[Senate Hearing 108-604] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] S. Hrg. 108-604 CRUDE OIL: THE SOURCE OF HIGHER GAS PRICES? ======================================================================= HEARING before the SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST, COMPETITION POLICY AND CONSUMER RIGHTS of the COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE ONE HUNDRED EIGHTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION __________ APRIL 7, 2004 __________ Serial No. J-108-65 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on the Judiciary U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 95-551 WASHINGTON : DC ____________________________________________________________________________ For Sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; (202) 512�091800 Fax: (202) 512�092250 Mail: Stop SSOP, Washington, DC 20402�090001 COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY ORRIN G. HATCH, Utah, Chairman CHARLES E. GRASSLEY, Iowa PATRICK J. LEAHY, Vermont ARLEN SPECTER, Pennsylvania EDWARD M. KENNEDY, Massachusetts JON KYL, Arizona JOSEPH R. BIDEN, Jr., Delaware MIKE DeWINE, Ohio HERBERT KOHL, Wisconsin JEFF SESSIONS, Alabama DIANNE FEINSTEIN, California LINDSEY O. GRAHAM, South Carolina RUSSELL D. FEINGOLD, Wisconsin LARRY E. CRAIG, Idaho CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York SAXBY CHAMBLISS, Georgia RICHARD J. DURBIN, Illinois JOHN CORNYN, Texas JOHN EDWARDS, North Carolina Bruce Artim, Chief Counsel and Staff Director Bruce A. Cohen, Democratic Chief Counsel and Staff Director ------ Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights MIKE DeWINE, Ohio, Chairman ORRIN G. HATCH, Utah HERBERT KOHL, Wisconsin ARLEN SPECTER, Pennsylvania PATRICK J. LEAHY, Vermont LINDSEY O. GRAHAM, South Carolina RUSSELL D. FEINGOLD, Wisconsin SAXBY CHAMBLISS, Georgia JOHN EDWARDS, North Carolina Peter Levitas, Majority Chief Counsel and Staff Director Jeffrey Miller, Democratic Chief Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- STATEMENTS OF COMMITTEE MEMBERS Page Craig, Hon. Larry E., a U.S. Senator from the State of Idaho..... 9 DeWine, Hon. Mike, a U.S. Senator from the State of Ohio......... 1 prepared statement........................................... 118 Feingold, Hon. Russell D., a U.S. Senator from the State of Wisconsin, prepared statement.................................. 121 Kohl, Hon. Herbert, a U.S. Senator from the State of Wisconsin... 3 prepared statement........................................... 138 Leahy, Hon. Patrick J., a U.S. Senator from the State of Vermont. 6 prepared statement........................................... 169 Schumer, Hon. Charles E., a U.S. Senator from the State of New York........................................................... 7 Specter, Hon. Arlen, a U.S. Senator from the State of Pennsylvania................................................... 5 WITNESSES Bermann, George A., Walter Gelhorn Professor of Law and Jean Monnet Professor of European Union Law, Columbia University School of Law, New York, New York.............................. 20 Cooper, Mark, Director of Research, Consumer Federation of America on behalf of Consumer Federation of America and Consumers Union, Washington, D.C............................... 21 Felmy, John, Chief Economist and Director of Policy Analysis and Statistics, American Petroleum Institute, Washington, D.C...... 16 Hastings, Justine S., Assistant Professor of Economics, Yale University, prepared statement................................. 18 Kovacic, William E., General Counsel, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., prepared statement........................... 14 Wyden, Hon. Ron, a U.S. Senator from the State of Oregon......... 10 QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS Responses of George Bermann to questions submitted by Senators DeWine, Kohl, and Craig........................................ 40 Responses of Mark Cooper to questions submitted by Senators Craig and Leahy...................................................... 43 Responses of John Felmy to questions submitted by Senators DeWine, Leahy, Kohl, and Craig................................. 45 Responses of Justine Hastings to questions submitted by Senators DeWine, Kohl, Leahy, and Craig................................. 50 Responses of William Kovacic to questions submitted by Senators Kohl, Leahy, DeWine, and Craig................................. 58 SUBMISSIONS FOR THE RECORD Bermann, George A., Walter Gelhorn Professor of Law and Jean Monnet Professor of European Union Law, Columbia University School of Law, New York, New York.............................. 84 Bingaman, Jeff, Ranking Member, letter to President, March 24, 2004........................................................... 87 Cicio, Paul N., Executive Director, Industrial Energy Consumers of America, Washington, D.C., prepared statement............... 95 Cooper, Mark, Director of Research, Consumer Federation of America on behalf of Consumer Federation of America and Consumers Union, Washington, D.C., prepared statement.......... 101 Felmy, John, Chief Economist and Director of Policy Analysis and Statistics, American Petroleum Institute, Washington, D.C., prepared statement............................................. 123 Hastings, Justine S., Assistant Professor of Economics, Yale University, prepared statement................................. 129 Kovacic, William E., General Counsel, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., prepared statement........................... 140 Sloan, James B., Antitrust Attorney, Chicago, Illinois, statement 172 CRUDE OIL: THE SOURCE OF HIGHER GAS PRICES? ---------- WEDNESDAY, APRIL 7, 2004 United States Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights, Committee on the Judiciary, Washington, DC. The Subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 2:53 p.m., in room SD-226, Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Mike DeWine, Chairman of the Subcommittee, presiding. Present: Senators DeWine, Specter, Craig, Kohl, Leahy, and Schumer. OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. MIKE DEWINE, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF OHIO Chairman DeWine. Good afternoon. Let me welcome all of you to the Antitrust Subcommittee hearing on the causes of higher gas prices in the United States. As most Americans know, we are in the middle of another round of painful increases in gasoline prices. The national average has reached a new record high for self-serve unleaded gas, and that is about $1.80 per gallon. Recently, in my home State of Ohio, gas prices have been even higher. In Marietta, Ohio, for example, gas was $1.84 per gallon recently. In Cleveland, it was $1.86, and in Columbus it topped out at $1.88 at some stations. Many analysts predict that prices could break the important psychological barrier of $2.00 per gallon this summer. Although the prices this time around seem particularly high, the American consumer has unfortunately been here before. Since the 1970's, when we first experienced the so-called oil shocks, periodic price spikes seem to have become as predictable as the seasons changing. Though these spikes no longer surprise us, they continue to harm consumers, weaken the economy and leave us with an important question: What, if anything, should lawmakers be doing to address this recurring problem? Today, we hope to address that question in a setting where we can explore the reasons for high-price gasoline and consider possible policy steps. We do have excellent panelists and we will hear from a number of experts who will offer their perspectives on the root causes for higher gasoline prices. But I want to stress one thing upon which I think there will be universal agreement. The single most important factor affecting gas prices in the United States is the price of crude oil. We have a chart over there which indicates that. As we can see from our chart, as of March 2004, crude oil is the largest single component of the gasoline price, making up nearly half of the overall price that consumers pay at the pump. Beyond that, the Federal Trade Commission has said that changes in crude oil prices account for approximately 85 percent of the variability of gasoline prices. In other words, the changes in crude oil prices lead directly to the