59\1/ 2\. People need some amount of savings they can tap into in an emergency such as unemployment or a medical problem. The rich can utilize provisions--the restrictive provisions such as IRAs and pensions and still have money to set aside for instant access. The working poor, however, are often unable to save for retirement in one account and for emergencies in another. Rather than risk a tax penalty, they put their savings in bank accounts that are fully subject to the income-tax bias against saving. Efforts to lock people into retirement savings have had the opposite effect of frightening low-income households away from retirement-saving plans. Consequently, their assets are overtaxed and build slowly. Therefore, many households never achieve the levels of precautionary savings that they need before they can set money aside for retirement. If low-income households could receive the same tax-deferred or tax-exempt treatment of saving available to our affluent citizens, without restrictions, they could more quickly build their rainy-day funds to acceptable levels and have more money to set aside for long-term investment. A complete rationalization of taxation of savings and investment, including elimination of the transfer tax and the double taxation of corporate and individual income, would probably require total restructuring of the tax system. Until then, small steps in the right direction would help individual households and the economy. Saving incentives must be part of the inevitable reform of Social Security. To ensure that the added saving is used to increase domestic business investment to boost U.S. productivity, wages, and employment, Congress should also enact faster writeoff of plant, equipment, and structures. Such steps are affordable. Their dynamic effect on the economy and on saving should ease budget concerns and should be counted. Projected budget surpluses should also ease the adoption of progrowth tax initiatives and, if necessary, the Budget Act should be revised. Promotion of a more productive economy is the best way to use projected budget surpluses to raise incomes for retirees and the rest of the Nation. Thank you. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Stephen J. Entin, Executive Director and Chief Economist, Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation The public and this Committee have long been concerned about the adequacy of saving in the United States, with regard to both the financial well-being of individuals and households and the health of the national economy. The subject takes on added importance as the baby boomers approach retirement with clearly inadequate financial resources. The tax treatment of saving affects the ability and willingness of people to save for emergencies, for education, homebuying, and retirement. The ordinary income tax is heavily biased against saving and in favor of consumption uses of income. Income is taxed when first earned. If it is used for consumption, it is free of additional federal income taxes. If it is saved, however, the returns on the saving are taxed again. This is the fundamental bias of the income tax against saving. In addition to this basic bias, the tax system piles on several additional layers of tax on income that is saved, in the form of the corporate income tax and the federal transfer (estate and gift) tax, compounding the problem.\1\ These multiple layers of tax on saving and capital increase the cost of saving, leading to a smaller stock of capital than would otherwise prevail. A smaller capital stock means lower labor productivity, real wages, employment, and income than could otherwise have been achieved. A neutral tax code would not penalize saving relative to consumption. There are two ways to make the taxation of saving and consumption neutral. Either income that is saved should be exempt from tax and the earnings of the saving and the principal taxed upon withdrawal, or the amounts saved should be taxed when earned but the earnings should be tax exempt. The saving-deferred approach is embodied in deductible IRAs and in 401(k), 403(b), Keough, and employer-sponsored retirement plans. The returns exempt approach is embodied in tax exempt securities and the recently enacted ``back-ended'' Roth IRA.\2\ The tax bill enacted in 1997 liberalized existing provisions that offset some of the tax bias against saving for retirement, and added several vehicles to encourage saving for education. Nonetheless, there is still much work to do to provide saving with the neutral tax treatment that would be most beneficial for taxpayers and the national economy.\3\ I should like to refer specifically today to two proposals that would improve the tax treatment of saving particularly for low income households and for young households who have relatively few current assets. Senator John Breaux (D-LA) and Representative Jim McCrery (R-LA) have introduced the Individual Investment Account Act in the 105th Congress as S. 330 and as H.R. 984. The bill would permit taxpayers to defer taxes on saving without restrictions as to amount of saving or time of withdrawal or income level of the saver. It would allow unlimited tax deduction of amounts saved, tax-free investment growth until withdrawal, no penalty tax on withdrawal at any age, and no forced distribution at any age. There would be no income tax at death; heirs could maintain the deferral of the saving until they chose to withdraw it. Representatives Kenny Hulshof (R-MO) and Dennis Kucinich (D-OH) are preparing to introduce a bill that would exclude the first $200 or $400 in interest and dividends from taxable income for single and joint filers, respectively. Figures provided to the sponsors by the Joint Tax Committee from the 1995 tax year indicate that 30 million tax returns reported interest and dividend income of less than $200. About 19 million joint returns reported interest and dividends income of less than $400. Altogether, the $200/$400 exclusion would cover all interest and dividend income on returns filed by more than 32 million households, covering more than 50 million taxpayers. About 67 million households (about 57 percent of all taxpayers) would receive partial or total relief from tax on their saving under the proposal. Assuming a 5% rate of interest or dividends, a $200 exclusion would protect all of the income from up to $4,000 in financial assets held by an individual, and up to $8,000 in financial assets held by a married couple. Many households have assets in excess of these levels, and would receive no incentive at the margin to add to their saving as a result of the exclusion. However, tens of millions of households have less than these levels of savings. They are concentrated among the lowest income households in the country. Both of these proposals for reducing the tax bias against saving have an important advantage over other saving plans for low income households. They are free of any tax penalty for withdrawals, regardless of how long the saving had been held, or the age of the taxpayer, or the purpose for the withdrawal. By contrast, most of the provisions in current law that protect a portion of saving from the biases in the income tax apply to retirement income, and impose a penalty as well as a tax for most early withdrawals. Unfortunately, people need ready access to some amount of savings in the event of an emergency, such as a spell of unemployment or a medical problem; the tax code now provides only a few, narrow exemptions to the early withdrawal penalty. The rich can save for retirement in pensions and IRAs, and still have plenty of income to set aside in ordinary saving for instant access. The working poor, however, are often unable to save for retirement in one account and for emergencies in another. They are afraid to risk the tax penalty for early withdrawal from retirement saving plans, and must put their saving in bank accounts and money market funds that are fully subject to the income tax bias against saving. By allowing maximum flexibility for the taxpayer/saver, the Breaux-McCrery and Hulshof provisions would be more useful and attractive to low income households, and would encourage them to do more saving, than existing tax provisions. The restrictions that encumber most saving incentives in current law are intended to increase long term saving, and, in particular, to prevent people from drawing down their saving before retirement age. It is unclear if the intent is to protect irresponsible people from themselves, lest they waste their retirement nest eggs, or to protect the federal government, which does not want to support destitute senior citizens on the dole. In either case, the idea seems to be that it is necessary to lock savers into their retirement plans to increase the amount of assets available to them in old age. Not only is this dim view of the intelligence of the population insulting and misguided, the tactic probably backfires. The efforts to force people to save for retirement have had the opposite effect of frightening low income households away from the retirement saving plans. Consequently, their assets build painfully slowly, and many never achieve the levels of precautionary savings they need before they can consider the luxury of setting money aside for retirement. If the saving of low income households received the same tax-deferred or tax exempt treatment available to retirement accounts of more affluent citizens, their assets would build faster, they would more quickly build their rainy day funds to acceptable levels, and they would have more money available to put into longer term saving vehicles, including retirement plans. If all saving were to receive the same neutral tax treatment, there would be more saving in total, less incentive to withdraw and spend down saving at all ages, and, consequently, more saving for retirement, than under current law. Most of the provisions in current law that protect a portion of saving from tax bias have to do with retirement saving. The bias in the income tax extends to all taxable saving, not just that for retirement. Consequently, to create a neutral tax system, all saving, whether for retirement, buying a house, college tuition, a new car, a vacation, or protection against a rainy day, should receive the same treatment as in a tax-deferred income plan. A complete rationalization of the taxes imposed on saving and investment will probably have to wait for a total restructuring of the tax system with one of three approaches: A saving-deferred tax for individuals. Allow savers to defer tax on all their net saving and tax all net withdrawals of non-reinvested returns on capital on individuals' tax forms, with no additional tax at the business level. (Example: an integrated cash-flow tax, such as a modification of the individual side of the (Nunn-Domenici) USA Tax.) A neutral business level tax. Allow businesses an immediate write-off of all investment outlays and tax all returns of capital on business tax returns, with no additional tax at the individual level. (Example: the Armey-Shelby Flat Tax.) A retail sales tax. Tax income when it is spent on final consumption goods and services. (Example: Tauzin-Shaefer.) Until such time as the country and the Congress are ready for a totally new tax system, small steps in the right direction would do a great deal to improve the performance of the economy and the well-being of individuals and families. Endnotes 1. After income has been earned and taxed, personal taxes on returns on non-corporate investments, such as interest, rents, and earnings of unincorporated businesses, constitute a second round of taxation--double taxation--of income that is saved. Similarly, personal saving invested in corporate ownership is subject to a second round of taxation--the corporate income tax on the corporate earnings on that saving. A third round of income tax--triple taxation--is imposed if the corporation distributes its after-tax income as dividends to individuals. If the corporation retains its after-tax earnings for reinvestment, the resulting increase in the share price constitutes a capital gain, also resulting in a third layer of tax on the retained earnings if the shares are sold. Capital gains may also occur when a business's earnings outlook improves for reasons other than reinvestment. A new product or patent, a rise in sales, anything that would lead to a jump in anticipated income (income that the business has not even received yet) may boost the current valuation of the shares or business. If the higher expected business earnings come to pass, they will be taxed as corporate income and/or personal business or dividend income. To tax the increase in the current value of the business, either upon sale, gift, or bequest, is to triple-tax the future income. If the saving outlives the saver, the federal unified transfer (estate and gift) tax may impose yet another layer of tax on the saving. In addition to the federal income and transfer taxes, state and local income, estate, and gift taxes impose multiple layers of tax on saving and its returns. There are property taxes as well. 2. A neutral tax code would raise revenue without distorting economic activity. The tax would do this by increasing the cost of all private sector activities equally. The income tax, because it is assessed on both income that is saved and the returns on that income, taxes saving and investment more heavily than consumption. Suppose that, in the absence of taxes, one could buy $100 of consumption goods or a $100 bond paying 4% interest, or $4 a year. Now impose a 20% income tax. One would now have to earn $125, and give up $25 in tax, to have $100 of after-tax income to consume. The cost of $100 of consumption in terms of pre-tax income has risen 25%. To get a $4 interest stream, after taxes, one would have to earn $5 in interest, pre-tax. To earn $5 in interest, one would have to buy a $125 bond. To buy a $125 bond, one would have to earn $156.25 and pay $31.25 in tax. The cost of the after-tax interest stream has gone up 56.25%, more than twice the increase in the cost of consumption. There are two general approaches to restoring neutrality. One is to exempt returns on capital from tax. One would then have to earn $125 to buy a $100 bond, earning $4 with no further tax. This is akin to the tax treatment accorded state and local bonds. The other method is to allow a deduction for income that is saved, while taxing the returns. One would have to earn $125 to buy a $125 bond, earning $5 in interest pre-tax; after paying $1 in tax on the interest, one would have $4 left. This is akin to the deductible IRA, or qualified 401(k) or company pension plans. 3. There are many shortcomings in the existing tax provisions. IRAs, 401(k) plans, and other deferred compensation plans that moderate the tax bias against saving, as currently constituted, have several shortcomings. In spite of the changes enacted in last year's tax bill, there are still limits on the amounts that can be deducted. IRAs give no added incentive to save to those who are already doing long-term saving in amounts above the limits. (Senator Ashcroft has proposed doubling the amounts that may be contributed to deductible IRAs, giving more savers incentive ``at the margin''.) Another drawback is that withdrawals from most plans before age 59\1/2\ are frequently subject to a penalty in addition to tax. This often makes these saving plans unattractive to lower income savers who cannot afford to save separately for emergencies and other near-term goals, as well as a more distant retirement. Commendably, the tax bill approved in 1997 waives the early-withdrawal penalty on IRA distributions used to buy a first home or to pay qualified higher- education expenses. Two other liberalizations in the 1997 legislation are also steps in the right direction, but they do not go far enough. The new Roth IRAs permit savers to deposit after-tax money into custodial accounts in which the earnings are tax free. But Roth IRAs also have income limits on participants (higher than the income thresholds for non-Roth IRAs), and limit the amounts that may be contributed. Further, assets must be held five years or more in Roth IRAs and the individual must have attained age 59 (or qualify for one of several exceptions) in order to make withdrawals without a tax penalty. The non-deductible education IRA in the same legislation also addresses the tax bias against saving but is subject to contribution and income limits and is only penalty free if used for eligible education outlays. Another problem is that there is a mandatory age (70\1/2\) for beginning to withdraw from non-Roth IRAs to force commencement of recapture of the tax deferral, yet the saving done by the elderly is as economically valuable as saving done by the young. Indeed, all saving contributes to capital formation, productivity, and national income, regardless of the motive behind it. There is no economic reason for the government to discriminate against or discourage any type of saving. Tax exempt bonds receive the same ``back-ended'' tax treatment as a Roth IRA. The saver gets no deduction, but the returns are not taxed. There is no holding period or tax penalty for early withdrawal to frighten away low income savers. However, tax exempt bonds offer a lower rate of return than ordinary bonds or stocks. The difference reflects the marginal tax rates of the upper income taxpayers who invest in the tax exempt securities. The issuing states, counties, and cities capture the tax advantage through the lower interest rate paid on such bonds, leaving the taxpayers only slightly better off than if they had invested in taxable securities. Because of their relatively low interest rates, these securities are not a good investment for taxpayers in low tax brackets. Chairman Archer. Thank you, Mr. Entin. Mr. Stevenson, you may proceed. STATEMENT OF WILLIAM STEVENSON, CHAIRMAN, FEDERAL TAXATION COMMITTEE, NATIONAL SOCIETY OF ACCOUNTANTS; AND PRESIDENT, NATIONAL TAX CONSULTANTS, INC. Mr. Stevenson. Thank you. My name is William Stevenson. I am representing the National Society of Accountants in which I am the Federal tax committee chairman. I am also president of National Tax Consultants Inc. in Merrick, New York. Good morning, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. We're really pleased to testify today on this issue of Federal tax burden, and when I'm finished everyone's going to think that you planted me here. The National Society of Accountants represents interests of over 30,000 practicing accountants who provide accounting, tax services, management advisory services to about 6 million small businesses and individuals. In the past 10 years, I personally prepared 5,000 tax returns, probably more. Our comments today are going to focus on one area, namely the complexity of the 18-month holding period for the new 10- and 20-percent capital gains rate. We're also going to demonstrate to you the problems this has caused many taxpayers including tax preparers like myself. The mind-boggling complexity in the new capital gains rate and the reporting of it really needs to be eliminated. In particular, the National Society endorses the elimination of the 18-month holding period and in its place, we recommend what Chairman Archer announced in his opening comments that a 20- percent gains rate should be effective for capital assets held for a year or more. And here's why--and incidentally, this is not theory. This is practicality as compared to some of the much broader issues that we have been discussing. In 1996, the Schedule D had 19 lines on it, and it had 3 pages of instructions with a little worksheet. This year, those 19 lines have grown to 54 lines and 4 pages of instructions. The complexity of the new capital gains laws are particularly burdensome for owners of mutual funds. Before 1997, taxpayers could report their mutual fund distributions directly on the 1040 and then bypass the Schedule D. In 1997, taxpayers must report the tiniest capital gains distribution on Schedule D, and, according to one national press report, the mutual fund trade industry estimates that the 1997 act's mandate regarding this change alone could affect 5 million of the 63 million investors in mutual funds. I really think that it is a lot more than that based on my own personal experience. One of the publications referred to the 1997 tax law as ``the tax-preparation industry full employment act,'' and I suppose I should thank you for it. But it is making me crazy, too. Each January, taxpayers owning mutual funds are inundated by their annual reports and Form 1099-Div--Div means Dividend-- and they get these from all their different mutual funds. Even tax-free funds often generate a statement containing capital gains. Deciphering the Form 1099-Div has always been difficult, but this year, for the average taxpayer and average investor, it is particularly incomprehensible, it is indecipherable. For the benefit of the Committee, we've submitted, as an attachment to our written statement, a real-life example. This is an actual client of mine. I have just taken one of his mutual funds that he held for 2 years--and in this example, I've pointed out to you the needless complexity of our new capital-gains laws. When you get a chance to look at the report, you will see that this taxpayer, Michael J.--I blanked out his last name and Social Security number--he just invested $39,000 in a mutual fund in March 1996. He added $20,000 over the last 2 years and made a couple of withdrawals, and in addition to that, we will assumed he sold it on December 15. In that scenario, I had to go through 15 steps, first to determine his holding period, his gain percentages, his gain and loss profit--all of this prior to reporting it on the Schedule D, and when you take a look at the D, you will think that he had 100 different transactions. This is just to report this. And the same complexity applies to an investor whether they had $1 million in the fund. Frankly, Congress has given us a law that is almost impossible to follow. We recognize that this also created a burden for the IRS. So much so that they couldn't even process electronically filed returns of Schedule D until today. What most people don't realize is that farmers and fishermen, they have to file their returns by March 2, so it is causing an enormous burden. So, I see my time is up. Providing your questions aren't too complex, I will be glad to respond to them at the end. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of William Stevenson, Chairman, Federal Taxation Committee, National Society of Accountants; and President, National Tax Consultants, Inc. The National Society of Accountants (NSA) is pleased to testify on the issue of reducing the federal tax burden. NSA commends Chairman Archer and the other members of the Committee on Ways and Means for holding this most important hearing on proposals designed to eliminate complexities or perceived inequities in the Internal Revenue Code. My name is William Stevenson, and I am testifying today in my capacity as Chairman of the National Society's Federal Taxation Committee. I have been an Enrolled Agent for many years and have served on the Commissioner of Internal Revenue's Advisory Group. I am president of National Tax Consultants, Inc., a firm that concentrates on taxpayer representation before the United States Tax Court, and also am president of Financial Services of Long Island, a mutifaceted tax preparation and accounting firm that services individuals and small businesses on Long Island, in Merrick, New York. NSA is an individual membership organization. Through our national organization and affiliates in 54 jurisdictions, we represent the interests of approximately 30,000 practicing accountants. Our members are for the most part either sole practitioners or partners in moderate-sized accounting firms who provide accounting, tax return preparation, representation before the Internal Revenue Service, tax planning, financial planning, and managerial advisory services to over six million individual and small business clients. The members of NSA are pledged to a strict code of professional ethics and rules of professional conduct. The National Society's comments today will focus on the complexity of the 18-month holding period for the new 10 and 20 percent capital gains rates, and proposals for an exclusion for interest and dividend income. Capital Gains The National Society strongly supports the proposition that a low capital gains rate is critical to spurring capital formation and prosperity for the American work force. However, the mind-boggling complexity in the new capital gains rates and reporting should be eliminated. In particular, NSA endorses elimination of the 18 month holding period involved with the new maximum 20 percent capital gains rate. Instead, we recommend that the top 20 percent capital gains rate become effective for capital assets held for one year or more. The technical impediments imbedded in the Internal Revenue Code create the complexity which makes it difficult for individual taxpayers to comply with the law and for the Internal Revenue Service to administer it. We believe the current 18 month holding period for capital gains, enacted as part of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, is an excellent example of needless complexity. According to IRS statistics, approximately 50 percent of all federal tax returns are prepared by tax professionals. The August 13, 1997 issue of Money Daily states the capital gains measure of the 1997 law is likely to spur even more individuals to take their tax reporting obligations to professionals for assistance. Indeed, one tax professional quoted by Money Daily called the 1997 law the ``Tax Preparation Industry Full Employment Act.'' The National Society of Accountants supports the reduction in the top capital gains rate to 20 percent. However, in order to qualify for the 20 percent rate under the 1997 tax law, an individual must now hold his or her capital asset for 18 months or longer. Assets held for more than a year, but for less than 18 months, will be taxed under the new tax act at a maximum capital gains rate of 28 percent. The Schedule D (Capital Gains and Losses) for the 1996 Form 1040 contained 19 lines on the schedule, accompanied by a 13 line worksheet in the instruction book. The instructions for the form were three pages. Due to the capital gains provisions of the 1997 tax act, the Schedule D for the 1997 individual tax return contains 54 lines. The instructions for the form have increased to four pages. Thy considers to be needless. The blame for such complexity can not be placed on the IRS. The agency was given a mandate, based on enactment of the 1997 Tax Act, to design a tax form to provide accounting for at least six capital gains tax brackets for 1997. The 54 line Schedule D and the four pages of instructions were the necessary result. And the complexity of the Schedule D will only get worse by the year 2000 when the IRS will be faced with designing a form which accounts for nine tax brackets. The complexity of the new capital gains law will be particularly burdensome for owners of mutual funds. Before calendar year 1997, a taxpayer who had only taxable capital gains distributions from mutual funds was permitted to report those distributions directly on the Form 1040 and was not required to file Schedule D. This now will be different. For 1997, taxpayers must report all capital gains, including mutual fund distributions, on Schedule D. According to one national press report, the mutual fund trade industry estimates that the 1997 tax act's mandate regarding this change alone could affect 5 million of the approximately 63 million Americans who own mutual funds. Each January, taxpayers owning mutual funds are inundated by annual reports and Forms 1099-DIV from their mutual fund companies. Taxpayers are bewildered by the statements and often do not read the tax reporting instructions enclosed with them. The Form 1099-DIV reports the amount of long-term capital gains distributions and short-term capital gains distributions made to taxpayers. However, the short-term capital gains are lumped together with dividends on the Form 1099-DIV as one figure. No wonder taxpayers are confused. As indicated, deciphering a Form 1099-DIV has been a difficult task for the average taxpayer. For 1997 tax returns these forms are likely not only to be indecipherable, but incomprehensible to mainstream Americans. For the benefit of the House Ways and Means Committee, we have attached an example of mutual fund capital gains reporting to illustrate the needless complexity in the new capital gains law. In March, 1996, taxpayer ``Michael J.'' invested $39,000 in a mutual fund. During the two years he held the fund, he invested an additional $20,000, had two small liquidations of $1,500 and $4,000, and reinvested quarterly dividends. For purposes of illustration, we will assume he sold his entire investment December 15, 1997. It sounds simple, but this scenario requires 15 different steps to determine holding periods, gain percentage categories, and gain or loss in order to report the transactions on Schedule D. Reporting capital gains this year requires multiple steps; the average taxpayer who merely types mutual fund purchase and sale dates into a tax software program may not have an accurate result on the tax return. Capital Gains and Farm Returns The National Society of Accountants believes the complexity of the calculations for 1997 capital gains has created a burden for the IRS which impacts adversely on individual taxpayers. At the same time the IRS is trying to encourage more taxpayers and tax practitioners to use electronic filing, it has announced it may have problems processing electronically filed returns containing Schedule D. Taxpayers and tax practitioners who have made a commitment to convert to electronic filing now are being told by IRS that they may not be able to transmit their returns electronically. The complexity in the tax law is causing cascading problems at the IRS with respect to return processing and electronic filing. As we stated before, the blame for this cannot be placed on the IRS. Some issues related to capital gains in the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 were not resolved unchnical Corrections Bill. With the resolution of the issues, the IRS was able to finalize the Schedule D and to begin modifying its return processing software. The time required to implement the programming means that the IRS will not be able to process any returns with Schedule D until mid-February 1998. A taxpayer who files a paper return with a Schedule D before mid-February may experience a delay in the processing of his or her return. However, a taxpayer who files an electronic return containing Schedule D may not even transmit it until February 12, because IRS computers cannot accept it until then. While the IRS estimates that only two percent of taxpayers who report capital gains or losses will be affected by this processing issue, farmers, fishermen and practitioners who prepare their returns may experience particular difficulties. Farmers and fishermen must file their returns and pay their taxes by March 2 or be subject to estimated tax penalties. Yet those taxpayers cannot even transmit their electronic returns until February 12. Once the electronic pipeline is open, practitioners will have a very short span of time to correct errors in rejected returns. Electronic transmission is not flawless, and often returns fail to transmit for various reasons. Practitioners working the rejected returns must correct errors, contact clients to verify information, and retransmit the return. Practitioners who transmit large numbers of electronic farm returns containing Schedule D could be facing extremely heavy workloads related to reworking those rejected returns at the height of their busiest season. The National Society of Accountants applauds the IRS for recognizing this problem and agreeing not to impose the estimated tax penalty on any farmer or fisherman whose electronic return is filed and accepted by March 9, 1998, which reflects a one week extension. The IRS has every reason to demonstrate its flexibility to practitioners enrolled in its e- file program. To reach the goal of 80% of returns to be filed electronically by 2007, as stated in the restructuring legislation, the Service needs the enrollment of large number of practitioners in its electronic filing program. ``Glitches'' such as the capital gains processing delay are disincentives for tax professionals to embrace the electronic filing program. Practitioners who make the commitment to invest time, money and staff training to convert to the electronic filing program do not want to switch gears in the middle of their busiest season and revert to filing paper returns because IRS computers cannot accept electronic transmissions. The National Society of Accountants recommends that Congress reduce the complexity in tax law, especially capital gains reporting, before serious damage is done to beneficial IRS programs, such as the electronic filing program. Exclusion for Interest and Dividend Income. Before the Tax Reform Act of 1986, the Internal Revenue Code provided for a modest exclusion for interest and dividend income. This exclusion was revoked by the 1986 Tax Act. The National Society of Accountants recommends restoration of the exclusion. While the stated objective by Congress for its previous elimination of the provision in 1986 was to simplify the tax law, our members never viewed the previous interest and dividend exclusion as being a complex measure. NSA members welcome a vigorous debate by Congress over the issue of whether restoration of the exclusion has positive capital formation benefits for the U.S. economy. Conclusion The National Society of Accountants is pleased to provide these comments on reducing taxpayer burden. I hope that the Society's insights have been helpful today and, on behalf of all of the members, I thank you for your interest. I hope you will feel free to contact NSA at any time for assistance with any additional information you might need. Attachment On March 19, 1996, ``Michael J.'' invested $39,000 in the Franklin Rising Dividend Fund. During each of the two years he held the fund, he invested an additional $10,000. In 1996, he had two small liquidations of $1,500 and $4,000. We will assume that he sold his entire position on December 15, 1997. In order for him to prepare an accurate Schedule D, he must identify each investment including the reinvested dividends and determine which of the three holding periods applies to each one (12 months or less; more than 12 months but less than 18 months; over 18 months). ------------------------------------------------------------------------ ITEM ------------------------------------------------------------------------ 1.............................. The initial investment was purchased on March 19, 1996 and was held for over 18 months. The number of shares sold during that year should be subtracted from the original amount purchased. The remaining shares fall into the 20% category. 2.............................. The reinvested dividend was made on June 3, 1996. It was held for over 18 months and falls into the 20% category. 3.............................. A second investment of $10,000 was made on June 20, 1996. Since it was sold on December 15, 1997, it falls into the 28% category since it was held for more than 12 months but less than 18 months. 4.............................. The reinvested dividend was made on September 3, 1996. It was held for less than 12 months and falls into the 28% category. 7 & 8.......................... The reinvested dividends and capital gains were made on December 2, 1996. These amounts are in the 28% category. 9, 11, 12 & 13................. The quarterly reinvested dividends were all made in 1997 and sold in 1997. Therefore, they are short term capital gains and taxed at ordinary income tax rates. 10............................. The new investment of $10,000, made on March 10, 1997, will be taxed at ordinary income tax rates. 14............................. The Fund's capital gain earnings has been identified on Form 1099-DIV as simply Capital Gain Distribution. On the actual statement it shows up as a Long Term Capital Gain (LT Cap Gain). Therefore, we will presume it to fall in the 20% category. However, in most cases, this amount will be divided into the middle and long-term groups based on a percentage provided by the mutual fund. 15............................. The Fund's other earnings or dividends will be taxed at the ordinary income tax rates. 14............................. The funds from the capital gain distribution of $8,168.84 were applied to ``Michael J.'s'' account on December 1 and sold on December 15. Therefore, the amount falls into the short-term category. 15............................. The short-term capital gain distribution which was applied to ``Michael J.'s'' account on December 1 will also fall into the short-term gain category. ------------------------------------------------------------------------ Now that each transaction has been identified, the taxpayer can begin to complete Schedule D. Once each transaction has been placed into its proper category, the next step is to determine the loss or gain for each item. If we assume that the liquidation price of the fund on December 15 was $25.25, then the calculation for the Schedule D would show a gain on every transaction with the exception of item 12. These transactions require 13 different entries on Schedule D, and for each entry, calculations to determine the proportion of sales price allocated to the entry. A review of the attached documents shows this to be an actual case. It is also a very simple and common example. Imagine the difficulty of tax reporting for a taxpayer who has several mutual fund holdings and transfers funds between them at varying times during the year. Some funds attempt to be helpful by providing the investor with figures that can be directly entered onto a tax return, but an experienced tax professional knows these entries are not always correct. Also, many taxpayers have funds from different organizations, and each mutual fund company has its own style of reporting transactions. It is easy to see why capital gains reporting is very complex and confusing to taxpayers. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.135 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.136 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.137 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.138 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.139 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.140 Chairman Archer. Mr. Stevenson, the questions are never complex, but the results and the law create complexities often that are unintended. I appreciate your input particularly because, as I mentioned, I am now beginning to prepare my return for this year, and it is not a very happy prospect. Other than the reduction of the 18-month holding period to 12 months, what other areas of simplification might we consider in the capital gains area alone? Mr. Stevenson. Well, one of the things that is kind of a corollary to it are the small amounts of foreign tax that is withheld. You will have a taxpayer that will have a mutual fund, and there will be a distribution--an index distribution because there is some foreign-owned stock. That will throw up a $5 or $15 foreign tax credit, and in that we have to prepare a Form 1116 which is a very complicated calculation just to get this guy back his $5 to a foreign country. You might want to take a look at that. It is somewhat of a nuisance. It is not too bad for us who prepare tax returns on a computer, but for the people who do it manually it is---- Chairman Archer. Do you have a suggestion for the Committee as to how we might change that? Mr. Stevenson. Yes, just give--just say that if the foreign-tax credit is under $50 just make it a credit--an automatic credit without all kinds of complications. I just used $50, make it $25 or whatever number it is. You don't really need that---- Chairman Archer. Any other suggestions? In any event, if you and your organization have got suggestions that you would like to submit to us in writing, we would be most happy to receive them. Mr. Stevenson. Well, I feel like a mosquito in a nudist colony because I don't know where to begin when you ask a question like that. I mean there are so many things that we do, and we'll be prepared to submit something---- Chairman Archer. Once you get into the entire Code it gets to be massive, but just in the capital gains area alone, try to find the best possible ways to simplify it. Will we be able to handle the 18-percent rate with a 5-year holding period without any great difficulty in the next century? Is that going to pose the same sort of difficulties that we have today? Mr. Stevenson. Congressman, I suspect that if there are no changes in the law that there will be very few correctly calculated Schedule D tax returns either done by preparers or by taxpayers. As far as the holding period, I think you are going to find that also difficult to monitor because people just don't save their records that long of a time. I mean the law says you only have to keep them for 3 years unless you feel that you fraudulently prepared your tax return, and now you are going to require people to hold onto their records for a much longer period of time. Chairman Archer. So, if we correct the holding period from 18 months to 1 year for the 20-percent rate, we leave in the law the 18-percent rate for the 5-year holding period beginning in the year 2001. Clearly the 18-percent rate is a very attractive thing because it reduces the tax by 10 percent if you have held an asset for 5 years. On behalf of savings, that is very attractive. Mr. Stevenson. Yes, but what you don't realize is that that 20 percent, 18-percent rate, that can turn out to be a bogus rate particularly if there is a significantly large capital gain that throws off a State tax. That State tax, which could be large, throws a taxpayer into the alternative minimum tax situation and the capital--I mean I have a calculation where I can show you that it is 21 percent. So, when Congress tells the public that ``your rate is such--well, we're doing this for you, and your rate is 20 percent and 18 percent,'' when you get down to do the tax returns, it is really not that rate, quite often. Chairman Archer. But is that the result of reducing the rate to 18 percent with a 5-year holding period? Or would that problem exist relative to the 20-percent rate? Mr. Stevenson. No, it's a failure to see the relationship between the alternative minimum tax and how the tax return is calculated on a much broader scale. Chairman Archer. But that would apply also to the 20- percent tax, would it not? Mr. Stevenson. That is correct---- Chairman Archer. OK. Mr. Stevenson [continuing]. Yes. I have somebody in my office and we just did her return, and she wound up with at 21- percent rate. Chairman Archer. Well, in my opinion, the alternative minimum tax has outlived its usefulness and should be repealed. We should be very careful that the provisions in the Code make sense. And once we decide they do make sense, if people can take advantage of them, they should be able to take advantage of them and not have a ``snapback'' in some broad, unintended way hit them through the alternative minimum tax. Mr. Stevenson. Well, you will have a huge--if you don't do something about the alternative minimum tax next year, when the middle class starts looking for all their credits, there is going to be a human cry across this country that will make Congress quite uncomfortable because a lot of people will not get these credits because the AMT only allows you to take credits up to the amount of the AMT tax. You can't go below that. The same thing is true of low-income housing credits. Chairman Archer. It's not been stated today, but it should be stated, as a part of this hearing, that if we do reduce the holding period for the 20-percent rate from 18 months to 1 year, it actually raises revenue over the 5-year period during which we budget here in the House of Representatives. So, it is not a revenue loser, and that makes it even more attractive for the Committee. Does any other Member wish to inquire? Mrs. Johnson and then Mr. McCrery. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Thank you. Your testimony has been very interesting and very helpful. I would like any of you who have the time to look at the SAVE bill that I put in about a year ago with Earl Pomeroy with the intent of helping small businesses provide a defined benefit option to their employees. This Committee passed what we called SIMPLE--it didn't turn out to be quite so simple--but any suggestions you would have to simplify this SIMPLE plan now that we have some experience or your comments on the SAVE bill, we will be looking at that in the Subcommittee later on as well as some of these other options. And then, last, let me just say, the Hulshof bill is very interesting because it just rewards savings. The Tax Code on the whole rewards savings for specific purposes, retirement, home buying, what ever. And I'm just wondering where you stand on that. Should we have pursued targeted approaches to incentivizing savings on the theory that there was a far greater urgency to help people save for retirement and that home buying has an inherent, structural benefit for society than we have across-the-board savings. Would you comment on where you think we ought to go--particularly in light of the fact that we just passed the Roth IRA and some of those things. Should we hold, see how those are going to do? What is your advice on this targeted versus general savings incentives where we are now? Mr. Entin. I mentioned in my statement that a provision with no strings is better than a provision with strings. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. I noticed that. Mr. Entin. The retirement-saving restrictions tend to chase people away from retirement-saving plans. Any time you try to micromanage the public you are going to have a lot of trouble, because you don't know what their circumstances are, and they react to what you do. Across the board is always better. All saving should receive some sort of relief, either front-end or back-end, deductible or Roth-style, and not just saving for retirement, because all saving is subject to the tax bias. The income tax is biased against saving. It is not neutral as between saving and consumption. So, when you provide pension-type treatment, you are eliminating a bias. You are not giving a favor. And, of course, if having a bias is bad for one form of saving, it is also bad for any other, and it should be removed. There are really two sides to the situation. You want to encourage saving--or not discourage saving as under current law. But there is also the treatment of investment in plant and equipment. To get a double whammy from your saving incentives, you really need to see an improvement in the creation of plant and equipment in the country for labor to work with, so labor may become more productive and get higher wages. If people add to their saving as a result of incentives, they put it into the global saving pool, and who knows where it will ultimately end up triggering more investment in plant and equipment--it could be here, it could be in China, it could be in France. Wherever the saving goes, it is good for the saver. The saver will have more retirement income, and will be earning money from the return on the capital that he helped to create, and he will be able to buy more goods and services in his old age. But if you would also like to see U.S. workers getting the benefit of the higher saving rate, and see more plant and equipment in the United States, and boost U.S. wages so that people are benefiting when they are young as well as when they are old from their saving and that of their neighbors, then you need to do something to improve the tax treatment of U.S. domestic investment. We need expensing, not depreciation of plant, equipment, and structures. All of the fundamental tax- reform plans, in effect, move us from depreciation to expensing. That is true for a saving-deferred tax that falls on individuals and does not put an added layer of tax at the business level, or for an Armey-style plan which allows for expensing, or for a national retail sales tax which does not fall on investment goods. They are all a distinct improvement, and they give you the double whammy of higher wages as well as higher assets for retirement. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Thank you. Mr. Bloomfield. Mrs. Johnson, we took note of the SIMPLE plan in our testimony, I would be pleased to go back to some of our members---- Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Thank you. Mr. Bloomfield [continuing]. And see how it operates in person. The second question about moving forward incrementally, strings attached, no strings attached, retirement savings versus education savings--my sense is that these incremental changes, by and large, are good. Some may be better than others, but I think that you are a heck of a lot better moving toward a consumption tax where you don't differentiate. Third, Chairman Archer, again I would like to commend you for your initiative today to reduce the holding period and comment more on its economic impact than its simplification impact. CBO, in a 1997 report, indicated that now about one- half of all U.S. families hold assets such as stocks, bonds, real estate and businesses that might produce capital gains or losses. And that proportion ranges to three-quarters of families if homes are included. Since this is a problem for a lot of Americans, I think your step will be helpful. In an economic sense, if you look at a survey of industrialized countries and Pacific rim countries and what their holding periods are, you see that only one country, Sweden, has a holding period longer than a year. And obviously, with a longer holder period, there is more risk, it increases the cost of capital, and you don't get the economic bang, that the Committee, I think, thought it would get when you heard expert witnesses like Alan Sinai who testified about the economic benefits of capital gains tax cuts. The benefits are reduced because of the holding period, and we would be a heck of a lot more competitive according to this chart with a shorter holding period. Mr. Stevenson. May I respond for a second? Chairman Archer. Yes, sir. Mr. Stevenson. I'd like to suggest that Congress consider eliminating the 10-percent penalty for early withdrawal. I think that is one of the cruelest taxes. It does not prevent anybody from taking money out of their retirement, because by the time they do that they are desperate, and they have to give away 10 percent of the money that they take out. I think that that would also encourage some more younger people to make an investment in their retirement plan. Whether or not they keep it all the way to retirement, they will be saving it without fear of having to be penalized 10 percent if they have to take it out for emergencies. Chairman Archer. Thank you. By the way, Mr. Stevenson, I have just refreshed my memory, and in the bill that we passed last year under the simplification section we provided for a $300 exclusion for the foreign-tax credit limitation. And it does not take effect until this year. It had a prospective effective date. But I guess we heard you in some way through ESP last year and put it into the Code in our 1997 Tax Relief Act. On the issue of savings--and on the issue of simplification for the Code, would you or would you not agree with me that in today's parlance that whenever we hear the targeted--the word ``targeting,'' or ``targeted'' tax relief used that it is a code word for complications in the Code. Would you or would you not agree with that? Mr. Stevenson. Yes, it creates another category that you have to deal with separately. Chairman Archer. Because we're hearing that a great deal out of the White House now. It is fascinating, too, that Secretaries of the Treasury under both the Republican administrations and Democratic administrations have been enamored with staggered holding periods. I have always been very concerned about it, and you have given us some very good input today as to why my concerns were with some degree of support. Mr. McCrery. Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First I want to thank Mr. Entin and Mr. Bloomfield for their kind references to H.R. 984. And I want to talk about that in just a minute. First, though, Mr. Bloomfield, in your testimony, you urge the Committee to weigh carefully the President's proposals to make sure that we minimize their effect on investment. But you have that little phrase labeled as a step backward. Could I take that to mean that you don't favor most of the President's proposals for revenue raisers? Mr. Bloomfield. Well, as you know, there is a long list in the old parlance ``to raise revenue you go after cats and dogs.'' Now they are going after puppies and kids of puppies. So, some of those things are so minuscule and beyond my comprehension. But there are some issues that are raised today, like annuities, like inside buildup. The headline of the New York Times---- Mr. McCrery. Those are not puppies, are they? Mr. Bloomfield. Those are not puppies. After the President's budget came out, there was a headline, I think in the New York Times, that said, ``Administration Sends Mixed Signals on Savings and Investments.'' So, when I'm talking about steps backward, I'm saying that there may be things in there because there are so many of them, but I would look very carefully at all of them and look at the fundamental question of what is their impact on savings and investments. It is clear that some of the ``puppies'' could severely impact negatively on savings and investments. Mr. McCrery. I was also interested in, Mr. Bloomfield, your admonition that we make sure that anything that we do with respect to tax reform is done in a fiscally responsible way. I suppose by that that you mean let's not create another large deficit in fiscal terms. And it is in that context that I want to examine, for a moment, H.R. 984 because the primary criticism that we hear about H.R. 984 is, ``Oh gosh, it will just cost billions and billions of dollars.'' And I'm a little stumped by that analysis because take H.R. 984 and strip all the fancy words and basically what you have is an unlimited savings account, and anything that you put in the savings account you don't get taxed on, but when you pull it out you get taxed on it. Well, obviously, if you pull money out of a savings account, you do it because you are going to buy something, you are going to consume. Then you get taxed. Explain to me how that is different from a national sales tax. I don't think that it is any different, but if I am right, and it is not any different, then why can we rationalize a national sales tax, in terms of its fiscal responsibility and not an unlimited savings account? Mr. Bloomfield. Let me, if I could, respond in two ways. First, I would make a difference--distinguish between progrowth tax measures and general tax relief. I agree with the Chairman that our tax levels may be too high. He's talked about a long-term goal about reducing tax receipts as a percentage of GNP, and I also understand the pressures that people are under. But there is a difference, a fundamental difference in terms of long-term economic growth between those two different tax measures. And so let's put that, and let's put Mr. Hulshof's and others in one category, and other measures in another. The second question addresses fundamental tax reform. Obviously your proposal is basically a consumption or consumed income tax. There are three generic types of tax reform proposals. There is the Hall-Rabushka plan and the Armey proposal, which is a flat tax. There is the retail sales tax, and the value-added tax. There's the unlimited IRA, which you proposed. In many ways those proposals are more similar than dissimilar because they only tax savings once. As Mr. Entin pointed out, we're exempting investment from the tax. And I would refer you to our testimony where we discuss the views of some of the best economists in the country, the Joint Committee work, Jane Gravelle, you know who testifies before this Committee on many occasions, on the impact of tax policy on economic growth. If you look at table 3, at the long-run effect of a consumption tax--which is one of the three generic ones--versus a unified income tax, you will see that the economy is a heck of a lot better off under a consumption tax. So, if you are concerned about Federal revenue, obviously, if you have a stronger economy you are better off in the long term. When you do revenue estimating, you don't look at the macroeconomic impact, and that is a decision, obviously, that the Congress has to make. Mr. McCrery. Mr. Entin, would you like to comment on my question? Mr. Entin. We are preparing a total tax overhaul paper that incorporates your approach, which I will share with you as soon as it is available. It is one of the three approaches that does get to the same tax base. You must look at the growth consequences of it to get a good feel for what it would do, what it would cost, and what the rate structure would have to be. If you use static revenue estimation, it all looks much harder to do than it really is. As a result, all of the hundreds of billions of dollars of additional income for the population is lost because of the fear of proceeding. I hope you can cut through that Gordian knot and proceed anyway. While you are tearing out the income tax by the roots and doing these major overhauls, you may find you will have to tear out many of the provisions of the Budget Act by the roots in order to get a fair hearing. I would certainly support you in that activity. Mr. McCrery. Mr. Chairman, I didn't get a satisfactory answer, really. If I could pursue it for just a moment. I appreciate everything that both of you said, and I agree with you, but just from a common sense standpoint, if you institute a national sales tax at 17 percent that is supposed to equal the revenues in the current system, I don't understand what is different about that and my proposal which, if you impose a flat rate of 17 percent on anything consumed, anything not saved, what is the difference in terms of revenue to the government? Mr. Entin. The sales tax is a substitute for the individual income tax, the corporate income tax and, one would also hope, the transfer tax (the estate and gift tax). If the universal IRA proposal is passed as a substitute for all three, then a rate structure similar to the sales tax should yield you the same revenue. If you simply add it on to the current personal income tax and leave the corporate tax the way it is and the estate tax where it is, and then don't adjust the income tax rates, you would get a different result. But if you make it do the whole job, then both of those taxes are, in effect, consumed-income taxes. They would have the same tax base and you would get the same revenue for the same rate structure. Mr. McCrery. Right. So, Mr. Chairman, my point is I think we can look at this concept that's embodied in H.R. 984 as an alternative to creating a new bureaucracy to collect a national sales tax or a value-added tax. It's the same effect. It's a consumption tax. It's just, to me, it seems like it would be easier to convert--and easier to sell, frankly, to the American public--than a national sales tax or something like that. That's the only point that I'm making. Mr. Bloomfield. Mr. McCrery, conceptually, in terms of the economic impact, they're the same, so I would encourage you to join the road show of Mr. Armey and Mr. Tauzin. Mr. McCrery. I would be glad to. Mr. Bloomfield. What is at issue here, though, is when you're talking about fundamental reform, what is that reform? As you know, there is one sales tax proposal--the 23 percent-- which not only replaces the individual and corporate taxes, it also replaces Social Security, estate and gift taxes. Some of these tax reform proposals deal with Social Security; the Nunn- Domenici proposal does. Others do not. So, the rate structure-- that's one of the questions--depends on what you're replacing with what. Mr. McCrery. Absolutely. My only point is I think this approach is worth looking at in terms equal to the sales or VAT approach and the flat tax approach. Chairman Archer. I would just jump in and say the Chair welcomes all types of alternatives for consideration that will get us to the same desired goal, and the Nunn-Domenici approach gets us basically to most of the goals. But the attributes of Nunn-Domenici, and I believe from your proposal as I understand it, leave the IRS in everybody's life. Every individual still has to file a return, and the IRS still survives, exists, and is alive and well. And that is a big, big difference from the standpoint of freedom and privacy and what value people might attach to that. In addition, the Nunn-Domenici and the Armey and your proposal, as I understand them, will not get at the underground economy because they're not going to file an income tax with the IRS. As a result, the underground economy continues to flourish without paying their fair share of the cost to government. That is another difference, and I think an important goal. I don't think that your proposal, or Nunn-Domenici, would qualify for border adjustability and all of the advantage that would give us in reducing the price of our exports and seeing more factories built in this country for export. So, the goals of greater savings are there; the goals of simplification are there, although Nunn-Domenici has significant complexities in it also. Investment incentives, and so forth, are there, so I congratulate you on that part of it. Mr. McCrery. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. You and I certainly don't want to do a road show right here, but I would say to the Chairman that there are problems with an underground--a so- called underground--economy with the national sales tax, as well. In fact, most economists will tell you there's very little difference in the impact to revenues between the two, so I don't think that's a particular obstacle. Chairman Archer. Sure, there are problems with leakage in any tax system. Mr. McCrery. Absolutely. Chairman Archer. Any tax system is going to have leakage. The question is, What kind of leakage and how is it perceived by the public and how willing is the public to be to accept it? The fact that drug dealers can escape is abhorrent to the public, and the public understands that drug dealers will, when they buy the expensive items in the marketplace--if you have a spending sales tax, will pay. Mr. McCrery. We're going to follow the Speaker's lead, though, and get rid of those drug dealers over the next few years, so we don't have to worry about them buying Cadillacs anymore. Chairman Archer. Well, let's hope so. Mr. Watkins. Mr. Watkins. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Members of the Committee, and the panel. We all know we're truly in a global competitive economy, and I guess one of the great interests I have sitting on this Committee is, I think we must analyze the entire tax policy and how it affects our economy and allows us to be able to compete in that competitive, global economy. Mr. Bloomfield, you discussed the time periods regarding selling, capital gains, for taxes and all. I know we must increase our savings. We know we have the lowest percentage of savings of any industrialized country in the world. I might add I'm personally not worried about what's happening for my future, but I'm worried about the future of my children and my grandchildren, and the children and grandchildren of all the people here. We've got to, in my opinion, shape and mold our tax policy to let us have at least a fair and competitive--and maybe even an advantage--tax policy, instead of being a hindrance and detrimental. I know some countries do not even have a corporate capital gains tax. Now we, I think, moved in the right direction by lowering the capital gains tax for individuals. But it seems to me it would make good, sound policy for us to be able to compete in that global economy to lower or drop, as much as we can, the corporate capital gains tax, like we have with the individual rates. Now, I've got a couple of questions. Mr. Bloomfield, could you provide, possibly, to me and maybe the panel, the countries that do not have a corporate capital gains tax? And also, I know it makes economic sense, but do you feel like this would be good, something that is very much needed as far tax policy to let us compete in this 21st century? Mr. Bloomfield. Mr. Watkins, I will submit that for the record, but I would like to, while I'm here, also respond to your question. [The following was subsequently received:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.141 Mr. Bloomfield. It makes no sense to differentiate between individual and corporate capital gains rates for several reasons. First, there is precedent. We've always had an alternative capital gains tax rate in the Code from 1942 until the Tax Reform Act of 1986. Number two, we tax corporate capital gains much more harshly than do all our competitors. We have a survey that I will submit that shows that 14 out 16 countries tax corporate capital gains more favorably than the United States. [The information follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.142 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.143 Mr. Bloomfield. Third, there's the efficiency of capital markets. Capital is less mobile and you lose economic efficiency because of the lock-in at the high rates that you have with the corporate rate now at 35, as opposed to the lower rate we have for individuals. Fourth, the structure of U.S. business: The current imbalance between individual and corporate capital gains rates heightens inequities already inherent in what Mr. Entin talked about--the double taxation of current profits--and you have excessive tax planning that may accentuate a movement away from the traditional corporate form of organizations. Fifth, corporations provide a heck of a lot of venture capital, as well as spinning off and funding their own venture. So, if you're talking about the economic case for low capital gains taxes--the impact on capital costs, capital mobility, entrepreneurship--it makes absolutely no sense to differentiate between individual and corporate capital gains if low capital gains tax rates make economic sense. Mr. Watkins. It sounds like you were loaded for my question. [Laughter.] Mr. Bloomfield. I try to be prepared. Mr. Watkins. I just am concerned about making sure we do not overburden, or that we have an overburden in some cases, especially in a lot of our startup, entrepreneur-type companies, with other corporations around the world. In fact, 96 percent of the consumers of the world live outside of the United States. That's one heck of a big market, and as businessmen tell me, ``I want to be able to be in that market, and I want to be out there trying to penetrate that market, and I don't want to be overburdened with regulations and with taxes and with other things.'' And, I think this is something we've got to do if we're going to be allowing our children and grandchildren to be competitive in this world. Mr. Entin, would you like to add to that? Mr. Entin. I would add two points. Corporations are owned by people. It's wrong to tax capital gains received by shareholders directly from a corporation; it's also wrong to tax capital gains that one corporation receives from another corporation. That receiving corporation is owned by shareholders. It's the shareholders' money, and if it's wrong to tax it when they receive it, it's wrong to tax it in mid- stream as well. Taxation of capital gains is double taxation wherever you find it. As for the competitiveness of U.S. companies abroad, it's not just the taxation of capital gains at the corporate level that does the damage. Our whole structure of international taxation, of tax treatment of multinational corporations, puts our firms at a competitive disadvantage in third countries--in foreign countries--vis-a-vis other corporations from third countries. What you really need to do is totally restructure that whole treatment of U.S. corporations that earn income abroad, and go from a global treatment of foreign source income to a territorial system. Mr. Watkins. Can you give me the facts on that? Mr. Entin. Yes. Mr. Watkins. I'd like to have the materials and information in my office. Mr. Entin. We really should not be trying to reach globally to tax our people on incomes they earn in other countries, when other countries are taxing that income. A territorial tax would be a heck of a lot simpler and make our firms a lot more competitive abroad. Mr. Watkins. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Archer. Thank you. Any further questions of the panelists? All right, thank you very much, and we'll have our next panel, please. Dean Kleckner, president of the American Farm Bureau Federation; David A. Hartman, chairman of the Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation; Thomas Kelly, president of the Savers & Investors League. Thank you. Mr. Kleckner. STATEMENT OF DEAN KLECKNER, PRESIDENT, AMERICAN FARM BUREAU FEDERATION Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am Dean Kleckner. I am a farmer from north Iowa, raising corn, soybeans, and hogs. I'm also the elected president of the American Farm Bureau Federation, which is not only the country's, but the world's, largest farmer organization. Our members grow everything commercially that's grown in the United States. I commend this Committee for calling this hearing. I'm here today to speak in just two areas--although you've covered a lot already--the FARRM Accounts and capital gains tax relief. FARRM is spelled F-A-R-R-M, Farm and Ranch Risk Management Accounts. We support the creation of those to allow farmers and ranchers to manage business risks better through savings. FARRM Account legislation will soon be introduced, and I just received a copy of the bill this morning by Representative Hulshof, who is here, and Congresswoman Thurman. Under the bill, farmers and ranchers would be allowed to put up to 20 percent of their net farm income--pretax--into a special savings account. Money could remain in the account for no more than 5 years, and then whenever it came out it would be taxed at the going rate. Last month Congressman Hulshof traveled to the American Farm Bureau annual meeting to speak to farmers and ranchers from around the country about this--and let me tell all of you, he was enthusiastically received. Let me explain why the idea of a pretax savings account for farm income is so popular. Like other small business people, farmers and ranchers have predictable expenses. I'm one; I know. Each month we must pay for fuel, animal feed, repairs, maintenance, insurance, utilities, and meet a payroll. And in addition, we plan for seasonal expenses like taxes, seed, heat, and fertilizer, and then budget for major purchases, often done yearly or even less than that, like equipment, land, and buildings. While many expenses can be predicted and to some degree controlled, farm income is neither predictable nor controllable. The prices that farmers and ranchers receive for their products are determined by forces we can't control: markets and the weather. We don't know from 1 year to the next if our business will earn a profit, break even, or be in the red. Few other industries face the challenge that farmers do year after year after year. What all farmers and ranchers hope for--I know I do--is that good years will outnumber the bad ones. Believing that better times are coming, we get through the tough times by spending our retirement savings, borrowing money, refinancing debt, putting off capital improvements, and too often, lowering our standard of living. None are good for the business or the family that operate it. FARRM Accounts--with the two ``R's''--will furnish a very valuable risk management tool for farmers and ranchers and provide a meaningful incentive to save for that rainy day. The Farm Bureau commends Congressman Hulshof for his leadership on this profarmer, prosaving legislation, and we ask each Member of the Committee to cosponsor the Hulshof-Thurman FARRM Account bill and urge its passage during this Congress. Another subject: We also commend this Committee on Ways and Means for capital gains tax relief that was passed last year as part of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. Lower capital gains taxes that resulted from that bill are providing real benefit to America's farmers and ranchers. The Farm Bureau believes it is simply wrong to tax earnings twice. The capital gains tax does that, first as earned income and then as investment income. This double taxation results in inefficient allocation of scarce agriculture resources and less net farm income. Farmers and ranchers need capital gains tax relief to ensure the cost and availability of investment capital. The tax reduces the amount available for reinvestment. When borrowing from banks or other institutions, the impact of the tax on farm profitability can affect loan eligibility. Capital gains taxes are a deterrent for new and expanding farms and ranches. Some older farmers and ranchers want to sell their farms, but they don't. I'm approaching that myself. We don't because we don't want to pay the capital gains tax rate, even at the lower 20 percent level. When we do sell, young farmers and ranchers must pay a premium to cover the capital gains tax assessed on the seller. We, frankly, believe that capital gains taxes should not exist, but until repeal is possible we support cutting the rate to no more than 15 percent, regardless of the length of time that assets are held, and believe that assets should be indexed for inflation. We also recommend that the $500,000 exclusion that you passed last year for the sale of a primary residence, should be expanded to include farms and ranches. It's a matter of equity, we believe, and of fairness. Last year's reduction in capital gains taxes improved the financial environment in which farmers and ranchers operate our businesses. We urge Congress to enact FARRM Accounts--with the two ``R's''--Congressman Hulshof's bill--and further reduce capital gains taxes without delay. The result will benefit farmers, consumers, and the economy. I thank you for this opportunity to present this testimony. [The prepared statement follows:] Statement of Dean Kleckner, President, American Farm Bureau Federation My name is Dean Kleckner. I am a hog and grain farmer from Rudd, Iowa, and who serve as the elected president of the American Farm Bureau Federation. AFBF is a general farm organization of 4.7 million families whose members produce every commodity commercially marketed in this country. Farm Bureau commends the Committee on Ways and Means for calling this hearing to focus attention on the importance of saving and investment incentives. I am pleased to be here today to speak on behalf of several initiatives that would be beneficial to farmers and ranchers. FARRM ACCOUNTS Farm Bureau supports the creation of Farm and Ranch Risk Management Accounts (FARRM), to help farmers and ranchers manage risk though savings. Using Farm and Ranch Risk Management Accounts, agricultural producers would be encouraged to save money in good economic times for the ultimate lean economic years. Like other small businessmen, farmer and ranchers have predictable expenses. Each month they must pay for fuel, animal feed, equipment repairs, building maintenance, insurance, utilities, and meet a payroll. They must plan for seasonal expenses like taxes, seed, heat, and fertilizer they must also budget for major purchases like equipment, land and buildings. While many expenses can be predicted and to some degree controlled, farm income is neither predictable nor controllable. The prices that farmers and ranchers receive for their commodities are determined by forces over which they have no control, markets and the weather. Farmers and ranchers do not know from one year to the next if their businesses will earn a profit, break even, or operate in the red. Few other industries must face such a challenge year after year after year. What all farmers hope for is that the good years will outnumber the bad ones. Believing that better times are coming, farmers and ranchers get through tough times by spending their retirement savings, borrowing money, refinancing debt, putting off capital improvements and loweriing. All of these activities damage the financial health of a farm or ranch and the well- being of the family operating the business. The 1996 farm bill phased out government price and income supports to farmers through the year 2002. Farmers and ranchers supported this phase-out because of the promise of expanding market opportunities and assurances by Congress that new ways would be found to help farmers and ranchers manage their financial risks. FARRM accounts would encourage farmers and ranchers to save by allowing them to put up to 20 percent of their net farm income, pretax, into a Farm and Ranch Risk Management (FARRM) Account. Money would be allowed to remain in the account for no more than five years and would be subject to taxation at withdrawal. Farm Bureau asks each of you for your support for FARRM accounts. Their creation will give farmers and ranchers a meaningful incentive to save for a rainy day and provide a very valuable tool for managing financial risk. We urge you to cosponsor legislation to create FARRM accounts and to pass it into law during the 105th Congress. INCOME AVERAGING Farm Bureau compliments Congress for including income averaging for farmers and ranchers in the Tax Relief Act of 1997. This action added a much needed dose of fairness to the tax code. Unfortunately, this important section of the bill sunsets after 2000. As explained earlier, farm and ranch income varies greatly from year to year due to unpredictable markets and uncontrollable prices. It is common for a typical farmer from my state of Iowa to see his taxable income vary by 50 percent over the course of a marketing cycle. During that same period, his income tax rate can vary from 0 percent to over 30 percent. This means that the farmer ends up paying more in taxes than his nonfarm neighbor who earns the same aggregate income in equal installments. In addition to being unfair, a tragic result of a tax code without income averaging is that it makes it more difficult for farmers and ranchers to reinvest in their businesses and to prepare for bad years. Farmers and ranchers can only save money when the money they earn is available to invest. Without income averaging, inflated tax rates produce high taxes that eat up farm or ranch profits rather td for difficult financial times. Beginning next year, income averaging will work by allowing farmers and ranchers to reduce their farm income in a given year by treating a portion of that income as if it was earned in the three previous years. While the farmer's or rancher's tax liability for the current year would be reduced, the amount of taxes due for the previous two years could increase. This creates fairness in the tax code and would allow farmers and ranchers to save what they have earned instead of paying overstated taxes. Farm Bureau calls upon Congress to make income averaging a permanent part of the tax code. The provision could by be improved by allowing farmers and ranchers to allocate a greater portion of current income to the lowest income year rather than dictating that it be reallocated in equal installments. CAPITAL GAINS TAXES Farm Bureau commends the Committee on Ways and Means for capital gain tax relief passed as part of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. Lower capital gains tax rates that took effect last summer are providing real benefit to America's farmers and ranchers. Farm Bureau believes it is wrong to tax earnings twice. The capital gains tax does that, first as earned income and then as investment income. For farmers and ranchers the tax is especially burdensome because it interferes with the sale of farm assets and causes asset allocation decisions to be made for tax reasons rather than business reasons. The result is the inefficient allocation of scarce capital resources, less net income for farmers and reduced competitiveness in international markets. Farmers also need capital gains tax relief in order to ensure the cost and availability of investment capital. Most farmers and ranchers have limited sources of outside capital. It must come from internally-generated funds or from borrowing from financial institutions. The capital gains tax reduces the amount of money available for reinvestment by farmers and ranchers. Financial institutions look closely at financial performance, including the impact of the capital gains tax on the profit-making ability of a business when deciding loan eligibility. Capital gains taxes affect the ability of new farmers and ranchers to enter the industry and expand their operations. While many think of the capital gains tax as a tax on the seller, in reality it is a penalty on the buyer. Older farmers and ranchers are often reluctant to sell assets because they do not want to pay the capital gains taxes. Buyers must pay a premium to acquire assets in order to cover the taxes assessed on the seller. These higher costs for asset acquisition negatively impact the ability of new and expanding farmers and ranchers. Farm Bureau believes that capital gains taxes should not exist. Until repeal is possible, we support cutting the rate of taxation to no more than 15 percent regardless of the length the assets are held. We also recommend that the recently increased exclusion on the sale of a primary residence, now set at $500,000, should be expanded to include farms and ranches and that rate relief should also be provided to incorporated farmers and ranchers. Farm Bureau also supports adjusting capital gains for inflation so that only real gains in the value of assets would be taxed. Under current law, many farmers and ranchers pay an effective tax rate that is extreme and sometimes end up paying more in capital gains taxes than the increase in the real value of the assets. For assets held for long periods of time, adjusting their value for inflation is a matter of fairness. Farmland provides a good example. Farmers and ranchers on average hold farmland for about 30 years. In 1967, farmland in my state of Iowa was valued at an average of $257 per acre. In 1997, the average was $1,680. A farmer who bought 300 acres of average land in 1967 for $77,100 and sold it in 1997 would have a taxable gain of $426,400 and owe $85,380 at a 20 percent tax rate. Average prices in the U.S. economy are now 4.26 times what they were 30 years ago. This means that the real increase of value on those 300 acres was $175,554, making the effective tax rate on the real capital gain 48.6 percent. FARMER IRA Farm Bureau also supports allowing receipts from the sale of farm and ranch assets to be placed directly into a pretax individual retirement savings account (IRA). Withdrawals would be taxed at the regular applicable income tax rate. Farm and ranch assets accumulated over a lifetime are often the ``retirement plan'' for farmers and ranchers. Allowing these funds to be placed into a pretax account would treat farmers and ranchers in the same manner as other taxpayers who contribute to IRAs throughout their working life. EXEMPTION FOR THE FIRST $1,000 OF INTEREST INCOME Farm Bureau believes that there should be no income tax on the first $1,000 of interest income for individuals. While the exemption would provide a great savings incentive for taxpayers of all income levels, it would be especially beneficial to middle and lower income taxpayers. It would be of special value to young people trying to get into the farming business, to students saving for college and to workers saving to buy their first home. The savings incentive would also help young people establish a pattern of saving leading to a lifetime of saving and investing that would be good, not only for the individual, but for the economy. CONCLUSION American farmers and ranchers are the most productive in the world, allowing U.S. citizens to spend only less than 11 percent of their income on food, the lowest percentage in the world. Last year's reduction in capital gains taxes greatly improved the financial environment in which farmers and ranchers operate their businesses. In order for them to continue their high level of productivity and improve on their record, Farm Bureau urges Congress to make further improvements in capital gains tax law, to enact FARRM accounts and to extend income averaging without delay. The results will benefit farmers, consumers and the economy. Thank you again for the opportunity to testify today on these matters of importance to our nation's farmers and ranchers and their families. Mr. Herger [presiding]. Thank you, Mr. Kleckner. Mr. Hartman, please. STATEMENT OF DAVID A. HARTMAN, CHAIRMAN, INSTITUTE FOR BUDGET & TAX LIMITATION, AND CHAIRMAN AND CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER, HARTLAND BANKS, N.A., AUSTIN, TEXAS Mr. Hartman. Thank you. Mr. Chairman, Members of Congress, ladies and gentlemen, my name is David Hartman, chairman of the Hartland Banks and chairman of the Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation, both of Austin, Texas. My testimony today presents the institute's proposals for closing the U.S. capital formation gap. Before I commence, I would like to applaud the efforts of you, Mr. Chairman, and your Committee, to reduce, simplify, and make more efficient our Tax Code. Our Nation, which throughout most of this century was a net exporter of financial capital to the rest of the world, has recently been importing one-half of its net new capital formation each year from abroad. This is no Marshall Plan. The earnings which we pay to foreigners will drain our national income in the future, and we cannot rely on endless importing. The problems of insufficient capital formation have come from four sources: the Federal deficit, taxing the corpus of our existing capital, insufficient personal savings, and double taxation of corporate income. The Federal deficit has diminished, and the budget now projects a current cash flow surplus. However, under our present circumstances of a huge deficit in capital formation and a pending Social Security crisis, a surplus of at least the difference between the current inflows and outflows of Social Security and Medicare should be the minimum for responsible fiscal policy. Nearly that scale of surplus is projected for fiscal year 2002--the sooner the better. Moving up rear-loaded spending cuts could provide room to circumvent PAY-GO. It is further proposed that the following changes be made to the Internal Revenue Code in order to remedy the problems that limit capital formation. First, allow rollover of capital gains which are reinvested in any capital assets or accounts, without taxation. Two, tax any capital gains not reinvested at ordinary rates, after indexing, for inflation, which ironically comes out pretty close to 20 percent. Allow estates the same rollover as for capital gains with continuity of ownership, including taxation at the prevailing ordinary tax rates after indexing for inflation those assets not reinvested. Allow all individuals the right to save and invest up to a total of 15 percent of their income, with exclusion from income taxation, without limitation of income or nature of investment. Fifth, end double taxation of dividends by exempting dividends from income taxation, and by excluding increases in retained earnings from capital gains on stocks. We note here that we would consider that the interest should continue to be taxed when received as income and when paid for productive purposes, exempted as a factor cost. The first four proposals, which should be considered the most important for capital formation are estimated to cost $78 billion per year and are presented in order of priority. The elimination of double taxation, while the most unjustifiable and confiscatory, is of lesser priority due to its estimated revenue cost of $99 billion and the fact that it will be in part consumed rather than reinvested. The right to exclude up to 15 percent of income should promote a personal savings increase of $96 billion. The reductions in capital gains and estate taxations due to rollovers would fully translate into increased capital formation. Should Congress resolve to budget sooner a $98 billion surplus equal to the net cash inflow of Social Security and Medicare, the combined effect would be additional new domestic capital formation equal to $240 billion. The net result, as estimated, would return the United States once again to a capital surplus in control of its economy's future. The proposals presented for the first four items should prove to be self-funded over the course of time. The additional supply of capital that results would lead to a return to interest rates comparable to those in the early sixties, resulting in a reduction of $72 billion per year in Federal net interest costs, prospectively and into the future. A productivity increase dividend of perhaps a half a percent a year could yield an additional $64 billion in taxes by 5 years hence. The benefits would accrue to all Americans--a $100 billion-plus in mortgage interest and a $100 billion-plus dividend in growth of personal income. In summary, it is of critical importance that we adopt the following measures to increase capital formation: rollover of capital gains, indexing of capital gains for inflation, rollover of estate assets, exclusion of 15 percent of personal income saved, and run a responsible budget surplus. Hopefully, the double taxation of corporate income could be included as well in the future. I conclude by reminding you that Federal Government spending consumes an excessive portion of the Nation's resources at the expense of the productive private sector and capital formation. Nothing could brighten the future of this country more than a commitment to less government and lower taxation to enable closing the capital formation deficit. Mr. Chairman, I have offered an additional exhibit, which I would like to have included in the record. It shows the comparison of a 20-percent capital gains tax compared to indexed capital gains. And I would also like to request, if it would be possible, that we offer the Institutes just released assessment of the marriage tax penalty. Mr. Herger. Without objection, that will be done. [The prepared statement and attachments follow:] Statement of David A. Hartman, Chairman, Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation, and Chairman and Chief Executive Officer, Hartland Banks, N.A., Austin, Texas [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.145 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.146 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.147 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.148 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.149 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.150 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.151 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.152 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.153 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.154 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.155 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.156 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.157 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.158 Mr. Herger. Thank you, Mr. Hartman. Mr. Kelly. STATEMENT OF W. THOMAS KELLY, PRESIDENT, SAVERS & INVESTORS LEAGUE, VILLANOVA, PENNSYLVANIA Mr. Kelly. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My name is W. Thomas Kelly. I am the president of the Savers & Investors League in Villanova, Pennsylvania. I am here to discuss the Individual Investment Account Act, H.R. 984, which has been favorably commented upon by some of the other presenters here today. These accounts operate like IRAs, and they can be described in just three sentences. Every person can make unlimited tax deductible contributions to their individual investment account. These assets are invested tax- free until withdrawn by the owner or the beneficiary. There are no penalty taxes, no forced distributions, and no estate tax at death. Now I'd like to describe just some of the attributes of this legislation. First, it is fiscally sound. It produces tax revenue gains, not losses. Also, it is bipartisan in sponsorship, both in the House and the Senate. It has been voter-taxpayer tested and enthusiastically endorsed. There are few, if any, transition problems. It promotes new saving by lowering the cost of savings. In effect, it converts an income tax to a form of consumption tax so that savings are only taxed once, as they should be. Permit me to comment upon the cost. Static revenue estimates show costs as being high and continue to grow continuously over the years. However, when proper analysis of this proposal is made through dynamic revenue estimates, they show that costs are low, they stay low for a few years during the transition period, then the static scoring shows that tax revenues gain and grow and grow. Static scoring shows major tax revenue losses, whereas dynamic scoring shows major tax revenue gains. It is appropriate to state that static scoring has major flaws in its inception and use. Static scoring must be changed. Static scoring creates major tax policy mistakes. What would be the effect of this legislation? First, I'd like to comment on just two major effects--on jobs and on the aftertax income of our taxpayers. Jobs, with this tax proposal, will start to increase immediately. In less than 3 years, 400,000 new jobs will be created. That is about the same number of jobs which are held in the city of Detroit currently, to give a frame of reference. In less than 10 years the number of jobs will increase by 1,300,000. That is approximately the employment currently in the city of Chicago. In less than 15 years, the number of jobs will increase by 2,100,000, and that number of new jobs is about two-thirds of the number of jobs in New York City. Talking about the aftertax income of our taxpayers, they will increase in less that 10 years by about 10 percent. This is through the income capital growth that this proposal produces. The lowest quintile of those taxpayers have their aftertax income increased by 15 percent. Obviously, they increase more because they pay less in taxes, being in the lowest quintile, and many of them pay no taxes; therefore, they enjoy more of the gain that flows from the economic growth. In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, H.R. 984 is most worthy of Full Committee report, and further, this Committee, in my judgment, must insist upon correcting the fundamental flaws of static scoring. Thank you. I'll be glad to respond to any questions. [The prepared statement follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.159 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.160 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.161 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.162 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.163 Mr. Herger. Thank you very much, Mr. Kelly. Mr. McCrery, I know you have to leave. Would you like to inquire? Mr. McCrery. Yes, thank you, Mr. Chairman. Unfortunately, I do have to leave for an important meeting that started 3 minutes ago, but I did want to stay for all of your testimonies and I thought all of them were excellent. Mr. Kelly, I particularly want to thank you for your contribution to H.R. 984. It was Mr. Kelly that originally brought the idea to me, and I think it's--as you can see, Mr. Kelly--gaining some favor in important circles around the country, and we have more and more people looking at some sort of savings-exempt type of income tax as an approach that makes a lot of sense. So, thank you very much for helping us with H.R. 984. As you know, we're making some refinements to it now and hope to have that completed in the near future. So I just wanted to thank you, Mr. Kelly, and thank all of you for your testimony today. Mr. Herger. Thank you, Mr. McCrery. Mr. Kleckner, if I could ask a question of you. In 1986, Congress did away with income averaging for farmers. We brought it back again last year, at least to extend through the year 2001. Could you tell me, how would your recommendation of being able to put away 20 percent of any one year's income compare with income averaging? Mr. Kleckner. In many ways they are comparable in the end result, but we don't see them as being in opposition to each other or interfering with each other. We support both. The income averaging, if I recall correctly, was passed for 3 years; it would have to be authorized again. I think that's necessary. Income averaging really affects us farmers mostly when we have a spike in income. If you have a sudden spike in income, income averaging allows you to go back over 3 years to refigure your taxes. That's somewhat expensive. But, again, it's good to have. We see the FARRM Accounts, if they're enacted, as allowing farmers to make up their own minds to set aside up to 20 percent. I think many farmers might only set aside 5 or 10 percent, but they have the option of 20 percent. It's highly unlikely in my view that farm income would stay high for 5 years, so few people would come to the place where they were forced to take money out. Farm income goes up and down. If I have 2 good years in a row, I'm happy; the third year I'll probably pull some out. So the chances of money being in there for 5 years are virtually nil in my view. We don't see them as antagonistic toward each other; they're really complementary. Mr. Herger. Good. I thank you very much. Mr. Hulshof to inquire. Mr. Hulshof. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First of all, Mr. Kleckner, thank you for your testimony. Thanks for your kind words, and I really want to thank the Farm Bureau for your support and your interest, whether it's the national American Farm Bureau Association or whether it's the 88,000 Missouri Farm Bureau members, of which I am one. When all of you are singing together in the same chorus, when you're voices are singing the same refrain, it's a loud voice. And, certainly, when you speak, we listen here in Washington. I, too, as you know, Mr. Kleckner, am a farm boy and know first hand of many of the things that you've talked about, and I'm proud to have that background. As you alluded to, farm incomes vary not only with market conditions and yield and weather, but sometimes with the political decisions we make here in Washington affect--especially on trade issues. Certainly through the farm bill of 1996, it places more risk management on farmers and ranchers, as far as future responsibility. You talked about--and Mr. Chairman, you mentioned--income averaging; yes, it's due to sunset. Hopefully, we can allow some more permanence in income averaging. But if I could perhaps answer your question, Mr. Herger, as to how these two work together. I guess they're somewhat--income averaging and the FARRM Account would be sort of like distant cousins to one another, although income averaging looks back, FARRM Accounts look forward, and I do see them complementing one another. One of the criticisms, if you want to call it that--that's probably too strong of a word about income averaging--is that it's useful only in a high year. As Mr. Kleckner says, when you spike up you can take certain amounts of that income and deflect it back in the preceding 3 years to help stabilize and reduce the amount of taxation that would have occurred in that high year. Many of us in Missouri, in fact in the Midwest, recall all too well 1993, with the great flood, and again in 1995. What do you do in a down year? Income averaging only benefits farmers and ranchers when they see a spike up and, hopefully, through the FARRM Account, it would be a way for them to prepare for the future in those third years, as you mentioned, Mr. Kleckner, that invariably come when there are drought conditions or too much rain or circumstances beyond farmers' and ranchers' control to allow them to put aside. In fact, we envision, perhaps, income averaging and FARRM Account contributions. But, again, just some of the technical points, and Mrs. Thurman and I are trying to work out the details and expect this legislation to be introduced next week. But an eligible farmer can take an above-the-line deduction up to 20 percent of net farm income. The FARRM Account is actually a trust. It's really not like an IRA, but it is income that's tax-deferred, put into this trust account for up to 5 years--and I can't envision, Mr. Kleckner, 5 good years in a row--but if, in fact, no distributions were taken from that account, that in the fifth year you would have to take a distribution. And it would then be taxed, of course, at the time that it's removed and would be included as taxable income. It would be similar to first-in, first-out rules, and that is the money that you put in the first year would be the money you would take out in the sixth year, and we have some other technical aspects to the legislation to make sure that it's mainly for individual farmers. So, the long way around to answer your question, along with what Mr. Kleckner said to you, Mr. Herger, is that we see these as working together. Income averaging is good; it's a good, useful tool. But the FARRM Account, I think, is another management tool to help farmers spread the risk, and we certainly appreciate the efforts of the Farm Bureau in helping us promote the idea, and I yield back. Mr. Kleckner. Mr. Chairman, I really think--and I'm trying to remember back in my 30-plus years of farming--I really only think I've used income averaging, when it was allowed, twice. You don't very often have those spikes where it really is effective to use. Something like FARRM, I can see a number of farmers using it fairly often. Mr. Herger. Thank you very much, and thank you for the sake of the record, particularly, in clarifying that. I'm also from agriculture country myself, and this is something that's very important to all of us. Thank you. Mrs. Johnson to inquire. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Thank you. Mr. Kelly, why would you need this other FARRM trust approach if the approach that you advocate was adopted? Mr. Kelly. Could you repeat that? Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Yes. Why would we need IRAs or Roth IRAs or this new FARRM trust proposal if the approach that you advocate is adopted? Mr. Kelly. Well, certainly the approach which I am suggesting does not remove those. Any corporation can and will continue with their pension plans. As a matter of fact, if this were introduced and passed, corporations could now return to the proper approach that they've taken and install defined benefit plans, as contrasted with defined contribution plans. It's only what I'll describe as the insane way in which our Nation taxes tax-qualified plans that has, in a sense, forced corporations to gradually get away from defined benefit plans and then lead others to install in lieu thereof defined contribution plans or 401(k)s, or 401(k)s to supplement instead of increasing defined benefit plans. There's nothing that would keep corporations from doing that which they wish. This merely offers another alternative, a very fine alternative, where corporations can utilize this approach also, and I might also add it helps solve the serious problem of terminated employees and the portability of pensions. You can go right down the list, and there are all kinds of advantages as to why corporations would utilize and encourage this kind of approach. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. In your testimony you suggest that if this approach were adopted there would be no need for special IRAs, for education, for retirement. Mr. Kelly. Yes, that's true, and I say that in this context. Today we see IRAs popping up all over the place: the education IRA, the medical savings accounts. But in the main--I guess the Chairman commented earlier--when you see those kinds of plans they become targeted plans, and they typically have phaseouts, which means that you can join in at one stage of life, then you're thrown out because you've moved up in compensation. It's sort of a shell game; you're in or you're out, and you can't figure out where you are. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. Well, certainly the complexity that we've created in the IRA laws, the complexities that we've created both with targeting IRA privileges and phaseouts does make it complex. Mr. Kelly. Yes. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. And it is becoming extraordinarily complex, so the idea of simplifying this dramatically, as you offer, is an interesting idea. I do think, though, that you really need to give some thought to the social consequences and the policy consequences of letting people contribute as much as they want to and not being taxed until they take it out and spend it, with no estate tax at no time until they spend it, because compensation schedules have an element of arbitrariness to them. I know people who work extremely hard and get paid $30,000 a year, and I know people who get $250,000 a year and, frankly, I don't think they do anything. So, compensation is not well- related, necessarily, to contribution to our society. So this kind of a tool, that's quite open-ended without any phaseout, does allow, frankly, the rich to get richer, and it allows the rich to get really a lot richer. I don't think you can really justify that, so I think you have to deal with the issue of at what point does society really need to encourage you to save? And at what point should you be carrying your own weight in providing support for government services? So, I do worry about the lack of any phaseout, though I understand perfectly well that the nondiscrimination rules in the pension area have completely eliminated small pensions and I'd like to get rid of a lot of that complexity. But I think the option you offer is desirable because it makes all of these other tools unnecessary, including the one that Kenny was just talking about. But I don't see why we would need any of these vehicles, really, if we did this right. But at some point, I think, you do have to phase out that sort of reward for savings at, in a sense, government expense. Mr. Kelly. I certainly appreciate your views, and you're not alone, but let me hasten to say that there is no reason, absolutely no reason why a cap, such as you're suggesting, should be imposed other than the fear or the feeling that people might save too much. Saving is---- Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. No, it doesn't go to that and I think that's the important point here. My concern is not that people might save too much. My concern is that by foregoing taxes on income because it is saved, as desirable as that is, we do reduce tax income for current expenses and invite that income when you spend the money. Now you say this would generate so much activity that it would offset that--I'd have to see that. But the general concept is that if you save this, we won't have you pay taxes on it until it comes back into the stream. And at a certain point, you rob one generation for the benefit of another generation, and there is a limit to how far we can go in that regard. Mr. Kelly. No; I'm sorry--and I will be glad to give you the full report which better explains your questions--but let me go on a second. When you have an upsurge in new savings, as I think everyone here will agree will happen, you are certainly going to have, through new saving, a reduction in the cost of saving. When you reduce the cost of computers, you get more computers. Reduce the cost of savings, and savings go up. When you have more savings, you have more capital. When you have more capital, you have more production, you have more jobs, you have a higher standard of living, and from that global increase--and increased corporate taxes--from that whole global increase, after a transition period from 8 to 10 years, our Federal Government starts to collect more taxes then under the existing system of taxation. You just have no comprehension-- and when I say you, I don't mean---- Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. I understand. Mr. Kelly [continuing]. I'm just talking about generally. Mrs. Johnson of Connecticut. But it could also include me. Mr. Kelly. Sitting here, people really don't appreciate the power of compound rates of return. You don't want to thwart that. Our income tax today kills it, and the higher your tax bracket, the more it kills it, the more it cuts it down. That's stupid, from just tax principles, and it really is stupid from the government's viewpoint because the more you tax away a rate of return, there's less capital to be invested thereafter. You just have to study the report--I think you already received the report in an earlier submission I made to every Member of this Committee earlier this month. And I urge everyone here, from both sides of the aisle, to study that report. It was produced by a very fine economist group here in Washington, DC. Fiscal Associates, Inc. Study that report; understand what we're dealing with here. This is serious business. The way we've taxed our capital as a nation has really thwarted, really stunted our economic growth. We could be far better off than we are today. So, anyway--[Laughter.]-- you hit a hot button. Mr. Hartman. Mrs. Johnson, could I comment on that point a moment?--because it bears directly on exactly what the Institute for Budget & Tax Limitation is proposing as well. There are some public misconceptions that exist as to how the wealth process gets distributed and how it actually works. For all that we put individuals, privately held corporations and assets through in this country, and the huge amount of time spent with accountants and attorneys and so forth, out of about $1.7 trillion, we collect $20 billion of estate taxes. We stand people on their heads; we force companies to be closed; we tend to promote the breakdown of estates that give our country's best interest, should distribute that wealth for reinvestment and for consumption, passing down our capital. We sell farms and turn them over to being subdivided, or whatever. The point--but we don't look at what the real truth is. The highly wealthy find a way to get around such circumstances. The guy you snare in this situation is the poor soul that has been building up a farm or a business, hasn't had time to play all the wrinkles, didn't know he should be giving the business away from the first year he got it to his kids, and he's the guy that can least afford to pay those $20 billion in estate taxes. The rest skate by and have done it forever. You won't stop it and I won't stop it. If you look at lifecycles, you'll find that this rich wealth described by income statistics is, in fact, quite illusory. The fact of the matter is, people tend to have, on average, little in savings when they're young. After the kids are gone they save heavily, and they disgorge those savings in retirement. And what you find is that the rich, as shown by income statistics, are largely a figment of statistical imagination. We would all be better off, as the gentleman said, if we would get rid of the spirit of envy and social manipulation and let people work, profit, save, and invest, and let them keep the money they work for to do those things. Mr. Herger. Mr. Hartman, I want to thank you. We have about 5 minutes until the vote. I'm very excited by your energetic close, Mr. Kelly. As a matter of fact, I want to run out and save some money after listening to you. Mr. Kelly. Sign up. Mr. Herger. But we--I think it's very clear in this Nation that we have a need to create an incentive to save; we know that compared to other industrial nations we rank very low. And I want to thank you very much for the very good testimony from each of you and each of our panelists this morning on this very important issue. And with that I adjourn the hearing. Thank you. [Whereupon, at 12:21 p.m., the hearing was adjourned subject to the call of the Chair.] [Submissions for the record follow:] Statement of Section of Taxation, American Bar Asssociation Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: This statement is presented on behalf of the American Bar Asssociation and supplements earlier testimony presented by the Section of Taxation of the American Bar Association. Under the U. S. income tax system, married couples with the same income pay the same tax, no matter what the source of their income. This result is the consequence of Congressional action in 1948 that permitted married couples to aggregate their incomes on one joint return and compute their tax liability as if each spouse had received one-half of their joint income.\1\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ Before 1948, each taxpayer reported his or her income and paid tax as an individual. Married couples could file joint returns, but the tax was computed using the same rate schedule as that applicable to individuals. Joint returns were then an advantage only when one spouse had deductible losses to offset the other spouse's income or when one spouse had no taxable income. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Before the 1948 Act, married taxpayers living in community property states each reported one-half of community property income for tax purposes under the decision in Poe v. Seaborn.\2\ Under a progressive income tax, the effect of Poe v. Seaborn was to shift earned income in community property states \3\ from the higher marginal tax rate of the taxpayer who earned it to the lower rate of the spouse who did not, even when each files a separate return. The 1948 income-splitting legislation made the result in Poe v. Seaborn immaterial in determining tax liability, and eliminated the differences in the tax liabilities of married couples based on where they lived. After the 1948 change, however, income tax was still calculated according to one basic rate schedule. Consequently, the income levels at which marginal rates increased in a progressive tax (``rate-breaks'') for an unmarried taxpayer were exactly 50% of the rate-breaks for married taxpayers filing joint returns. A taxpayer who married an individual with less taxable income would, as a result, pay less tax. Thus, the ``marriage bonus'' was created. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \2\ 282 U.S. 101 (1930). \3\ Earned income is always classified as community property. The very high marginal income tax rates in the 1940's caused some separate property state legislatures to enact community property rules. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- In 1969, Congress responded to concerns of single taxpayers that their tax burden was disproportionately large compared to the tax liability of a married couple with the same income by enacting an entirely new rate schedule for unmarried taxpayers. This schedule reduced the tax a single individual would pay by increasing the rate-breaks to levels which were 60% of those for married taxpayers filing joint returns. The result of this rate structure is that two taxpayers with approximately the same taxable income who marry will pay more income tax than the aggregate amount they paid as single individuals. Thus, the ``marriage penalty'' had been created. Over the thirty years which followed enactment of the individual tax schedule in 1969, a great deal has been written about the marriage penalty. It has been studied by the GAO, the CBO, the Treasury Department and the Joint Committee and this Committee has received volumes of testimony relating to it. Somewhat lost in the current deluge of criticism of the ``marriage penalty'' is one essential fact. IT IS IMPOSSIBLE TO HAVE A MARRIAGE NEUTRAL TAX in a tax system that has a progressive rate structure and in which couples with equal family incomes pay the same tax. This proposition was demonstrated with elegant mathematical simplicity by Assistant Treasury Secretary Edwin S. Cohen in testimony before this Committee in 1972.\4\ As he concluded then, and as remains the case today, ``no algebraic equation . . . can solve this dilemma . . . . All that we can hope for is a reasonable compromise.'' --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \4\ Case 1 is a single person who earns $20,000. Case 2, two single persons each earn $10,000. Case 3, a husband earns $20,000 and a wife earns zero. Case 4, a husband and wife each earn $10,000. If we want no penalty on remaining single--a large group insists upon this--Case 1 must pay the same tax as Case 3. A single person earning $20,000 pays the same tax as a married couple earning $20,000. If we want no penalty on marrying, Case 2 must pay the same tax as Case 4. Two single persons earning $10,000 each pay the same tax as a married couple each earning $10,000. If we want husband and wife to pay the same tax however they contribute to the family earnings, Case 3 pays the same tax as Case 4. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Until now, Congress has chosen to tinker with the effect of marriage on tax liabilities, but has not changed the basic relationship between the rate schedules that produces the result. The revenue statistics reveal why the problem is difficult. The CBO has reported that, under a ``basic measure'' of the penalty and bonus, 25.3 million joint returns received a marriage bonus costing nearly $33 billion in revenue compared to 20.9 million joint returns which paid a marriage penalty increasing revenues by nearly $29 billion. Efforts to mitigate the penalty without reducing the bonus (causing a tax increase for some couples) are very expensive. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- To summarize the tax results: Case 1 equals Case 3. Case 2 equals Case 4. Case 3 equals Case 4. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- It is, of course, true that one way to solve the problem is to depart from the principle that all married couples with the same income should be taxed alike. Some proposals already do that by identifying characteristics which would justify a different tax liability, principally a deduction or credit based on the earnings of the lower earning spouse, but these proposals continue to rely on the underlying principle that married couples with similar incomes should bear the same tax burden. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Based on the fundamental mathematical principle that things equals to the same thing must be equal to each other, the result should then be that Case 1 equals Case 2, or, in other words, that the tax on a single person earning $20,000 equals the tax on two single persons each earning $10,000. But that cannot be so if we are going to have a progressive income tax structure, and progressive taxation is a basic tenet of our income tax system. The tax on a single person earning $20,000--Case 1--must be greater than the total tax on two single persons each earning $10,000 if we are to have a progressive rate structure . . . . It becomes apparent from this analysis that you cannot have each of these principles operating simultaneously, and that there is no one principle of equity that covers all of these cases. Hearings on Tax Treatment of Single Persons and Married Persons where Both Spouses are Working, before the House Ways and Means Committee, 92nd Cong., 2nd Sess (1972). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Some have suggested a more radical solution--that each individual taxpayer should be liable for tax on his or her own income.\5\ Individual filing would eliminate differences in the tax burden between married and unmarried couples having the same income. A single individual and a married couple, only one of whom had income, with the same income would, potentially at least, pay the same tax.\6\ Because there are many who advocate a return to filing as individuals, it is important to explore some of the difficulties that would have to be faced were this approach to be seriously considered. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \5\ Most of the current tax scholarship to consider this question concludes that a return to individual filing is the best way to achieve tax neutrality with respect to marriage. See e.g., L. Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax, 67 S.Cal. L. Rev. 339 (1994). \6\ It would be possible, in theory, to adopt a different definition of the appropriate tax paying unit. Any such definition would have to have a simple characteristic so that all taxpayers would know what the boundaries of the unit are and the IRS could enforce it with the least possible intrusion into the personal lives of taxpayers. However, there does not appear to be any alternative definition of taxpaying unit, other than the individual or marriage, which has the same simplicity and more relevance to tax paying characteristics. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Issues Raised by Individual Filing Supporting families. It is said that the marriage penalty discourages two individuals with earned income from marrying. The marriage bonus might also be said to encourage marriage because of the tax advantage which a high earning individual could obtain after marriage with a low earning spouse. While there does not appear to be conclusive evidence for either proposition, adoption of an individual filing system would eliminate the marriage bonus. If Congress decided that there should be a tax advantage for marriage despite adoption of an individual filing system, it might consider whether to confer tax benefits on spouses who stay home, for example, to care for children. The child credit is one form of relief for families with children that might be expanded as the married filing rate schedule is eliminated. This would focus the effect of tax advantages on a different characteristic, such as minor children in the household, rather than the formal status of marriage. Assigning income between spouses. One problem that is solved by a joint filing system is the assignment of income from one spouse to the other without any shift of economic benefit. The principal issue here is posed by Poe v. Seaborn, under which community property income is divided equally between spouses no matter which one earned or has control over it. Requiring individuals to pay tax on their own incomes will again raise the problem that the income-splitting joint return was enacted to solve. Individual filing is not practical unless this problem is resolved. If Congress decides to return to individual filing as the basic principle in the income tax, it would probably be constrained to also provide that community property law will be disregarded in determining federal income tax liability. Such a decision would also require rules to allocate community property income and deductions between spouses. These issues are discussed below. An alternative solution would permit voluntary assignments of income. In Lucas v. Earl,\7\ the Supreme Court refused to give effect for tax purposes to a binding contract under which husband and wife agreed to share the husband's earnings. This principle has been the bedrock of the income tax doctrine forbidding the assignment of personal earnings to another taxpayer for tax purposes, and any relaxation has been widely viewed as seriously undermining the U. S. income tax. Voluntary assignments of income between spouses should continue to be treated as ineffective for tax purposes. A rule permitting voluntary assignment, even when limited to interspousal transactions, ignores ownership principles under which the spouse who has the closest relationship to the income in question could retain control over it. This would be inconsistent with the principle underlying individual filing. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \7\ 281 U.S. 111 (1930). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- A return to individual filing will put pressure on assignment of income principles in any event as taxpayers seek to reduce tax burdens by shifting incomes within marriage.\8\ This will, in turn, cause potential compliance problems for the Internal Revenue Service in the exercise of its responsibility to assure that real transfers have occurred before income shifting is permitted.\9\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \8\ Married taxpayers who do pool their resources would be encouraged to make interspousal transfers of property in order to allocate income for tax purposes. Interspousal transfers would not be taxable because married taxpayers are treated as a single taxpaying unit for this purpose. IRC Sec. Sec. 1041; 2523. It might seem ironic to some that present system of joint filing is attacked on the ground, among others, that it is based on an inaccurate premise--to wit, that married taxpayers universally pool their resources, when it is asserted that they do not. In a system of individual filing, required for all taxpayers, those who do pool may have an advantage in the allocation of income to achieve the best possible outcome in determining tax liability. Family law scholars might welcome such a result as encouraging real transfers to spouses who would otherwise be in an economically inferior position. \9\ Audits of interspousal transfers to determine the appropriate income tax consequences seem contrary to the purpose of section 1041, which is to reduce the tax significance of these transfers. At some level, this type of audit can become more intrusive than desirable or even perhaps sustainable when viewed in light of the IRS' current problems. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Determining how income should be allocated between spouses. Allocation issues, as distinct from the filing burden discussed below, are difficult. Many allocation issues may turn out to be straightforward for most taxpayers and where the supporting records for an allocation are lacking, arbitrary default rules can be adopted. Nonetheless, there are some problems. Business income. Spouses may participate in the same business as owners, operators or employees. Business income may not be clearly the income of either, or may be arbitrarily allocated by them, potentially for tax effect. One possible approach would be to allocate business income to the spouse with control over the business. Jointly owned property. The most administrable and reasonable rule for jointly owned property would be for title ownership to control how income from that property is allocated for tax purposes. Deductions. An itemized deduction expense might be paid by one spouse, or from joint funds. In order to measure the taxable income of each spouse most accurately in an individual return system, the spouse who pays the expense should receive the deduction (e.g., the spouse makes the payments on a joint mortgage on the couple's jointly owned personal residence). Payments from a joint account, or made under circumstances where the identity of the payor cannot be shown from supporting records, could be divided equally. Personal exemptions or credits. These are rate reduction devices for families with dependents. The spouse could allocate these as they decide; any alternative approach seems unduly burdensome and complex. The filing burden. Both the Treasury Department (in its report on joint and several liability) and the Internal Revenue Service have asserted that separate filing for spouses would cause an enormous processing burden for the IRS. Some states now require married persons to pay tax individually and permit spouses to file a single return on which the income and deductions of the spouses are allocated between them. For most taxpayers, this is not difficult. But it is also true that state allocation requirements are probably simpler than those that would apply to a federal allocation regime. States' allocation systems begin with amounts reported on the federal return, and rely on the federal system for substantiation. Allocations for state purposes, moreover, carry less significance because marginal rates are lower and effective rates are lower still due to the deductibility of the state income tax for federal purposes. It is a different matter if allocation were permitted for federal purposes. Review of the allocation decisions also adds administrative burdens. Rates. Eliminating the joint return rate schedule will change the allocation of the tax burden and the overall revenue yield of the individual income tax. The tax burden would increase on married couples in which one spouse earns most of the income, absent broader changes in rate schedules. A shift to an individual filing system would accordingly raise broader issues of the appropriate rate schedule. Intermediate Proposals As the foregoing demonstrates, the costs of moving to a system of individual filing are significant. The marriage penalty can be alleviated but not eliminated, with less comprehensive revisions. Reducing the tax rate on earned income. The system of joint filing in place since 1948 has had an impact on married persons which is independent of marriage neutrality. When both spouses have earned income, the income of one spouse (the ``secondary earner'') is ``stacked'' on top of the income of the other (the ``primary earner'') for purposes of determining the marginal rate of tax applicable to the secondary income. The secondary income will then be perceived to have been taxed more heavily than will the income of the primary earner. While there is no obvious answer to which income is ``primary,'' the rational choice is to treat the spouse with the larger income as the primary earner. One way to address the disproportionate tax burden imposed on the second earner is to reduce the tax burden on the second income through a mechanism like an earned income deduction. From 1981 through 1986, a married couple filing a joint return was allowed to deduct 10% of the earned income of the lower earning spouse up to a maximum of $30,000. A similar provision, adjusted to meet revenue requirements, would reduce the tax burden on the income of the lesser earning spouse and could do so at moderate cost. This proposal is more beneficial to higher income married taxpayers because this is where the incentive effect of the stacking problem is likely to be the greatest. Another way to address the issue is through a tax credit. The Tax Section adopted a Legislative Recommendation in 1978, subsequently passed by the ABA House of Delegates, that would permit a credit for married individuals equal to the taxes paid on the earned income of the spouses in excess of the sum of the taxes each spouse would pay on the separate income of each if unmarried. The effect of the proposal is to assure that no married individual will pay a greater tax on earned income due to marital status. Adjusting rate breaks for higher income taxpayers. The marriage penalty was exacerbated by the 1993 tax changes, particularly at upper income levels where the rate breaks for the higher marginal rates for single individuals were placed at a higher percentage of the similar rate breaks for joint returns. This effect could be reduced by raising the rate breaks for the joint return rate schedule. For example, the rate breaks for the basic marginal rates (15, 28 and 31%) for singles are approximately 60% of those for joint returns; thus, the 28% marginal rate for 1997 for single returns begins at $59,750, which is 60% of $99,600, the 28% rate break for joint returns. On the other hand, the rate break for the 36% rate is $124,650 for singles, which is 82% of the comparable rate break for joint returns ($151,750); and the 10% surcharge begins at the same income level for both singles and joint returns. The effect is to produce a very large marriage penalty at the highest incomes. That marriage penalty could be reduced by reducing the income level at which singles begin to pay the higher marginal rates, by raising the income level at which joint filers begin to pay at the comparable marginal rate, or by some combination of the two. This simple measure would address the most striking examples of marriage penalties. In 1969, the Congress decided to calibrate the brackets for single taxpayers as 60% of the brackets for married taxpayers filing jointly. A reduction in this relationship, which could be accomplished by reducing the tax on married couples without increasing the tax currently imposed on unmarried individuals, would reduce the ``penalty'' on two earner couples who marry but would, in the long run, cause a redistribution of a portion of the income tax burden from married couples to single individuals. Although related to the ``marriage penalty'' issue, the relative tax burden of single and married individuals is a different issue, which ought to be considered on its own merits. The earned income tax credit. For taxpayers at the opposite end of the income scale, there are also marriage penalty effects. The most serious involves the earned income tax credit and results from the application of the earned income tax phase-out rule. When the phase-out amount for an individual taxpayer is more than half of the amount allowed for a married couple, married taxpayers will have a smaller exemption (the phaseout will begin earlier) than would be true for two individual unmarried taxpayers. More generally, however, a married taxpayer is required to aggregate his or her income with the income of a spouse in order to apply the phase-out rule. This is accomplished by requiring married couples to file a joint return in order to obtain the benefit. The earned income tax credit, for example, is phased out as the taxpayer's adjusted gross income (or earned income if greater) rises above a phaseout level ($11,930 for 1997).