gasoline price spikes that cause so much economic distress. Of U.S. imported crude oil, more than 40 percent comes from OPEC member nations. Last week, OPEC met in Austria and decided to cut production by 4 percent, down about 1 million barrels to 23.5 million barrels per day. The price of a barrel of oil is already very high, between $35 to $38 per barrel. And according to some analysts, the price is likely to break the $40-per- barrel ceiling. Of course, OPEC's decision to decrease supply likely will increase U.S. gasoline prices further, causing American consumers to suffer more. That is why last week Senator Kohl and I reintroduced our No Oil Producing and Exporting Cartels Act of 2004, or our NOPEC bill. The purpose of the bill is to end OPEC's flagrant violation of our antitrust laws. This is hard-core cartel behavior and should not be tolerated. If OPEC were a group of international oil companies getting together to set prices and cut output, it could be prosecuted under U.S. antitrust laws. But to this day, OPEC continues to receive special treatment under U.S. antitrust law. Our bill would remove the legal obstacles that have protected OPEC until now and gives our antitrust enforcement agencies the tools they need to prosecute OPEC. First, NOPEC, this bill, responds to a 1979 Federal district court opinion that found that OPEC's activities were, and I quote, ``governmental,'' not ``commercial,'' and therefore protected from prosecution under the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act. Second, our bill responds to a 1981 Federal court of appeals decision where the court refused to hear that same case against OPEC based on the so-called ``act of state doctrine,'' which states that a court will not judge the legality of the sovereign acts of a foreign country. Finally, our bill gives the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission explicit authority to prosecute OPEC. In short, our bill says to OPEC, no more special treatment under U.S. antitrust law. One of our expert witnesses today will offer his legal analysis of our proposed law and we look forward to his testimony. We are going to try to move the NOPEC bill and are hopeful that if it becomes law, it will help restore market discipline to crude oil prices. But even if we do manage to get crude oil prices back in line with the laws of supply and demand, there is a range of other factors that affect gasoline prices, and we will consider those today as well. For example, the proliferation of specialty gases creates a particularly complex part of the supply problem, as our chart over there indicates, as well. In the United States, as we can see from this chart, a number of State and local governments have different gasoline grades that they use to achieve EPA mandates for cleaner air. There are currently 18 different grades sold in the United States. This creates two supply problems. First, it reduces the availability of substitutes to cushion supply and price shocks. Second, it makes importing gas harder because many foreign refiners do not provide non- conventional gas grades. Refining capacity is another part of the gasoline supply problem and a number of people believe it is the key problem we are facing today. There are about 145 refineries currently operating in the United States. In the last 15 to 20 years, no new refineries have been built and about 75 have been closed. Although the efficiency of the remaining refineries has been improved, refinery capacity is still strained. In fact, refinery capacity utilization rates are running at about 90 to 95 percent today. This leaves the system with very little margin for error, because a fire or other accident that temporarily shuts down a refinery cannot be easily accommodated by increased output from another refinery. Even worse, there is no solution on the horizon. Despite the high demand for gasoline, refiners are unwilling to build new refineries because of cost, environmental issues and expected local opposition. Another controversial aspect of the gasoline pricing problem is the issue of concentration within the refining industry. Those who have followed the work of this Subcommittee are well aware of the merger wave that rolled through the U.S. economy in the 1990's. That wave engulfed the petroleum industry as well. Mergers such as Exxon-Mobil, BP-Amoco and Conoco-Phillips clearly increased concentration levels both upstream, in exploration and production, and downstream, in refining and retailing. Now, whether or not this concentration has reached a level high enough to raise competition concerns is a matter of some dispute. For example, in 1983 the top five refiners controlled approximately 35 percent of the U.S. domestic refining market. In 2003, that number increased to over 50 percent. From a pure antitrust merger analysis point of view, I question whether these concentration levels are high enough to merit serious concern, but we will consider this issue during the course of today's hearing. In addition, we will examine a number of other secondary factors contributing to the recent increase in gas prices, such as strong growth in the U.S. and China's demand for oil. Finally, we will touch today on the state of competition in the market for natural gas, which is also selling at prices approaching historic highs. Let me now turn to my friend and colleague, the Ranking Member of the Subcommittee, Senator Kohl. STATEMENT OF HON. HERB KOHL, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF WISCONSIN Senator Kohl. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, we are reminded everyday when we drive by a gas station that Americans are paying record levels for a gallon of gas. Gas prices now average $1.78 a gallon nationally and $1.80 in my State of Wisconsin. Prices over $2.00 a gallon are now common throughout our country. These rising gas prices are felt throughout the economy. They are a silent tax that takes hard-earned money away from Americans every time they visit the gas pump. Higher gas prices drive up the cost of transportation, harming every sector of the economy from aviation to trucking. Those costs are passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices for manufactured goods. Higher oil prices also mean higher heating and electricity costs. So let's examine the cause of these rising prices. First, we need to look at the price of crude oil. Indeed, the FTC states that 85 percent of the variability in the cost of gasoline can be accounted for by the price of crude oil. Simply put, the cost of crude oil moves the price of a gallon of gas. And as we all know, OPEC sets the price of oil. OPEC's actions to manipulate the oil market cost Americans billions of dollars every year. If the members of OPEC were private companies and not nations, they long ago would have been prosecuted for engaging in illegal price-fixing. The bill that Senator DeWine and I introduced last week, and which passed the Judiciary Committee unanimously in 2000, would end this injustice by subjecting OPEC to antitrust suits in U.S. courts. While NOPEC is not a panacea, a lawsuit or threat of a lawsuit will give our Government the first real weapon it has ever had to deter OPEC from its seemingly endless cycle of price increases. But restraining OPEC is not the entire answer. There are other factors that lead to higher gas prices. In the face of ever-increasing demand and higher prices, the domestic oil industry has not responded as we would have expected by increasing refinery capacity. Instead, numerous refineries have been closed--about 75 over the past 15 years--and none have been opened for many years, but it must also be said that existing refineries have also increased their capacity. Refinery capacity, now operating at 95 percent, has become a bottleneck, limiting supply and causing price spikes whenever an accident occurs. Indeed, critics argue that oil companies have chosen not to expand refining capacity in order to gain market power in order to keep prices high. While there are clearly barriers to expanding refinery capacity, at the same time the antitrust authorities must not permit oil companies with market power to deliberately withhold supply to raise prices. In addition, mergers in the oil industry have left a dangerous level of consolidation in their wake. The oil companies not only drill the oil, but they also refine it and they also own the gas pumps as well. The five largest oil companies now control more than half of our domestic refining capacity and more than 60 percent of the national retail gasoline market. This level of concentration, magnified in some areas, permits just a few competitors to control prices. Just as importantly, this consolidation has virtually eliminated independent retailers and refiners and the competition that they provide. Where there has been a high degree of integration between refiners and retailers, consumers pay higher prices. For the last 4 years, Senator DeWine and I have repeatedly called upon the FTC to study the cause for high prices. The FTC should remain vigilant in monitoring gas price increases, but it must do more. Antitrust authorities must scrutinize future oil industry mergers with a keen eye toward preserving the competitive benefits of independent retailers and refiners. So, Mr. Chairman, it is time for action to end the ever- escalating pattern of gas price increases that are regularly inflicted on our Nation's consumers. Our NOPEC bill is one place to start, but we must also do more to ensure that the conditions exist to lower gas prices for all Americans. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman DeWine. Senator Kohl, thank you very much. Senator Specter. STATEMENT OF HON. ARLEN SPECTER, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF PENNSYLVANIA Senator Specter. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. At the outset, Mr. Chairman, I thank you for convening this very timely hearing. There is no doubt that the actions by OPEC are drastically increasing the cost of gasoline and oil in the United States. On February 10, OPEC curtailed oil production by 1.5 million barrels a day, and then on March 31 an additional 1 million barrels a day. Oil has now reached the staggering price of $38 a barrel, which is the highest it has been since the Gulf War, in 1991. I believe that our Department of Justice and our Federal Trade Commission have been lax in not acting against the clear- cut violation of U.S. law, conspiracy and restraint of trade, which is clear-cut on what OPEC has been doing for years. I have studied this issue in some detail, and on April 11, 1998, I wrote to President Clinton outlining a course of action for lawsuits to hold OPEC responsible. I wrote the same letter to President Bush on April 25, 2001. Mr. Chairman, I would ask unanimous consent that both of those letters be made a part of the record. Chairman DeWine. Without objection, they will be made part of the record. Senator Specter. The essential points which I made in these letters--they really are, in effect, a legal brief--are that a suit in Federal court would be appropriate under U.S. antitrust laws, and there is not immunity under act of state or sovereign immunity. When they are engaged in a commercial transaction, there is no doubt they are subject to the antitrust laws. There has been an evolving recognition of international law that they are bound by the antitrust laws, which was a possible defense early in the interpretation of the antitrust laws. The letter which I sent to President Clinton was cosigned by you, Mr. Chairman; the ranking member, Senator Kohl; Senator Thurmond; Senator Schumer; and Senator Biden. It is high time that that action was taken. I believe the action can be taken under existing law, but I do believe, Mr. Chairman, that the legislation which you have reintroduced, Senate bill 2270, is a very good bill. It removes it from a common law interpretation so that there is specific legislation which provides that sovereign immunity does not bar an action or that the act of state does not bar an action. So it is really time to get on with it, and the American people are clamoring for relief. It is just really outrageous that we are being gouged by OPEC at the gas pump. We have had a very heavy winter. We are now about to provide for LIHEAP, low- income energy assistance, $2 billion-plus. It is high time we focused on the fact that the Saudis are not our friends on so many lines. On terrorism, which they are sponsoring under the guise of helping charitable organizations, 15 of the hijackers on 9/11 were from Saudi Arabia. And they are continuing to gouge the American consumers and it is time we acted to stop them. So I hope this hearing will provide an impetus to do just that. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman DeWine. Senator Leahy. STATEMENT OF HON. PATRICK J. LEAHY, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF VERMONT Senator Leahy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am going to be home this weekend and when I go to the gasoline pump and I am pumping gasoline in my car, my neighbors in Middlesex, Vermont, are going to say, Pat, what is going on? Why are we paying so much? If we have a Vermont farm, why are our profit margins, which are historically thin anyway, being cut out entirely by this? Frankly, I have to say that not enough is being done by our Government or by others to cut down the price of fuel. I hope that today's hearing tells both the administration and foreign governments that the American people and the Congress demand that we use the tools we have available to keep gasoline prices affordable. I feel as one Vermonter that if we don't have enough legal tools, then let's find some more and pass those. We know, and most Americans do, why high prices are at the pump. The OPEC cartel sets production quotas for member countries and prevents the free market from setting crude oil prices. I agree very much with the Senator from Pennsylvania when he says we ought to realize that the Saudis are not the great friends that they say they are. I think they have demonstrated that in one thing after another. As of April 5, the U.S. Department of Energy reports the nationwide average price of a gallon of gasoline is $1.78. Now, on this chart, just to give you an idea, that is an increase of $.60 since the year 2001. Some are saying it may go up to $3.00 this summer. That is going to be like what we saw in real dollars during the shortages of the early 1980's. And that seems likely, since OPEC met on March 31 and they decided to cut the output of oil even further, not only cutting it by a million barrels a day, but they wanted to increase that. A Nigerian petroleum advisory says that they are considering raising prices $3.00 a barrel. That is going to increase costs to consumers, small businesses and, in my State, the dairy industry, among others. Vermont dairies are experiencing 40-percent higher fuel prices. In a normal time, we ask the famous question ``Got milk?'' Today, we ask ``Got enough money for gas?'' To give you an idea, in a typical dairy operation in the Northeast it adds $5,000 to their costs. This shouldn't be falling on all of us. I think Senator DeWine and Senator Kohl deserve thanks for their leadership on the NOPEC bill. It is obvious that we are not going to get help otherwise to deal with the gas crisis that is a threat to our families, our farmers, our truck drivers. If the administration can't say no OPEC, then we ought to try to do it. OPEC has tried to dismiss criticism about the high price of gasoline through disingenuous arguments. Actually, the consumption of oil has remained relatively level over the past few years, and nobody could say with a straight face that a 60- percent increase per gallon in price is because of tough environmental rules by the Bush administration. Give me a break. This is not right. In fact, there is a letter by Senator Bingaman to the President, and I would ask that that be made part of the record. I am glad to see this hearing. I wrote to Senator Hatch urging such a hearing a couple of weeks ago. I have praised both Senator DeWine and Senator Kohl so many times in these hearings that I am afraid it may hurt them back home, but I just want to praise you two one more time. This is an important hearing. I will put the rest of the statement in the record. [The prepared statement of Senator Leahy appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Thank you very much. Senator Schumer. STATEMENT OF HON. CHARLES E. SCHUMER, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF NEW YORK Senator Schumer. I want to thank you, Mr. Chairman, for holding this hearing. I want to thank