\10\ This level is the same whether the taxpayer files as an individual or jointly with his or her spouse, but she is required to file jointly if married.\11\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \10\ IRC Sec. Sec. 32(a)(2)(B); -(b)(2). \11\ See IRC Sec. 32(d). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- In these cases, as with other means-tested welfare benefits, the apparent purpose is to limit a benefit based upon household resources, where marriage is used to define the household. The difficulty with the definition is that many households include individuals who are not married, and in some instances, households do not include both spouses. Because of the definition, however, and the relative importance of the EITC to taxpayers in that income level, there is a strong incentive not to marry. There may be sound programmatic reasons for aggregating household incomes, but an adjustment in phase- out levels for two income producing taxpayers in the same household could significantly affect the impact of this provision on marriage decisions. Other phaseouts. Differential taxation of married couples results also from other provisions in the Internal Revenue Code which provide different levels of benefits depending on whether the taxpayers are married or single. Some of these effects are artifacts of the rate schedule, such as the amounts allowed as standard deductions.\12\ In 1998, after indexation, an unmarried taxpayer is allowed a standard deduction of $4,250, which is more than half the $7,100 amount allowed to married taxpayers filing a joint return. Taxpayers who marry are limited to a standard deduction which is $1,400 less than the amounts they could otherwise claim by not marrying and filing separately. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \12\IRC Sec. 63(c). --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Phase out provisions for personal exemptions and itemized deductions. Personal exemptions are subject to a phase out beginning at specified adjusted gross income levels for which the ratio between single and married filers is 67%.\13\ Itemized deductions are subject to a limitation imposed after the specified adjusted gross income level for both joint returns and returns of an unmarried individual.\14\ These provisions are revenue raising devices at high income levels and thus contribute to the marriage penalty at the top end of the scale. Shifting the bracket levels to diminish the marriage penalty could be effective to reduce the marriage penalty effect of these phase-out provisions. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \13\IRC Sec. 151(d)(3). The ``threshold amount'' is indexed. For l998, the threshold amount is $186,800 for joint returns and $124,500 for single returns. Two individuals who marry will lose $62,200 of the otherwise available threshold, depending on the relative amounts of income earned by each. \14\IRC Sec. 68(b). The ``applicable amount'' is $124,500. Two taxpayers who marry will lose one full ``applicable amount.'' --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Conclusion Individual filing is the only way to eliminate the marriage penalty but it would require abandoning the fifty year old objective of tax neutrality among married couples. A case can be made in favor of that approach. However, it would entail significant compliance, filing and administrative costs. On balance, these costs appear to outweigh the potential benefits of individual filing. This statement has suggested other ways to reduce the increased tax burden imposed on two income families in the context of the present system. These alternative approaches seek to minimize the impact of changes on the distribution of the tax burden on all types of filers, a matter which will have to be considered more fully as the Committee debates this issue. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.164 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.165 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.166 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.167 Statement of Bond Market Association The Bond Market Association is pleased to provide comments on the subject of alternative minimum tax (AMT) relief for individuals. The Association represents securities firms and banks that underwrite, trade, and sell municipal, corporate, government and federal agency bonds, mortgage- and asset-backed securities and money-market instruments in the U.S. and international markets. Our members account for over 95 percent of the nation's municipal bond market activity. As such, we take an active interest in tax provisions like the AMT that affect savings, investment and the cost of capital. We commend Chairman Archer for his leadership on AMT reform generally and for focusing the committee's attention on individual AMT relief in this hearing. The municipal bond market is dominated by individual investors, who hold bonds either directly or through mutual funds. As of September 30, 1997, individual investors held almost 64 percent of all outstanding municipal debt. They are the single most important source of demand in the municipal bond market. Most municipal bond interest earned by individual investors is exempt from the ordinary income tax. As a result, investors are willing to earn a lower rate of return on their municipal bond holdings, and state and local governments are able to benefit from a lower cost of borrowing. The lower pre- tax return on municipal bond interest can be thought of as an implicit tax paid by investors not to the federal government but to state or local government bond issuers in the form of reduced borrowing costs. Unfortunately, not all municipal bond interest is entirely exempt from income taxation. Since 1986, the interest on so-called ``private-activity'' bonds has been subject to the individual AMT. Private-activity bonds include any debt issued by states or localities where more than 10 percent of the proceeds is used by a private business and more than 10 percent of the debt service is secured by a private business or where more than five percent of the proceeds are lent to a private party. In general, private-activity bonds may not be tax-exempt. This restriction exists in order to prevent private parties from unjustifiably benefiting from the federal tax exemption. However, when imposing the limitation on private use of the tax-exemption, Congress recognized that certain uses of private-activity bonds are important in implementing public policy goals. As a result, certain uses of private-activity bonds are eligible for the tax-exemption subject to numerous restrictions and limitations. Among these is a provision which fully subjects private-activity bond interest to the individual and corporate AMTs.\1\ The application of the individual AMT to private-activity bond interest has resulted in some peculiar market conditions which negatively affect the ability of states and localities to borrow at the lowest possible cost. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ In addition, 75 percent of non-private-activity bond interest is subject to the corporate AMT under the adjusted current earnings provision. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- With careful planning, taxpayers are able to predict with reasonable certainty whether in any given year they will be subject to the ordinary income tax or the AMT. The interest on most private-activity bonds is subject to the AMT but not to the ordinary income tax, and interest on other municipal bonds is exempt from both the ordinary income tax and the individual AMT. As a result, ``AMT bonds'' tend to yield 20-30 basis points (0.2-0.3 percentage point) higher than comparable bonds which are not subject to the AMT. This increased yield compensates AMT bond investors for the risk they face that their bonds may be taxable if, as a result of poor planning or an unforeseen change in circumstances, they unpredictably fall under the AMT. Municipal bond investors who anticipate that they will fall under the AMT simply buy bonds which are not subject to the AMT. Investors who believe they will pay the ordinary income tax are able to buy AMT bonds at yields higher than they can obtain by buying non-AMT bonds. Indeed, it is unlikely that the federal government collects much, or even any, tax revenue as a result of subjecting private-activity bond interest to the individual AMT. Virtually all interest on AMT bonds is likely paid to investors who fall under the ordinary income tax. Unfortunately, the losers in this scenario are state and local governments that issue AMT bonds, who face an unnecessarily high cost of borrowing as a result of the tax treatment of their interest. Clearly, the AMT was never designed with the goal of increasing borrowing costs for state and local governments. As you know, the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) concluded in a 1996 analysis that the number of individual AMT taxpayers will rise dramatically in the coming years because the ordinary income tax brackets are indexed for inflation, but the income thresholds for the AMT are not indexed. In 1996, the JCT staff predicted that the number of AMT payers would increase from 600,000 returns in 1997 to 6.2 million returns in 2006.\2\ We agree with Chairman Archer, who has wisely recognized that the AMT was never designed to apply to a large number of taxpayers and that the AMT income thresholds should be indexed for inflation. If they are not, the negative effects on state and local borrowing that ensue from the application of the individual AMT to private-activity bond interest will be exacerbated. As more and more taxpayers find themselves under the AMT, the market for AMT bonds will shrink. The ``spread'' between AMT bonds and non-AMT bonds--the differential in interest rates that state and local issuers of AMT bonds must pay relative to other municipal bond issuers-- will widen. And, ironically, the federal government will continue to collect little or no revenue from applying the AMT to private-activity bond interest. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \2\ Memorandum from Kenneth J. Kies, Joint Committee on Taxation, to John L. Buckley, House Committee on Ways and Means, regarding the ``Dole Tax Proposal,'' September 13, 1996. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- In addition to indexing the AMT ``brackets,'' we also urge the committee to reconsider the wisdom of applying the AMT to private-activity bond interest. This provision of the tax code serves no useful purpose. Its only perceptible effect is unnecessarily inflated borrowing costs for state and local bond issuers. We appreciate the opportunity to present our views on the individual AMT and the municipal bond market. We look forward to continuing to work with committee members and staff on issues of mutual interest. Statement of Kevin M. Williams, Chief Executive Officer, Distribution & LTL Carriers Association, Alexandria, Virginia The Distribution & LTL Carriers Association submits this statement on the need to reform one of the most unfair provisions in the tax code, namely the estate and gift tax laws. These code provisions impose an unconscionable tax rate of up to 55 percent on an estate. They often cause severe hardships to family businesses by forcing the sale of assets to satisfy the taxes. The law penalizes lifelong savings and investments based on antiquated social welfare goals. The Federal government receives from these taxes about $15- 17 billion, less than 1 percent of its $1.7 trillion in annual revenue. The main beneficiaries of these laws are accountants, tax attorneys and charities who implement complex asset transfer arrangements to legally reduce or avoid these onerous taxes. These costly tax avoidance practices are employed because the tax is perceived as unfair. Unfortunately, the result is often that less sophisticated persons, who do not employ these strategies, face the full brunt of these taxes. While a strong case can be made for the repeal of the estate and gift tax laws, our Association recognizes that may not be politically feasible. We concur with Senate Majority Leader Trent Lott, who stated: ``The estate tax is a monster that must be exterminated. If it were up to me, we would simply repeal the estate tax in its entirety. Unfortunately, our budget process does not allow us to completely repeal this tax all at once. We must do it in stages.'' Cong. Rec. S. 2566 (March 19, 1997). Therefore, we recommend that, as this Committee addresses the issue of reducing the tax burden, it seriously consider--as a first step--making the estate and gift taxes simpler, more equitable, and consistent with our other tax rates. As will be discussed more fully, we recommend the following: 1. There should be no tax when the taxable estate is $10 million or less. Essentially, the unified credit, which now allows a husband and wife to transfer $1.2 million, should be raised to $10 million; 2. This nontaxable estate of $10 million should be adjusted annually for inflation; 3. The graduated top rate on taxable estates should be reduced from 55 percent to either 27.5 percent or preferably to 20 percent, which is the capital gains rate. Ideally a fixed, but even lower, rate should apply to the taxable estate; 4. The annual gift tax exclusion of $10,000 per year, per donee should be increased to $20,000; and 5. The double taxation which results when a capital gains or income tax penalty is incurred because estate assets must be sold to pay these death taxes should be eliminated by some means. The Distribution & LTL Carriers Association represents trucking companies engaged in the warehousing, distribution and transportation of freight in small shipments. This so-called less-than-truckload segment of the industry generates approximately $18 billion in annual revenue from interstate transportation services. However, the overwhelming majority of these firms are private, family-owned businesses. They are entrepreneurs. Some involve several generations of families, whose goal, like for all Americans, is to pass on to their children the fruits of their labor. Estate tax reform is a top priority for these companies, since these laws can effectively bar or hinder their ability to transfer their business, which is often the largest asset in an estate. A 1995 Gallup survey found that one-third of the owners of family businesses expect that some or all the company will have to be sold to satisfy estate tax liabilities. The survey further found that 37 percent of the business inheritors had to shrink or reconstruct the enterprises solely to meet estate tax obligations. This is because of the lack of liquidity or cash to pay the estate tax. See, Cong. Rec. S. 2647 (March 20, 1997). Last year, Congress merely tinkered with the estate tax laws in the Tax and Budget Agreement. Essentially, the general estate tax exemption of $600,000, which had remained static since 1987, will be increased incrementally over ten years to $1 million. As Senator Grassley stated in his remarks last year, the $600,000 exemption needed to be increased by over $200,000 just to remain current with inflation. Cong. Rec. S. 2565 (March 19, 1997). This change is too little, too slow. Several bills have been introduced in Congress that would raise to $10 million the amount of an estate which would be exempt from taxes. (See, S.479 & S.482) There is no magic to the $10 million level. It is generally based on the belief that this level of lifelong savings is not inordinate wealth, which the government should tax again and redistribute through its spending programs. This Committee surely recognizes that the beneficiaries of most estates are the spouse and children of the decedent. It is a transfer of assets among family members. Since the estate taxes do not apply when a spouse is the beneficiary, the taxes are really punitive when the children are the beneficiaries. As Senator Grassley aptly said, ``The important thing to keep in mind about estate tax reform is that estates do not pay taxes, surviving families pay taxes.'' It is ironic and sad when both the Administration and Congress are attempting to promote education, child care, medical coverage and savings and investments, they allow the estate tax laws to undermine those goals. These assets are often used by the family to provide for their children (estimated cost to be $200,000 until age 21); to pay for college (which can exceed $100,000 for four years at a private university); to provide money for a down payment on a home or pay off an existing mortgage; to cover catastrophic medical expenses; or to provide a supplement for retirement beyond what social security will pay. In sum, a lifetime of savings of $10 millionnchmark for Congress to consider as a dividing line between taxable and nontaxable estates. This estate reform should not be limited to qualified family businesses, but should be available to all taxpayers. Moreover, to avoid the annual creep upward of taxation, there should be an indexation of the gross estate exemption for inflation. The existing exemption level of $600,000 per individual, established in 1987, lost over 25 percent of its value to inflation in 1997 dollars. An erosion of the new exemption level should be avoided through an annual inflation adjustment. In a similar manner, the annual exclusion, which permits gifts of $10,000 per year, per donee that are not subject to the unified credit, should be increased and preferably doubled. The value of this gifting allowance has similarly been eroded by inflation. The tax rate for taxable estates should also be substantially reduced. One has to go back to the old 70 percent tax rate, imposed on so-called unearned interest income, to think of a more confiscatory rate than the 55 percent estate tax rate. Moreover, the total death tax burden can exceed 73 percent, according to Senator Susan Collins, when assets have to be sold to pay estate taxes and capital gains are realized from the sale. Cong. Rec. S. 2647 (March 20, 1997). This is unconscionable! The estate tax rate should be reduced and brought in line with the much lower personal or capital gains tax rates. Senate bill, S. 482, would reduce it by half, to 27.5 percent. This is about the mid point range between the highest personal income tax rate of 39.6 percent and the capital gains rate of 20 percent. We believe the property in an estate should be treated like other real or personal property and taxed at the lower capital gains rate of 20 percent. Finally, Congress should devise a method to avoid the double taxation that occurs when assets must be sold to satisfy the estate tax requirements. One means would be to provide that assets receive a stepped-up basis to fair market value when they are devised or bequeathed by will, other legal instruments, or by statutory law upon the death of the maker. Conditions could be placed on this to limit the stepped-up basis to family members or to that portion used to pay estate taxes. There may be superior means to achieve this objective of avoiding dual taxation. We have not attempted to quantify the revenue loss to the Federal government if our recommendations were adopted. The loss would certainly be less than the full amount of $15-$17 billion now collected annually. Moreover, the net revenue loss (revenue minus expenses savings) would be considerably less. According to Senator Breaux, the Federal government incurs 65 cents in expenses for every dollars it receives under the estate tax laws. Cong. Rec. S. 2566 (March 19, 1997). Therefore, the net revenue loss under these reforms might be $3-$5 billion annually. This is an extremely nominal cost to the government, yet will provide significant benefits to many taxpayers. It could be readily paid for with only a fraction of the now projected $18 billion federal budget surplus. The Distribution & LTL Carriers Association appreciates this Committee's consideration of our views. Reform of the gift and estate tax laws is an area where, with relatively modest impact on Federal revenue, Congress can help many families and small businesses continue to provide for their children and grandchildren through the preservation of the business and personal assets that they created through hard work, savings and investments. Respectfully submitted, Kevin M. Williams Chief Executive Officer Statement of Institute for Research on the Economics of Taxation (IRET) PHASE-OUTS ARE BAD TAX POLICY, Economic Policy Bulletin No. 71, by Michael Schuyler The tax code is littered with rules that phase out various deductions, exemptions, and credits as taxpayers' incomes rise. Some of the items that taxpayers lose with higher incomes are the deductibility of individual retirement account (IRA) contributions, the earned income tax credit (EITC), the exclusion of social security benefits from taxable income, a portion of itemized deductions, even the personal exemption. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (TRA-97) adds significant new phase-outs. Its two largest provisions, the child credit and tax subsidies for college students, are both conditioned by phase-outs. Phase-outs create troubling problems in the areas of economic efficiency, simplicity, and fairness. Phase-outs raise marginal tax rates throughout the phase-out zone and, thereby, reduce incentives to work, save, and invest. Phase-outs make the tax code more complicated, which raises tax enforcement and compliance costs, both by making the tax code harder to understand and by making tax liabilities harder to compute. The instruction book that accompanies an individual's yearly tax forms includes an obstacle course of special instructions and worksheets testing whether various phase-outs affect the taxpayer and, if so, how much each relevant phase-out restricts the deductions, exemptions, or credits the taxpayer may claim. Further, although phase-outs are often called fair because they tend to increase tax progressivity, the arbitrariness and surreptitiousness of most phase-outs violates any reasonable standard of fairness. A Flock of Phase-outs Prior to this year's legislation, the individual income tax eliminated or restricted the following deductions, exemptions, and credits when taxpayers' incomes grew: the tax exemption for social security benefits, the EITC, the deduction for IRA contributions, the personal exemption, the medical deduction, the miscellaneous business deduction, the total of itemized deductions, the deduction for losses on rental real estate, the dependent care credit, the adoption credit, the exclusion for interest income from U.S. Savings Bonds used for higher education expenses, and the alternative minimum tax exempt amount.