you and Senator Kohl for being leaders on this issue, as you are on so many other antitrust issues. I want to thank our witnesses today, as well, and appreciate the opportunity to talk about natural gas as well as oil, although obviously I want to talk about both. Let me say, Mr. Chairman, that I believe that the Federal Government has an obligation to take decisive, aggressive and immediate action to curtail energy price spikes and make sure that energy costs stop creating hardships for working families throughout the United States. I am sure everyone here is familiar with the legend of the Bermuda Triangle, where planes and ships mysteriously disappear and are never heard from again. Well, over the past few months, American consumers feel like the same thing has happened to their energy dollar. But this triangle is the Saudi triangle, composed of OPEC, big oil companies and a lack of action by the administration to stem the tide of increasing prices. At one point in this triangle we have OPEC, which just last week announced its continued commitment to reducing production by a million barrels a day, despite the fact that crude oil was already approaching record prices. The decision is motivated purely by greed and a desire to bolster budgets and increase profits for OPEC's largest producers, like Saudi Arabia, by taking money out of the wallets of average American families. There are also indications that more OPEC action to pinch us at the pump may be on the way. They have sort out thrown out the window the $28 ceiling and they are now maximizing their profitability because basically no one is stopping them and they have been getting a green light. At the second point in the triangle is the trend of consolidation in the oil industry. Over the past 5 years, mergers between the biggest players in the market and increasing vertical integration have made consumers more vulnerable to exploitation at the pump. Currently, the top five oil companies in the U.S. control 14 percent of global production--almost as much as the Middle Eastern members of OPEC--over half of domestic refiner capacity and 60 percent of the retail gasoline market. This lack of competition has made the oil and gasoline markets vulnerable to market manipulation through the withholding of supply and other means, leading to longer, increasingly frequent price spikes and weakening any downward pressure on prices that exists in healthy and competitive markets. To make matters worse, these highly concentrated companies are sometimes directly tied to OPEC producers, as in the case of Motiva, a 50-50 venture between Shell and Saudi Aramco. The companies do nothing but benefit from high prices by reaping windfall profits and creating a win-win scenario for big oil at the expense of the American consumer. As prices go up and as OPEC raises prices, oil company profitability goes up. So they are on board for the ride. At the third point of the triangle, I regret to say, Mr. Chairman, lies the administration, which has a ``hear no evil, see no evil, do no evil'' attitude. They have not taken any aggressive action to provide needed relief to the American driver. It is bad enough that it hasn't happened so far, but if they don't do anything soon, gas prices are going to be sky- high as we go into the summer months. OPEC's ability to brazenly raise prices and fill its coffers is in part as a result of the administration's inability to engage and influence oil-producing nations to cooperate with U.S. needs and as a consequence of hostility that the administration's foreign policy has engendered toward America throughout the world. The President says he is close to the Saudi royal family, but time and time again when dealing with the Saudis, it is America that gets the short end of the stick. They tolerate Wahabbi extremists who preach hate and terror against the U.S., they refuse to allow our law enforcement the access it needs to investigate crimes, and now they are holding us hostage to high gas prices. What Uncle Sam gave us with the tax cuts, the $400 rebate every family got, he is now allowing the Saudis to take away with exorbitant prices at the pump. The President has the power to weigh in against the Saudis, but he is not using it. It is time he did. So we have this new Bermuda triangle--OPEC, consolidated big oil and a do-nothing policy from the administration. Let me say we have some weapons. First, we should stop adding 100,000 barrels of oil a day to the SPR. A majority of Senators voted for that amendment. The administration has also missed an opportunity to prevent gasoline price spikes by failing to approve oxygenate waiver requests from States like New York and California, which are being forced to use ethanol this summer, raising prices. Most importantly, they refuse to use the SPR as our ace in the hole against the Saudis and against big oil and bring prices down. As you know, Mr. Chairman, I have been advocating this for a long time. It took me about a year to get the Clinton administration to use it. When they did, prices went down; they stayed down. And the amount of oil in the SPR went up because the swap enabled us to get more oil for what we put into the market several months later. So we need a long-term solution--that is not what we are here to talk about today--that involves both new exploration and conservation. But we need a short-term solution, lest our economy go down the drain. I hope that we can break the influence of this triangle, get to work and do something good to reduce prices. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman DeWine. Senator Craig. STATEMENT OF HON. LARRY CRAIG, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF IDAHO Senator Craig. Well, Mr. Chairman, I largely came to listen today to our colleagues, and certainly to those who are experts in this field. All of us are concerned about high prices at the pump, but why should we be surprised? This Congress has refused to act in any progressive manner to increase production in this country for the last decade. So the blame game is now underway and we will hold hearings, as we should. At the same time, a decade and 39 States' investigations have not yet pointed to effective wrongdoing on the part of any producer in large part. What we have is a dysfunctional market today because we no longer control our destiny. We can bite around the edges, if we wish to, and we will, and we will try to find someone else to accuse. I have given in the last two weeks three speeches on the floor of the U.S. Senate on this issue. I am certainly no expert in it, but I have studied it closely as a member of the Energy Committee for the last 7 years. The problem is the U.S. Congress today, and the consumers of America ought to know it. We are no longer allowing this Nation to produce in any and every way we should. We should be encouraging the production of domestic oil, we should be encouraging the development of natural gas, we should be encouraging the building of necessary infrastructure like the Alaska natural gas pipeline, we should be encouraging the use of renewable fuels like ethanol, we should be encouraging more renewable energy. We should be encouraging the construction of new nuclear plants, clean coal technology, new hydrogen production, promoting energy efficiency and increasing the R and D on a variety of technologies. The Senator from New York and I differ a little, but at the same time there are many things on this issue we tend to agree on. The manipulation of SPR during the Clinton years effectively changed the price at the pump by one cent. Those are the facts on the books. So I am here to listen. It is obvious I have strong opinions on this issue. I think the consumers are gaining strong opinions on this issue, as they should. I hope they reflect on Congress' unwillingness or inability to act on this issue in any progressive and comprehensive form for well over a decade. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman DeWine. We will turn now to our colleague and friend, Senator Ron Wyden. STATEMENT OF HON. RON WYDEN, A U.S. SENATOR FROM THE STATE OF OREGON Senator Wyden. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I very much appreciate your giving me the chance to come. I would ask, with your indulgence, if my full remarks could be made part of the record. Chairman DeWine. They will certainly be made part of the record. Senator Wyden. I thank you. First, it is obvious if you want to get anything important done in this town, it has got to be bipartisan, and I congratulate you and Senator Kohl for doing that. That is what it is going to take to really make some changes in this area. And that is what the public is asking. The public is saying, are you all in Washington going to do anything or are you just going to talk about it? What I would like to do is just outline briefly what I think would be an effective bipartisan package in this area. Let me start by saying that I think the gasoline consumer is about to be hit by a perfect storm, and there are really three factors behind this storm that is coming. The first is what we have all talked about today, the OPEC shenanigans. The second involves refinery cutbacks, and the third involves the Federal Trade Commission sitting on its hands in the face of documented anticompetitive practices. I would just say, Mr. Chairman, that I think if we took your bill which deals with OPEC and my legislation, which is S. 1737, the Gasoline Free Market Competition Act, we could systemically tackle those three factors that come together to create what I call the perfect storm. First, with respect to OPEC, put me down as a cosponsor of your legislation. Chairman DeWine. We will add your name. We appreciate it. Thank you. Senator Wyden. Look, I have been saying all week OPEC stands up for OPEC. Anybody who thinks OPEC stands up for the American consumer thinks Colonel Sanders stands up for the chickens. I mean, it is just a preposterous idea that OPEC is going to do anything for the consumer. So I am very glad that you and Senator Kohl have teamed up in that area, and I want to be a cosponsor of your legislation. But I think we ought to be clear, and the Consumer Federation has offered an interesting report in this area that, for example, oil company refinery margins are taking an even bigger bite out of the consumer's pocket, as is the OPEC cartel. That is why I would very much like to merge my bill with the fine bill that you and Senator Kohl have because while taking action against OPEC will be very constructive, it won't provide full relief if Congress looks the other way when it comes to anticompetitive practices right here in our markets here at home. So just as you, Chairman DeWine and Senator Kohl, seek to provide new tools with respect to dealing with OPEC, that is what I am seeking to do with respect to making sure we have competition in our markets in this country. And to illustrate the need for my bill, I would like to talk about what is going on in Bakersfield, California, right now with the refinery cutbacks because I think it provides a textbook case of how these anticompetitive practices are perpetrated in our country. Obviously, when you ask about what is going on on the West Coast, they are saying what does that mean for us in Ohio and Wisconsin and other parts of the country? But what I offer up is inaction by the Federal Trade Commission on the growing problem of refinery shutdowns, which is clobbering my constituents now and is going to hurt people all over this country. What has happened in Bakersfield exemplifies how these refinery shutdowns are going to hurt people across the Nation. Suffice it to say there were 24 refineries that closed between 1995 and 2001. So you are talking about a combined capacity of more than 800,000 barrels per day, including many on the West Coast of the United States. I got involved in this issue with respect to refinery cutbacks, Mr. Chairman and colleagues, in 2001 when we came upon some internal oil company memos involving the closed Powerine refinery in southern California. One of the company documents then revealed that if the Powerine refinery was restarted, the additional gasoline supply on the market could bring down gas prices by two to three cents a gallon. And it called for, and I quote, ``a full-court press to keep the refinery down.'' So you have oil company documents that called for keeping a refinery down while they are saying that it could increase profit margins. That refinery was about 20,000 barrels per day. The one we are talking about in Bakersfield, which services the whole West Coast, about a third of my constituents, involves 70,000 barrels per day. So if Bakersfield goes down, this is going to be very, very harmful to the entire West Coast of the United States. I will tell you, Mr. Chairman and colleagues, this Bakersfield deal smells. First, we know that Shell has made no significant effort to try to find a buyer in that area. Second, a number of independent experts have documented that there is a substantial amount of oil in that area in the San Joaquin Valley. Recent news articles have reported both Chevron-Texaco and the State of California estimate that the San Joaquin Valley, where the Bakersfield refinery is located, has a 20- to 25-year supply of crude oil remaining. The Bakersfield paper indicated that there are 300 more new wells now being pursued this year than last year. And Texaco, Shell's former partner in the Bakersfield area, is actually increasing its drilling. So this certainly calls into question Shell's claim that a lack of available oil supply is the real reason for closing the refinery. Another reason to question Shell's claim about the availability of crude oil is the fact that Shell is currently the subject of an inquiry that we know about for misstating its crude oil reserves. So I have repeatedly asked the Federal Trade Commission to look into this and other anticompetitive practices, and they have just been AWOL. I know you are going to have them testify today. They have talked in the past about being concerned. They have talked in the past about doing sort of informal surveys, when our constituents are getting mugged at the pump. They have abdicated their responsibilities. By the way, Mr. Chairman, just so it is clear that my concern here is bipartisan, I don't think the Clinton administration covered itself with glory over at the Federal Trade Commission either. I think this is a systemic problem and it needs to be dealt with in a bipartisan fashion. So let me wrap up, if I might, by saying exactly the three areas that my legislation would change that I think would give us some tools to deal with the refinery cutbacks, the anticompetitive practices, and I think could complement the kind of work that you and Senator Kohl are trying to do with respect to OPEC. First, under my legislation the Federal Trade Commission would be empowered to issue cease and desist orders to prevent individual companies from gouging consumers. This is not allowed under current law, so we would give them cease and desist powers to prevent gouging of consumers when it is perpetrated by an individual company. Second, we would stipulate that the Federal Trade Commission would have the authority to put the burden on the oil companies to show that certain practices, such as the Bakersfield refinery shutdown or red-lining and zone pricing which has been found in the past--that the company has got to show that this doesn't reduce supply or drive up prices when we are talking about concentrated markets. This would apply, Mr. Chairman and colleagues, in the just over 25 States where there are concentrated markets. Senator Craig and I represent such an area. I hardly ever disagree with my friend from Idaho on these kinds of things. I would just say in response to my colleague's comments that the Federal Trade Commission has said in the past that there has been zone pricing and red-lining. They said they can't do anything about it and that is why I think this legislation is needed, Mr. Chairman. What we have seen in the past is the Federal Trade Commission sets out a bar that is absolutely unachievable with respect to showing that there are anticompetitive practices in the marketplace. The Federal Trade Commission has been arguing that they can only prosecute if they find out and out, blatant collusion, which savvy oil companies are not going to be involved in. They don't have to do that. They are not going to go to a smoke-filled room; they are not going to show up at a steakhouse and decide, well, let's set gasoline prices tonight. They are way too savvy for something like that. So that is why I would like to give the Federal Trade Commission these additional tools in S. 1737--the question of cease and desist powers, and the authority in markets where there is concentration to shift the burden of proof, such as we find with the Bakersfield refinery or red-lining and zone pricing. In a case like Shell's Bakersfield refinery, the Federal Trade Commission could issue under my legislation, Mr. Chairman, a cease and desist order to halt shutdown of the refinery. Because California is a highly concentrated market, Shell would be required to show that closure of the refinery would not have an anticompetitive impact by reducing supply or increasing the price of gas. If Shell can show that it would be increasing its production at the company's other West Coast refineries to make up for lost production at Bakersfield, the closure under my legislation could still be allowed to go forward. But my legislation would protect the consumer where an oil company was closing its refinery as part of a deliberate effort to reduce supply and to drive up prices. Suffice it to say, Mr. Chairman and colleagues, the problems that we are seeing we are going to have for some time to come. The Energy Information Administration came to the Committee that Senator Craig and I serve on saying that there will be continued vulnerability of future gasoline price spikes. Mr. Chairman, I would wrap up by way of saying I don't think there is a silver bullet here. I am supporting your bill because I think it is a significant step forward for the reasons that you have outlined, and particularly important today because the Saudi foreign minister said last week he wasn't even contacted with respect to this most recent production cut. But I would only say that I think we need to complement your fine legislation with the kind of measure that I am advocating that will get the Federal Trade Commission off its hands. You ask this commission what single thing have they done to help the gasoline consumer. I can't find one step that they have taken. By the way, it goes back a few years and we haven't seen any action that they have taken to help the gasoline consumer. I don't think that is acceptable. I want it understood, as you and I have in so many other instances, and I want to work with you in a bipartisan way. Senator Craig and I have talked about these issues a number of times over the years on the Senate Energy Committee, and I will look forward to working with you, colleagues, to try to deal with making sure the consumer gets a fair shake in the gas market. Chairman DeWine. Senator Wyden, thank you very much for a very provocative statement. It certainly gives the Subcommittee a lot of things to think about, and we will use some of your statements as questions when the next panel comes up. Thank you very much. Senator Kohl. Mr. Chairman? Chairman DeWine. Senator Kohl. Senator Kohl. I would like to ask consent that Senator Feingold's statement be placed in the record. Chairman DeWine. Without objection. Let me invite our next panel to come up right now and I will begin to introduce the panel as they come up. Mr. William Kovacic is a recognized expert in both antitrust law and government contracts law, and has published extensively in both fields, most notably as coauthor of Antitrust Law and Economics in a Nutshell. He presently serves as general counsel at the Federal Trade Commission. Mr. John Felmy is the chief economist at the American Petroleum Institute. He also serves as the Chairman of the Policy Committee of the Alliance for Energy and Economic Growth. Dr. Justine Hastings is an assistant professor in the Yale Department of Economics. Her current research interests lie in vertical integration, competition and product differentiation, and she has written extensively on the petroleum industry. Professor George Bermann is professor of law at Columbia University, where he has taught since 1975. He is recognized as an expert on European Union law and has written many articles and several books. Dr. Mark Cooper is the Director of Research at the Consumer Federation of America, where he works on economic policy, among other issues. Dr. Cooper has testified before the Subcommittee in the past and we welcome him back. Let me just say to all of our witnesses we are going to have 5 minutes. We have your written testimony and it will be made a part of the record. But we are going to limit you to 5 minutes, if you could just summarize, please, and then we will have the opportunity for questions. Mr. Kovacic, you can start, please. STATEMENT OF WILLIAM E. KOVACIC, GENERAL COUNSEL, FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Mr. Kovacic. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the Subcommittee. I am pleased to appear before you today to discuss the FTC's initiatives to promote competition in the supply of gasoline. My written statement presents the views of the Federal Trade Commission, and my spoken comments today are my views and not necessarily those of the commission or its members. The FTC's energy program reflects the agency's acute awareness of the vital role that competition policy in the petroleum industry plays in safeguarding consumer interests. Today, I will first describe the FTC's competition program in petroleum, and then I will identify lessons that the agency's work concerning gasoline prices has yielded. The FTC's competition program in petroleum has four elements. The first is to challenge mergers that are likely to reduce competition and injure consumers. Since 1981, the commission has taken enforcement action against 15 major petroleum mergers. Four transactions were either abandoned or blocked as a result of commission or court action. In the other 11 cases, the FTC required the parties to divest substantial assets in markets where competitive harm was likely to occur. From data the FTC recently released concerning enforcement programs from 1996 through 2003, it is evident that the FTC's remedial requirements have been more demanding in petroleum markets than for any other area of commerce in which the commission is active. The second activity at the FTC is to detect and prosecute antitrust violations that do not involve mergers. For example, in March of 2003 the FTC issued an administrative complaint alleging that Unocal violated the FTC Act by deceiving the California Air Resources Board in connection with regulatory proceedings to develop standards for reformulated gasoline. Unocal, the commission alleges, misrepresented that certain technology was non-proprietary and in the public domain at the same time that Unocal was seeking patents that would enable it to charge substantial royalties if CARB mandated Unocal's technology in the refining of summer reformulated gasoline. The commission has charged here that Unocal's conduct, unless enjoined, could cost California consumers hundreds of millions of dollars per year. The third activity is to monitor petroleum industry behavior to detect possible instances of anticompetitive conduct. Nearly 2 years, the FTC launched an initiative to monitor gasoline prices to identify unusual movements in prices and examine whether apparent anomalies might result from anticompetitive conduct. The FTC's economists have developed a statistical model for identifying such price movements. They look at price movements in over 20 wholesale and over 350 retail markets across the country. If our staff detects unusual price movements in an area, it studies the possible causes, and follow-up efforts typically have involved extensive cooperation with State attorneys general, State energy officials, and the Department of Energy. If our staff concludes that the unusual price movement likely results from a natural cause--that is, a cause unrelated to anticompetitive conduct--it investigates no further. Our experience to date indicates that unusual movements in gasoline prices typically have what we consider to be a natural cause. If there are competitive problems, the monitoring project and our expanded cooperation with Federal and State agencies have put us in a better position to identify and address these problems than at any time in recent memory. In recent years, the commission has also conducted intensive non-merger investigations involving refining and distribution practices in the western and midwestern United States. I would like to acknowledge the role that Chairman