\1\ In addition, some tax provisions impose tougher than normal requirements on taxpayers above various income thresholds. An example is the increased amount of estimated tax a person must pay to avoid underpayment penalties if the person's adjusted gross income exceeds $100,000.\2\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \1\ The limitations on the deductions for medical costs and miscellaneous business expenses are properly classified as phase-outs because, as a taxpayer's income rises, the taxpayer is required to disregard for tax purposes increasing amounts of expenses in those areas. \2\ Compared to prior law, TRA-97 eases the differential in most later years, and it suspends the differential for one year (tax year 1998). The differential in the stringency of the safe harbor amount of estimated payments between taxpayers with AGIs above and below $100,000 is particularly inappropriate because higher-income taxpayers often have difficult-to-predict incomes that make it very hard for them to estimate their end-of-year tax liabilities accurately. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- To this already long list, TRA-97 has added a welter of complicated new phase-outs. The benefits created in TRA-97 that taxpayers lose as their incomes rise are: the $500 child credit, the HOPE Scholarship tax credit, the lifetime learning tax credit, the education IRA, the Roth IRA, the deduction for certain interest on student loans, and the $5,000 tax credit for first-time home buyers in the District of Columbia. TRA-97 did not remove any of the existing phase-outs. But in a few cases (e.g., deductible IRA contributions), it raised the income threshold at which a phase-out begins or otherwise eased a phase-out. Other federal taxes also have phase-out provisions. The corporate income tax, for instance, imposes two surtaxes to phase out the tax savings from the graduated corporate rate schedule. The first surtax is 5% of every dollar of taxable corporate income above $100,000 and below $335,000 and raises the 34% statutory tax rate in that corporate income range to an effective marginal tax rate of 39%; the second surtax is 3% of each dollar of taxable income between $10,000,000 and $18,333,333 and boosts the 35% statutory tax rate to an effective marginal tax rate of 38%. Corporations with incomes above $18,333,333 pay an effective flat tax rate of 35% on total taxable income. The estate and gift tax phases out the benefits of the unified credit and the graduated estate and gift tax schedule with a 5% surtax. Although the top statutory estate and gift tax rate is 55%, the surtax lifts the marginal tax rate in the phase-out zone to 60%. The individual alternative minimum tax (AMT) also has a phase-out. A certain amount of income may normally be disregarded when computing the AMT, but, as income increases, that exempt amount must be added back to the tax base. (The individual AMT is, in effect, a parallel individual income tax: people must pay either the standard income tax or the individual AMT--whichever is larger.) Appendix I identifies the phase-out provisions in the standard individual income tax. For each of these phase-outs, it reports the income threshold at which the phase-out begins, the income range over which the phase-out continues, and the maximum number of percentage points by which the phase-out may boost the marginal tax rate of people within its phase-out zone. Appendix II covers the major phase-outs mentioned above in the corporate income tax, the estate and gift tax, and the individual AMT. Chart 1 shows the income ranges over which most of the individual income tax phase-outs occur. The tax code generally designates phase-outs in terms of adjusted gross income (AGI).\3\ For example, the new HOPE Scholarship tax credit is phased out over the $10,000 AGI range from $40,000 to $50,000 for single filers and over the $20,000 AGI range from $80,000 to $100,000 for joint filers. The complexities of the Chart drive home the large number and haphazard variety of income- based phase-outs. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \3\ In contrast, the schedule of progressive tax brackets is based on taxable income. AGI differs from taxable income because AGI is measured before subtracting personal exemptions and most deductions. For example, if a couple with an AGI of $50,000 in 1997 has two dependent children, claims the standard deduction, and files jointly, the couple's taxable income would be $32,500--$17,500 less than the couple's AGI. Because a given AGI corresponds to a taxable income that is thousands of dollars lower (with the exact difference depending on filing status, number of exemptions, and deductions claimed), phase-out ranges would begin at much lower stated dollar amounts if they were expressed in terms of taxable income instead of AGI. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- The relative heights of the lines are roughly based on the potential of the various phase-outs to raise marginal tax rates. For example, the partial phase-out of the dependent care credit for 1 child increases the marginal tax rate by 1.33 percentage points, on average, for taxpayers with AGIs between $10,000 and $28,000 who would otherwise qualify for the maximum credit.\4\ The partial phase-out of the dependent care credit for 2 or more children increases the marginal tax rate by 2.67 percentage points, on average, for taxpayers with AGIs between $10,000 and $28,000 who would otherwise qualify for the maximum credit. The phase-out of the tax credit for first-time District of Columbia homebuyers would affect few taxpayers, but for those taxpayers who would qualify except for being in the phase-out range, the effective increase in their marginal tax rates would be a whopping 25 percentage points. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \4\ The partial phase-out of the dependent care credit actually occurs in a series of steps, each covering $2,000 of AGI. Rather than trying to report that complicated pattern, in which AGI changes within a step do not affect the amount phased out but small AGI changes from one step to the next have a very big impact, it is assumed throughout this study that phase-outs proceed smoothly over the phase-out range. Also, if the taxpayer could not claim the maximum credit for reasons unrelated to the phase-out (e.g., dependent care expenses below that permitted by the credit, lack of taxable income), either the phase-out would not cause as much of a jump in the marginal tax rate or the phase-out range would be shorter. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Adding more complexity, many phase-outs use modified definitions of AGI, and the modifications often differ from one phase-out to another. For instance, the phase-out of the social-security-benefit exemption adds to modified AGI half of social security benefits and all tax exempt interest, and the phase-out of deductible IRA contributions modifies AGI by including IRA contributions and certain foreign earned income and foreign housing allowances normally excluded from AGI.\5\ Because of these differences in the definition of modified AGI, taxpayers need to follow very carefully the specific instructions for the particular phase-out in question. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \5\ Because the definition of modified AGI differs among the phase- out provisions, the horizontal positions of the lines in the Chart are not always strictly comparable. [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.172 Money for the Treasury and Progressivity Phase-outs have two properties that lawmakers have found very appealing: they increase the government's tax revenues and they heighten tax progressivity. Acting Assistant Treasury Secretary Donald Lubick referred to both these features when he defended in Congressional testimony the Clinton Administration's wish that the child credit be ``targeted,'' that is, phased out with rising income. ``A targeted child credit is an efficient way to address the increase in relative tax burdens faced by larger families...The relief is directed to low- and middle-income taxpayers because of the limited resources available for tax reduction and higher-income taxpayers' relatively greater ability to pay current levels of income taxes.'' \6\ Earlier in his testimony, Mr. Lubick had associated phase-outs with fiscal responsibility. ``Given the need for fiscal discipline, one of our principles throughout President Clinton's tenure has been that tax relief should be concentrated on middle-income taxpayers.'' --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \6\ Statement of Donald C. Lubick, Acting Assistant Secretary (Tax Policy), Department of Treasury, Testimony before the House Ways and Means Committee, March 5, 1997. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Although phase-outs limit the revenue cost to the government of the deductions, exemptions, and credits being phased out, whether that is desirable or undesirable depends on circumstances. Taking more tax dollars from wage earners, savers, and entrepreneurs is not necessarily a good thing. If the tax revenues are used to finance wasteful or otherwise inappropriate government spending programs, it would be better to cut the spending and not collect the revenues. If the spending represents the best use of the resources it consumes, on the other hand, it is reasonable to seek revenues. Still, that does not justify a particular phase-out rule unless the phase-out has fewer undesirable side effects regarding economic efficiency, simplicity, and equity than any alternative means of increasing tax collections. Standard estimation models, furthermore, usually exaggerate the revenue savings. The problem is that the increased marginal tax rates produced by phase-outs worsen anti-growth tax biases, and those biases slow the economy. When the economy slows, tax collections suffer. Standard revenue estimation models, though, are static in the sense that they ignore those antigrowth effects. Hence, a phase-out that weakens the economy tends to save less revenue for the Treasury than advertised. Similarly, unless one believes that the tax system is never progressive enough and should always be more progressive (logically culminating in complete, government-enforced equality of incomes despite differences in people's industriousness, skills, and saving behavior), greater progressivity through the tax system is not necessarily a good thing. Too often, proposals are made for increasing the tax system's progressivity without inquiring whether it is sufficiently progressive already or, perhaps, overly progressive, given the problems created when the government takes income from those who earned it and gives it to other people. Moreover, if greater progressivity is sought, a particular phase-out is the proper way to do it only if that phase-out causes fewer problems than any other means of redistributing the income. How Phase-outs Increase Marginal Tax Rates Over the income range in which a deduction, exemption, or credit is being phased out, additional income adds to a person's tax bill in two ways. First, the extra income is subject to regular income tax. Second, the extra income reduces the amount of the deduction, exemption, or credit that is being phased out. A lower deduction or exemption raises taxable income further, and further increases the tax. A lower credit reduces the amount subtracted from tax, and again the person's tax bill is higher than otherwise. In either case, the higher tax is, in effect, a penalty on the extra income that triggered the phase-out. For instance, suppose that a person is in the 28% tax bracket. Also suppose that the person had been claiming a credit that is being phased out at a rate of 15 cents for each $1 of added income. First, then, an extra $1 of income increases the person's pre-credit tax liability by 28 cents. At this point, the person's marginal tax rate is 28%. Second, though, the extra $1 of income increases the person's tax liability by another 15 cents because it reduces by that amount the credit the person can subtract from his or her tax bill. Thus, the additional tax triggered by an extra $1 of income is 43 cents (28 cents plus 15 cents). In this case, the person's effective marginal tax rate is 43%, of which the phase-out is responsible for 15 percentage points. The hike in the marginal tax rate due to the phase-out extends over the income range in which the deduction, exemption, or credit is being phased out. At incomes above and below the phase-out range, the phase-out does not affect the marginal tax rate. As a concrete example, consider the phase-out of the HOPE Scholarship tax credit. Suppose that a single parent has one dependent child entering college, and suppose that tuition costs are sufficient for the parent to claim the maximum $1,500 HOPE Scholarship tax credit in 1998 (ignoring for a moment the income limitation attached to the new credit). The HOPE Scholarship tax credit is phased out ratably over the $10,000 modified AGI range from $40,000 to $50,000. This taxpayer loses 15 cents of credit per dollar of income in the phase-out range.\7\ Accordingly, if the parent's modified AGI is between $40,000 to $50,000, each extra $1 of income will increase the parent's tax bill in two ways. First, the regular tax on the extra $1 of income will raise the parent's tax liability by either 15 or 28 cents, depending on the parent's tax bracket.\8\ Second, the extra $1 will reduce the HOPE Scholarship tax credit by 15 cents, which raises the parent's tax bill by 15 cents. Thus, in the phase-out zone for this credit, the single parent's effective marginal tax rate on each additional $1 of income will be either 30% (if the parent is in the 15% tax bracket) or 43% (if the parent is in the 28% tax bracket). Note further that modified AGI includes income from saving as well as wages. Thus, parents who save for their children's education are penalized with a reduction in the tax credit designed to encourage education.\9\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \7\ If the pre-phase-out credit were smaller, the loss per dollar of income in the phase-out range would also be smaller. For example, if tuition costs were sufficiently low that the taxpayer's maximum credit was only $1,000, the taxpayer would only lose 10 cents of credit per dollar of income in the phase-out range. \8\ Tax brackets depend on taxable income, not AGI. At the start of the phase-out, the taxpayer in the example will probably have a taxable income within the 15% rate bracket. At about the mid-point of the phase-out range, the taxpayer's taxable income will most likely cross over into the 28% rate bracket. \9\ Some parents may be able to avoid this penalty on saving for a child's education by putting some of the saving in the child's name. That way, returns on that portion of the saving would not restrict the parents' eligibility to claim the credit. (This assumes it is the parents who claim the credit and that they pay enough of the education costs to do so.) Giving the saving to the child would mean that yearly tax returns might have to be filed for the child on interest income. Also, until the child reaches age 14, interest income might be taxed at the parent's marginal rate because of the ``kiddie tax'' introduced as part of the 1986 tax act. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- As another example, this one involving a deduction, consider the 2% AGI threshold for the miscellaneous business expense deduction. The tax code allows individuals to claim miscellaneous business expenses only to the extent that they exceed 2% of AGI. Suppose that a taxpayer itemizes, has miscellaneous business expenses of $1,500, and an AGI of $60,000. Because 2% of that AGI is $1,200, the person can only claim miscellaneous business expenses of $300 ($1,500 of valid deductions--$1,200 income-based disallowance). For this taxpayer, an extra $1 of AGI would lower his or her miscellaneous business expense deduction by 2 cents and raise his or her taxable income by an additional 2 cents, for a total of $1.02. If the taxpayer is in the 28% rate bracket, this increases his or her tax liability by 28.56 cents (28% of $1.02). The taxpayer's effective marginal tax rate on the added $1 of income is 28.56%, of which the phase-out contributes 0.56 percentage points.\10\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \10\ The size of the marginal tax rate increase depends on the individual's tax bracket. For a person in the 15% tax bracket who claims the miscellaneous business expense deduction, the boost in the marginal tax rate due to the phase-out of this deduction would be 0.3 percentage points; for the person in the example in the 28% tax bracket, it was 0.56 percentage points; for a person in the 31% tax bracket, it would be 0.62 percentage points; for a person in the 36% tax bracket, it would be 0.72 percentage points; and for a person in the 39.6% tax bracket, it would be 0.792 percentage points. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Phase-outs Worsen Tax Distortions As explained above, when taxpayers lose deductions, exemptions, or credits because their incomes are increasing, the losses produce a spike in the taxpayers' marginal tax rates throughout the range of income over which the phase-out occurs. The tax rate spike hurts the economy because it aggravates tax biases against work, saving, and a variety of specific products and activities that the tax code treats more harshly than others. By compounding tax biases, phase-outs urge people to work less, save less, and be less productive. Consider, for instance, a single individual of age 62 or over who takes the standard deduction, has yearly social security benefits of $12,000, and receives private pension, interest, and dividend income of $30,000. This taxpayer would normally be in the 28% tax bracket. Due to the income-based phase-out of the exemption for social security benefits, each additional dollar of income requires the individual to add 85 cents of social security benefits to taxable income, for a combined increase in taxable income of $1.85. At the margin, therefore, each extra dollar of income from private saving raises the person's tax bill by 51.8 cents: 28 cents due to regular tax and 23.8 cents due to the phase-out of the exclusion for social security benefits. Note that the tax is effectively imposed on the income from saving that triggered the tax hike, not on the social security benefit itself. This very high tax bite is a powerful inducement for the person to save less and consume more. As a result, some people receiving social security and some younger people planning ahead for their retirement years will decide to save less than they otherwise would because of the tax penalty. The tax-induced drop in saving leaves those people less financially secure and, because saving and investment are major contributors to productivity, leaves society as a whole less productive. Wage and salary income of people who continue working after they begin receiving social security benefits can also trigger taxation of benefits (as well as being subject to payroll taxes). For those who fall in the phase-out zone for the exclusion of benefits from income, the penalty against work effort is at least as bad as against saving. If working beneficiaries also run afoul of the social security earnings test, the tax penalty will be even harsher, exceeding 100% of added wage income in some cases.\11\ --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \11\ Social security beneficiaries may earn limited amounts of wages without losing social security benefits. However, for each dollar of wages above the exempt amount, beneficiaries age 62-64 lose $1 of benefits for every $2 in wages (a 50% tax rate); beneficiaries age 65- 69 lose $1 of benefits for every $3 in wages (a 33.33% tax rate). The loss of benefits reduces the amount of benefits subject to tax, resulting in a bit less of a tax spike than would be indicated by simply adding up all the income, payroll, and penalty tax rates, but effective marginal tax rates of 85% plus for people age 65-69 or 100% plus for people age 62-64 are routinely possible. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Complexity Phase-outs worsen the complexity of the tax system. When a deduction, credit, or exemption is phased out, taxpayers have two additional administrative burdens. They must start by very carefully reading the tax instructions to learn if the phase- out might apply to them. Then, if the phase-out could affect them, they must work through the actual phase-out computations. The phase-out computations are generally not difficult, but they are tedious and come, of course, on top of all other tax calculations. In the Form 1040 Instructions for 1996, for instance, the worksheet for calculating the phase-out of the social security benefit exemption required 18 lines, the worksheet for the personal exemption's phase-out had 9 lines, and the worksheet for the phase-out of the IRA deduction took 10 lines (19 lines if there was a contribution to a nonworking spouse's IRA). Many other phase-outs did not have separate worksheets, leaving taxpayers to slog through the steps on their own. IRAs illustrate the complexity attributable to phase-outs. From 1981 to 1986, IRAs did not have a phase-out, and each worker could make yearly deductible contributions of up to $2,000, subject to a few qualifications. Contributing was a simple matter, and IRAs became hugely popular. The 1986 tax act suddenly changed that. The IRA deduction was reduced or eliminated if a taxpayer's modified AGI exceeded $25,000 ($40,000 for a couple filing jointly) and if the worker or the worker's spouse was an active participant in an employer- sponsored pension plan.\12\ With this restriction, many workers found themselves barred from making deductible IRA contributions, and many others had to perform detailed computations to ascertain if they could still contribute and, if so, how much.\13\ No longer was making a deductible IRA contribution a simple matter. Not surprisingly, IRA contributions plummeted. Although this was mostly because so many workers were now ineligible, the fact that people who remained fully eligible also reduced their contributions suggests that some workers found the new rules sufficiently confusing and intimidating that they avoided IRAs for that reason alone. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \12\ This year's tax bill raises the threshold, introduces a new type of nondeductible IRA (with its own phase-out), and makes other changes. \13\ Workers barred in some years from making deductible IRA contributions may make nondeductible contributions, but that entails still more paperwork, including an additional tax form to be filed and a greatly complicated tax situation in the future as they make withdrawals from the IRA. Withdrawals must be attributed proportionally to deductible contributions and non-deductible contributions; the former are taxable upon withdrawal, the latter are not. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- The phase-outs are probably somewhat more confusing than otherwise because there are so many different phase-out thresholds, as can be seen in Chart 1. One suggestion that has been floated for easing the compliance burden is to establish just a few phase-out thresholds, perhaps a low-income one, a middle-income one, and a high-income one. Unfortunately, while this suggestion is not without merit, coordinating phase-out thresholds would reduce complexity only slightly; the bulk of the problem would remain. A taxpayer would still have to investigate the rules governing each phase-out that might apply to him or her--the income level at which the phase-out begins is one of the rules but there are many others--and then perform all the calculations for that specific phase-out. Even worse, the bunching of phase-outs would increase the odds that taxpayers would be subject to more than one phase-out at the same time. Multiple phase-outs occurring over the same income range could create an extremely sharp spike in a taxpayer's marginal tax rate and a quantum leap up in complexity of calculations. Fairness Tax-policy debates about fairness often center on the relationship between people's tax liabilities and their incomes. What fairness really means in this context, however, has proven extraordinarily subjective and controversial. Some contend that people's tax bills should increase more rapidly than their incomes. This relationship, which is known as tax progressivity, demands, for instance, that if a person's income doubles, the amount of taxes the person pays to the government more than doubles. If one believes in progressivity, an essential follow-up question--but one that advocates of progressivity rarely address--is how much progressivity is enough. Should taxes rise slightly more rapidly than income? Should taxes rise much more rapidly? A competing standard of fairness is that people's tax bills should rise at the same rate as their incomes. With what is known as a proportional tax, if a person's income doubles, the person's tax bill also doubles. A good case can be made for a proportional system. For the most part, a person's income represents payments for labor and capital services offered to the market, and the person's income is proportional to the person's efforts and contributions to economic output. It is only fair that a person making twice the effort and generating twice the output should receive, after tax, twice the compensation, which implies a proportional tax system. The income tax system is already progressive because of its exempt amounts and ascending schedule of marginal tax rates in the various income brackets. If one believes that the current rate structure does not provide enough progressivity, the most direct and visible way to increase progressivity would be to steepen the rate schedule or to increase the standard deduction and/or personal exemption. Either method would be a clearer, simpler way to increase progressivity than phase-outs. On the other hand, suppose one believes in progressivity but thinks that the income tax is already progressive enough. In that event, the use of phase-outs to inject additional progressivity would be unfair. And if one believes that people's tax liabilities should be proportional, rising in step with their incomes, phase-outs would certainly have to be judged unfair. Although discussions of fairness in the context of tax policy often mention only the relationship between tax liabilities and income, another very important criterion of equity, surely, is according people equal treatment under the law. Specifically, if a particular deduction, exemption, or credit based on the nature of an expense is available to taxpayers in general, it is unfair to take it away from a particular group of taxpayers because of a characteristic unrelated to the rationale for the deduction, exemption, or credit. The child care credit and miscellaneous business expense deduction provide good examples. These costs of earning income are as real for high income earners as for low income earners. The true measure of income--revenue less the cost of earning the revenue--suggests that everyone should be allowed a full deduction for such expenses. Some policymakers defend the phase-out of the child credit and other phase-outs by insisting that tax policy ought to favor the poor and middle class. For example, early in 1997, President Clinton said, ``Over the last four years, we have provided tax relief to millions of working Americans and to small businesses. But I want to go further by helping middle- income Americans raise their children, send them to college, and save for the future.'' \14\ At one level this message is plausible: middle-income Americans may be overtaxed relative to the services they receive from the government.\15\ But hidden in the President's message is the very disturbing idea that tax rules should be based on what groups a policymaker wants to help or hurt, not on what rules would produce a less distortionary and less complicated tax system. For example, the phase-out of the child and education credits are a form of tax discrimination against the upper middle class and wealthy. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \14\ Budget Message Of The President in Office Of Management And Budget, The Budget Of The U.S. Government, Fiscal Year 1998 (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1997), p. 6. Although the President claimed that his tax proposals were targeted towards the middle class (he even labelled the main provisions a ``Middle Class Bill of Rights''), the actual proposals defined the middle class as ending at such low income levels that millions of households who regard themselves as solidly middle class would be excluded. The Administration, for example, recommended that the child credit begin phasing out at a modified AGI of $60,000. By any objective measure, that is hardly upper income. A two-earner couple would bump into that phase-out if each has gross wages of just $30,000. \15\ If some government services are not worth the money, the appropriate response is both to cut taxes and to rein in government spending. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- At the other end of the income scale are credits aimed at discriminating in favor of the poor. One of the largest credits subject to a phase-out is the EITC, a program of government aid to the working poor. The EITC is, in essence, a welfare program, but it differs from most welfare programs because it has the commendable feature of pegging aid to work, at least up to a certain level of income. Because one expects low-income assistance to be reserved for the poor or near poor, means testing of the EITC does not violate most people's personal standard of fairness. The EITC phase-out is still troubling on other fronts, though. It increases the EITC's complexity, and, even more damaging, it creates a powerful disincentive against additional work effort within the phase-out range. Consider a single filer with 2 eligible children, wages in 1998 of $20,000, and no other income. This worker would qualify for the EITC but be in the middle of its phase-out zone. The phase-out rate for an individual with two or more children is 21.06%. Thus, an additional dollar of wages would increase the worker's income tax by 15 cents (the person is probably in the 15% tax bracket) and reduce the credit the person can subtract from tax by approximately 21 cents. As a result, the worker would owe 36 cents more income tax on the extra dollar of income. In other words, the EITC phase-out pushes this low- income worker's marginal income tax rate from 15% to 36%. This is a powerful work disincentive. If the same worker has only one child, the EITC and its phase-out rate are both smaller. The phase-out rate is approximately 16%. In combination with the regular income tax, it produces an effective marginal income tax rate of about 31%. (To find the total marginal tax rate, one must add the payroll tax. The employee share of the payroll tax increases the worker's marginal tax rate by another 7.65%. In addition, it is generally accepted that the employer share of the payroll tax is passed on to workers, as well.) It is true that the EITC provides a powerful work incentive while it is being phased in (earnings from $0 to $12,260 in 1998), but more workers are in the phase-out range than the phase-in range.\16\ On balance, then, the EITC, which is often thought of as a spur to work effort by the working poor, may actually discourage more work than it stimulates. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- \16\ Based on author's calculations using IRS data for tax year 1994 published in Therese M. Cruciano, ``Individual Income Tax Returns, Preliminary Data, 1994,'' SOI Bulletin, Spring 1996, p. 25. --------------------------------------------------------------------------- Another fairness-based criticism of phase-outs is that although they can produce big tax increases, the rules and arithmetic are so complicated that taxpayers are often unsure of or confused about how much extra they are paying. People may legitimately object to such hidden taxes in much the same manner that they dislike having hidden charges tacked onto other bills they receive. If a private merchant adds hidden charges to bills, customers at least have the option of going to other merchants who practice more open billing. Indeed, the hidden charges may even be illegal! With tax bills from the government, unfortunately, people do not have that choice. A rising schedule of rate brackets is a much more visible method of taxing away an increasing share of people's incomes as their incomes grow than are phase-outs. Conclusion Phase-outs raise marginal tax rates and wreak havoc on economic incentives over the affected ranges of income. Although phase-outs can be extremely attractive politically because they are partially hidden and can be (mis-)touted as ``fair,'' they are very bad tax policy--distortionary, complicated, and unfair. Instead of adding more phase-outs to the tax system, the President and the Congress should be rescinding those already on the books. Ideally, all phase-outs should be swept aside in a fundamental overhaul of the tax system. Phase-outs violate several key principles to which a tax system should adhere. They needlessly damage economic incentives: taxpayers who are in the process of losing deductions, exemptions, or credits because of rising income experience higher marginal tax rates than otherwise, thereby sharpening harmful tax biases against work and saving. Phase- outs are complicated, which confuses taxpayers and adds to their paperwork costs. Further, although phase-outs are often defended vigorously because they steepen tax progressivity, the increased progressivity is actually unfair if the income tax is already sufficiently progressive or too progressive. Regardless of debates about progressivity, the arbitrariness and hidden nature of phase-outs are contrary to tax fairness. Further, phase-outs violate the concept of affording all citizens equal treatment before the law. In light of these problems, policymakers should reexamine the phase-outs now in the tax code. Most should be eliminated. New phase- outs should not be introduced. The inefficiencies and confusion introduced into the tax system by phase-outs are further evidence that fundamental overhaul and simplification of the tax system is sorely needed. When politicians are seeking to save money for the U.S. Treasury, phase-outs should be one of the last places they look, not one of the first. Michael Schuyler Senior Economist [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.181 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.182 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.183 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.184 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.185 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.186 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.187 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.188 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.189 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.190 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.191 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.192 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.193 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.194 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.195 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.196 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T0897.197 Statement of National Air Transportation Association, Alexandria, Virginia The National Air Transportation Association (NATA) represents the interests of aviation businesses nationwide. The Association's nearly 2,000 member companies provide a wide variety of aviation services, including on-demand air charter under FAR Part 135. As this Committee moves forward examining areas for tax simplification and relief, NATA on behalf of its on-demand air charter members is setting forth an initiative designed to provide a reformed and simplistic tax code for America's aviation businesses. Today, action is needed to ensure the economic competitiveness of the aviation industry is not compromised, aviation safety is enhanced, excise tax collections are simplified, and the use of fuel efficient aircraft is encouraged. Congress should implement one of the recommendations of the Congressionally-created National Civil Aviation Review Commission, that received unanimous support from its wide range of members covering every aspect of aviation, and change the method of taxation for on-demand air charter operators from the airline transportation taxes to a simple fuel tax. Under the standards of the Part 135 code, operators employ the most qualified and experienced pilots, and operate the safest, most technologically-advanced aircraft. Currently, the tax codes penalize on-demand air charter operators for the use of this certificate, lumping these operators with the world's largest airlines. Enhancing the competitiveness of the on-demand air charter industry is one of the many positive effects this change would spur. The current tax law provides a significant financial disincentive for operating under FAR Part 135, resulting in aircraft accidents by operators that operate illegally to circumvent the taxes. These illegal operations are an obvious breech to this Nation's high standard of aviation safety, and this simple tax change may be able to positively influence safe practices for all using our Nation's aviation system. The current tax code is gray, making it difficult to understand the standards between commercial on-demand air charter and non-commercial operations that often utilize the same aircraft. Shifting to the fuel tax will allow all of general aviation to operate in the same tax environment, and eliminate confusion caused by these differences. Today, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) has agents combing through the books of nearly 8000 charter operators and corporate flight departments. Moving on-demand operators from the obtrusive, labor-intensive transportation tax to a simple fuel tax will save in government paperwork and oversight. A fuel tax is also a good method of encouraging operators to utilize more fuel efficient and quieter aircraft, helping to reduce the amount of fuel burned, reducing air emissions and protecting the overall health of the environment. Moving on-demand air charter operators from the ticket tax to a fuel tax will maintain the current revenue stream that supports critical aviation programs. It also more accurately reflects revenues flowing into the Aviation Trust Fund from non-airline sources. This year thousands of on-demand air charter flights will carry passengers every day to destinations across the Nation. On-demand air charter companies provide their customers customized air transportation, staffed by highly trained pilots using aircraft scrutinized by the same standards set forth by the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) as the major airlines. These companies provide a vital link for their customers, providing them with access to over 5,000 airports across the country. Promoting safety, simplifying the tax structure, and saving taxpayer money are all important reasons to make this move, but enhancing the competitiveness of aviation companies, often small businesses, is truly a positive change. Together we can continue to promote American small businesses, encourage growth and supporting good business practices, while maintaining the current high standard of safety. Thank you for the opportunity to set forth this critical initiative. NATA looks forward to working with Congress and this great Committee to move forward these ideas. Together, we can improve upon America's great air transportation system. Statement of Clark S. Willingham, President-Elect, National Cattlemen's Beef Association Chairman Archer, Ranking Member Rangel, Members of the Committee: On behalf of the National Cattlemen's Beef Association (NCBA) and our 230,00 members from all segments of beef production, thank you for your interest in reducing the death tax burden on hard-working American families. I appreciate the opportunity to share with you the devastating effect death taxes have on the ability of cattlemen and women to pass their family businesses on to the next generation. Death is a lousy event to tax. For the past several Congresses, relieving the death tax burden has been a top priority for NCBA. We commend the Committee's hard work this past year in making significant progress toward the ultimate goal of eliminating death taxes from the federal tax code. Through our own resources and as a member of the Family Business Estate Tax Coalition, we are committed to working with you and the Committee to achieve additional progress. As evidenced by this hearing and the statements of Members of the Committee, it is clear that reform of death taxes remains a top priority in Congress. From the cattle industry's perspective, the death tax is the primary obstacle in keeping our family-owned businesses intact and viable during the transition from one generation to the next. Nearly one-half of our members have been in business more than 50 years and 15% of our members have operated their family business for more than 100 years. These are the folks who for generations have contributed to the economy of the local communities, who are the foundation of an industry that represents 20 percent of the U.S. agricultural gross domestic product and which annually generates over $150 billion in local and national economic activity. Add to this high level of economic activity the public monies generated, such as fuel taxes, excise taxes, income taxes and related revenues, and one must question the wisdom of a federal policy that effectively erodes the base of the rural economy. Death is a certainty for each of us. Unfortunately, it also unleashes the IRS, which can take up to 55% of a business and its assets before the next generation has the opportunity to carry on the family tradition. Statistics indicate the average age of a cattleman is 55 years, which suggests there currently are a lot of ranch families who will soon face the burden of federal estate taxation. Statistics also indicate that the number of cattle operations has declined 20 percent since 1981, a trend that many feel is accelerated by the burden death taxes pose on surviving family members. NCBA feels this burden has contributed to families selling their family farming and ranching enterprises in anticipation of the death tax. In addition, many of our members report that their efforts to plan for the impact of estate taxes has led to management decisions that are not always in the best interests of operating a profitable enterprise. We also believe, in addition to enhancing the well-being of the beef industry, that estate tax reform will provide society in general with environmental benefits. Any business that is successful over a long period of time is one in which the principals pay close attention to the maintenance, up-keep and improvement of the production facility. For cattlemen, their production facility is the land--land that they and their ancestors have nurtured to ensure its ability to support their beef herds, and land that they share with a natural ecosystem that includes wildlife habitat, watersheds, riparian areas, and so forth. Unfortunately, a cattle operation is a capital intensive enterprise typified by having most of its assets invested in the land or cattle. In the event of the death of a principal family member, the sale of the land and/or cattle becomes the primary source of funds available to meet the costs of death taxes. When this occurs, ranches or farms get split up, particularly in areas of aggressive urban/suburban growth and escalating land values. The net result is that land that once provided nutritious beef or other staples for our diets and habitat for Mother Nature's flora and fauna is instead used to grow houses, shopping malls, and roads. Taxing capital at death is frustrating when one considers that the money used to buy, maintain and improve these assets was taxed when earned. Adding to the insult are the estate tax rates which can impose a top rate of 55 percent--which is especially troubling when compared to the top capital gains tax rate for individuals of 20 percent. Obviously, NCBA's favored position is outright repeal of death taxes. But if repeal is not likely, we strongly support efforts to further reform the estate tax code, whether it be through lower rates, increased exemptions or exclusions, or some combination thereof. During several hearings on death taxes this past year, William W. Beach, Senior Fellow in Economics at the Heritage Foundation, repeatedly stated that the costs of compliance and lost economic activity due to the estate tax far exceed the revenues gained by the federal government. Professor Richard Wagner of George Mason University projects that over an eight- year period, elimination of death taxes would add 250,000 jobs and pump $80 billion in annual economic growth to the nation's output. It is our hope that this kind of information can be taken into account by budget analysts and provide you the resources necessary to include additional death tax reforms in any tax legislation you may consider this year. I mentioned that NCBA is a member of the Family Business Estate Tax Coalition, a large group made up of trade associations and organizations who represent the vast majority of this nation's family owned enterprises. This group worked in a bipartisan fashion throughout 1997 to build the case on the negative impact that the estate tax places on family businesses. The message of the Coalition is simple, and perhaps redundant, but it needs to be repeated. Liquidity is the fundamental characteristic that distinguishes the estates of family owned businesses from those of individuals holding marketable securities and/or other liquid assets. Publicly traded stock can be sold to pay the death tax, doing little harm to capital investments that are critical to the productivity of the business and the overall financial well-being of a company. But a family owned business, whether it's a ranching operation or a restaurant, must sell critical assets--and often the business itself must be sold--to pay death taxes, or suffer under the resultant debt load necessary to continue in business. Our campaign to reform/repeal the death tax is about jobs, economic growth and the financial stability of this nation's many small and medium sized communities. On behalf of the NCBA, we thank you and your colleagues for holding this hearing. We encourage you to move boldly in your efforts to provide additional relief from the death tax burden. We recognize the constraints placed on reforms by the budget and want to work with you to maximize the benefits for those who are most impacted. Thank you for your leadership on this important issue, and for the opportunity to provide this statement to the Committee. Statement of Bruce Hagen, Commissioner, North Dakota Public Service Commission Thank you for the opportunity to comment for the record on reducing the tax burden. I believe Congress should make every effort to first reduce the national debt before taxes are reduced. As I understand it, it is now over $5 trillion. Any change in the tax laws should give those people who have especially benefited from our system in the last years the opportunity to help pay for our country's debt. The national debt climbed from about $900 billion in 1980 to over $4 trillion by the end of 1992. Since the beginning of 1993, the rate of increase in the national debt has dramatically come down. Congress should try to continue this downward trend. When the Federal Government stops borrowing money to operate our government, it means interest rates normally drop and this benefits those folks who have to borrow money for home mortgages, farm expenses, cars, business, manufacturing--the entire economy. I believe the American people expect that we should start paying our debts and that we should do so on a consistent basis. A sensible tax system that's fair to all and doesn't favor the rich, who have certainly benefited in the last 20 years in our economic system, should always be a goal of this democracy. A modern democratic civilization such as the United States must have a fair tax system. Our tax system could be improved. For example, Congress uses the money that working people pay into Social Security to help balance the annual budget of the United States. Congress should not use Social Security funds to help balance the annual government budget. Thank you again for the opportunity to comment. Statement of White House Conference on Small Business The undersigned are the elected Regional Taxation Chairs representing the 2000 delegates to the last White House Conference on Small Business. We were delegated the responsibility for advancing implementation of the conference's recommendations with regard to the tax issues and reporting progress back to the delegates. As you prepare to consider tax policy issues again in the second session, the delegates to the White House Conference on Small Business want to remind you of the important tax issues for the growth and progress of small businesses in America. One of the strongest recommendations of the White House Conference on Small Business was a call for the repeal of the estate and gift tax. The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 included a provision which effectively excludes the first $1.3 billion of an estate where a qualifying small business constitutes over half of the gross estate. While this is welcome relief, more needs to be done to protect businesses from being dismantled at the death of the principal. The passage of a small business from one generation to the next has a positive impact on the community, promoting stable employment, long-term community support through community groups, and an active interest in maintaining the quality of education and life in the ``neighborhood.'' If outright repeal is too costly under the budget requirements, the tax issue chairs feel that proposals which provide for continued reduction of the tax and the administrative burden on small businesses would be helpful. By focusing the legislation, Congress can provide relief directly to farms and small family businesses while foregoing a relatively small amount of revenue. The Congress should adopt a tax policy moves the country toward the positive goal of sustaining the economic vitality of a small business and away from a policy which requires expensive and complex estate plans and insurance. The reality today is that elaborate and costly estate plans must be undertaken which drains assets from productive business investment. Without such plans, there is no guarantee that the business will last to serve the next generation of owners or workers. In general, the White House Conference urged Congress to investigate a simpler, fairer tax system but purposely did not specify what changes should be made. We would like to recommend that any changes that are considered be analyzed for their impact on small businesses and that representatives of the small business community be included in any hearings on the subject. We would be happy to work with you, your colleagues and your staff to help you better understand the importance of these proposals to small businesses and the U.S. economy. Thank you for your time and attention to this matter. Sincerely, Region 1 Debbi Jo Horton, Providence, Rhode Island Region 2 Joy Turner, Piscataway, New Jersey Region 3 Jill Gansler, Baltimore, Maryland Region 4 Jack Oppenheimer, Orlando, Florida Region 5 Paul Hense, Grand Rapids, Michigan Region 6 Joanne Dougherty, Houston, Texas Region 7 Edith Quick, St. Louis, Missouri Region 8 Jim Turner, Salt Lake City, Utah Region 9 Sandra Abalos, Phoenix, Arizona Region 10 Eric Blackledge, Corvallis, Oregon -