DeWine and Senator Kohl have played in inspiring the agency to undertake the midwest gasoline pricing investigation, even though the two investigations I have mentioned uncovered no basis to find an antitrust violation. The last activity of the FTC is to collect data and perform research to develop a better understanding of what affects gasoline prices and to improve our knowledge base about the consequences of our enforcement decisions. In 2001 and 2002, the commission held conferences on these topics and is currently updating a comprehensive report on merger enforcement in the petroleum sector since 1989. Let me finish by turning to the lessons that we derived from our program so far. First, the paramount factor affecting both the level and movement of gasoline prices in the United States indeed is the price of crude oil. Changes in crude oil prices account, as Senator Kohl's introductory remarks and yours, Mr. Chairman, mentioned, for approximately 85 percent of the variability of gasoline prices. Second, crude oil and refined products inventories significantly affect gasoline prices at retail. At one of our conferences, the Energy Information Administration reported that high crude oil prices indeed not only affect gasoline prices directly, but indirectly as well, by reducing inventories. There are indeed tighter inventory situations, but what we found, in general, is that by adopting just-in-time techniques, on average, there is the possibility that gasoline prices over time are lower than they would be if just-in-time techniques were not used widely. Third, our conferences and investigations have highlighted the generally high levels of utilization in the refining and transportation segments of the industry--conditions that do make interruptions attributable to fires and other breakdowns a possible cause of price spikes. Last, the interaction of environmental quality requirements and gasoline does supply a fourth important factor. There is no question in this country that pollution control has yielded massive benefits. At the same time, we have identified in our hearings and proceedings that such controls have added at times to the cost of refining crude oil, and thus to the price of gasoline. Finally, our research and conferences indicate that other Federal and State laws sometimes tend to increase gasoline prices. Let me finish by saying that competition policy unquestionably helps assure that the petroleum industry is and remains competitive. The commission has devoted substantial effort and resources to enforce the antitrust laws and to scrutinize behavior in this sector. We will continue to do so in the future. Higher prices for petroleum products deeply affect the quality of life in this country, and we are keenly aware of that. We will also seek to attack conduct that disturbs the proper functioning of the market where antitrust violations can be shown. I look forward to the opportunity to address your questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Kovacic appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Thank you very much. Dr. Felmy. STATEMENT OF JOHN FELMY, CHIEF ECONOMIST AND DIRECTOR OF POLICY ANALYSIS AND STATISTICS, AMERICAN PETROLEUM INSTITUTE Mr. Felmy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the Subcommittee. I am John Felmy, Chief Economist and Director of Policy Analysis and Statistics of the American Petroleum Institute. API is a national trade association representing more than 400 companies engaged in all sectors of the U.S. oil and natural gas industry. API is pleased to have the opportunity to present a statement on gasoline and natural gas, and urge Congress to enact national energy policy legislation. The recent spikes in gasoline prices are primarily due to fundamentals in the supply and demand for crude oil. Demand for crude oil has risen due to a cold winter and strengthening economies. Unrest in key supplying countries such as Venezuela and Nigeria, and lower Iraqi production have kept world supplies tight. OPEC continues to operate under production quotas and has recently confirmed its intent to cut production by a million barrels per day, to 23.5 million barrels a day, potentially worsening the current situation. However, there is no guarantee member nations will reduce output sufficient to comply. The United States continues to import more than 60 percent of the crude oil and petroleum products used each day to provide Americans the products they need. While 20 percent of current imports are from the Middle East, the U.S. Energy Information Administration, EIA, expects that figure to climb substantially as the gap between U.S. oil production and consumption widens. In addition to higher crude prices, several other factors have affected gasoline prices. We have experienced refinery problems; a Mississippi River accident that shut down traffic for several days; the difficulty of switching from winter to summer fuel in California; the introduction of new low-sulfur gasoline, Tier II; the bans of MTB in gasoline in New York, Connecticut and California; and sharply higher demand. I have attached two papers that elaborate on these points, and I have a chart here that shows the complex nature of the crude oil and gasoline markets. I don't have time in my verbal statement to elaborate, but I will be happy to answer questions later. As a consequence of all these factors, gasoline prices have reached a record level, unadjusted for inflation, of over $1.76 per gallon, while, adjusted for inflation, the real price of gasoline has fallen over 40 percent from a peak of $2.77 in 1981. The real cost of crude oil and manufacturing, delivering and marketing gasoline has fallen over the past 20 years, while the real cost of Federal and State taxes has risen. Demand for gasoline continues to be strong as our economy grows. Gasoline production is running at record levels this year to date. However, inventories are low because of strong demand and lower imports. Imports play an important role even though 90 percent of the gasoline we use is refined in this country. High tanker freight rates, low European inventories and increasingly more restrictive U.S. fuel specifications have contributed to the curtailing of gasoline imports. What then can be done about the situation? Some want to suspend filling the Strategic Petroleum Reserve and releasing the 150,000 barrels a day currently going into the reserve onto the marketplace. That would have negligible effect on supply because the amount made available is equivalent to only about two-tenths of 1 percent of world supply. The SPR was established as a back-up in the event of a real supply emergency shortfall, not a non-market mechanism aimed at influencing prices. Turning to the reserve when prices go up sends precisely the wrong message to the marketplace at exactly the wrong time. Unintended consequences may include foreign nations curtailing production. Let me also briefly discuss the situation in natural gas markets. Like gasoline, natural gas has increased substantially in price over the past 2 years. We have seen three price spikes in 3 years, and prices remain high due to high demand and low supply growth. Weather, economic growth and continued increases in demand for gas by electricity generators have kept prices over $5 per million Btus. The industry has responded to the higher prices by operating more drilling rigs searching for natural gas. We have also continued our efforts to obtain access to lands that are currently off limits to exploration for natural gas. API has argued for several years that we need a national energy policy that increases supplies, streamlines regulation, fosters energy efficiency and growth in renewables, and allows for increased infrastructure to get supplies to consumers. The Senate was only two votes short of passing an energy bill that contains provisions that would have helped consumers. A comprehensive energy bill needs to be passed and sent to the President for his signature. Failure to pass meaningful energy legislation will increase the risk that we will stay on the energy price treadmill. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am prepared to answer some questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Felmy appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Dr. Felmy, thank you very much. Dr. Hastings. STATEMENT OF JUSTINE S. HASTINGS, ASSISTANT PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS, YALE UNIVERSITY Ms. Hastings. Mr. Chairman, members of the Subcommittee, my name is Justine Hastings. I am an Assistant Professor of Economics at Yale University and a faculty research fellow at the National Bureau of Economic Research Program on Industrial Organization. I hold a Ph.D. in economics from the University of California at Berkeley and I have previously testified at the United States Senate Governmental Affairs Committee, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, hearings into Gasoline Prices: How Are They Set? The focus of my research over the past few years has been primarily on firm conduct, competition and consumer behavior, and much of my work has been applied to the gasoline industry. Through my research projects, I have analyzed extensive data on retail market structure, wholesale market structure and retail and wholesale gasoline prices for a diverse group of metropolitan areas for a time covering about the past decade. I have used this data to examine, among other things, vertical and horizontal market structure, vertical meaning relationships between upstream firms or producing firms, such as refiners, and retail firms, such as gasoline stations, and horizontal market structure, meaning kind of the structure of the market within either retail or at the refinery level, and the effects of these types of market structures on prices and competition through firm incentives. I have also examined the effects of consumer demand and consumer behavior and preferences on gasoline competition, and I am currently completing a study funded through the National Science Foundation on the determinants of wholesale price discrimination, which you may have heard referred to as zone pricing, and what are the effects of this pricing policy on gasoline retail prices and wholesale prices. I am also currently working on a project with colleagues at Yale and at the University of California at Berkeley examining the effects of environmental regulations that we are discussing today on market structure, arbitrage rates between markets, and gasoline price levels and volatility. Through my research, I have gained substantial knowledge about the gasoline industry, and my independent academic research and acquired knowledge will form the basis of my comments and answers before this Subcommittee today. I would like to make a few quick points or broad points and then I would be happy to answer questions related to them during the questioning session. First, crude oil prices explain a substantial amount of retail gasoline prices in most parts of the country. We have heard a figure of .85, 85 percent, a couple times so far today, and I put a quick table in my written statement that shows that if you went even State by State, with very limited data that I just had someone pull off the Web for me, that varies actually by State from 69 percent to 91 percent. So the question is, yes, it is a big fraction, but what is making the difference between 69 percent in some States and 91 percent in other States? Market structure, both vertical and horizontal, and environmental regulations are also going to be contributing to gasoline price levels, that 69-percent to 81-percent difference. My second point is that in markets where supply is very tight, inelastic demand for gasoline is going to lead to large price changes in response to small supply disruptions. In very tight markets, every firm actually may have market power to unilaterally increase market price. It is not anticompetitive. It is a factor of inelastic demand and a tight supply. Increasing the number of refineries in key markets may ease this tightness. And it is something we may not want to discuss, given environmental regulations and concerns, but it is something we are going to have to bring to the table. If new refineries are also new competitors in the market and, in addition, if they are relatively unintegrated, have a smaller downstream component, they may act to increase competition even further after entry. My third point touches on environmental policy. Environmental policy needs to be designed to incorporate the secondary effects of market structure, not just the effects on pollution. Smart environmental policy looks at market structure when looking at how to achieve an ultimate goal of pollution standards. Fourth, governmental regulations such as minimum mark-up laws, divorcement legislation, fair wholesale pricing or, as you have heard it referred to today, zone price elimination, and government-owned refineries or strategic gasoline reserves in most cases will actually make consumers worse off. I will be happy to address each of these issues during the questioning session. Finally, any policy that comes out of this or any other legislation session must really be founded in credible and sound statistical analysis, guided by economic principles, in order to ensure that the welfare of American consumers and taxpayers is maximized through efficient and competitive markets. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Ms. Hastings appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Mr. Bermann. STATEMENT OF GEORGE A. BERMANN, WALTER GELHORN PROFESSOR OF LAW AND JEAN MONNET PROFESSOR OF EUROPEAN UNION LAW, COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW Mr. Bermann. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and the other members of the Subcommittee. In the few minutes that I do have, I would like to address three questions very briefly and they have to do with the three dimensions that I see in the bill that is before me and before yourselves, and those three dimensions are the substance of the Sherman Act, the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act as the source of sovereign immunity defense that OPEC countries might assert, and last, and most complicated, the act of state doctrine, to which reference has been made. Because I want to discuss three subjects and I have 5 minutes, the math suggests that I need to move quickly. With respect to the Sherman Act, the bill before me and before yourselves seem to me to make it very plain, and perhaps desirably so, that foreign states are indeed subject to the Sherman Act. I say that because at least one district court has expressed the view that foreign states are not subjects of the Sherman Act. The bill makes that clear. Secondly, the court of appeals in that same case expressed doubt that international cartels constituted violations of the Sherman Act, saying that there was an insufficient consensus to that effect, and I think the bill would address that problem, as well, arising under the Sherman Act. With respect to the Sherman Act, I have simply one question that I would raise and one doubt I entertain, and that is why the absence of the Clayton Act from the legislation. In the two pieces of litigation that have been brought, both the Sherman Act and the Clayton Act have been evoked, the latter primarily because it gives rise to claims for injunctive relief. Turning to the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act, there was, and there is to this day debate over whether the activity of the OPEC countries and OPEC itself, were it a proper defendant, constituted a commercial activity. As you well know, the Federal courts are divided as to whether they do or do not constitute commercial rather than governmental activity. The creation of a new, independent exception to the principle of sovereign immunity in the FSIA which this bill would also do would obviate the necessity of characterizing price collusion, output collusion, as commercial or governmental by creating an independent, self-standing statutory exception. A final word of cautionary note with respect to the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act, and indeed with respect to the Sherman Act, is the bill requires direct, substantial and reasonably foreseeable effect on U.S. markets. And there is at least one Federal court that has found that the OPEC activity was not proximately causally related to the price effects reported in the U.S. market. I think that difficulty that one might encounter is endemic to any statute that contains the formula of direct, substantial and reasonably foreseeable effect on U.S. markets. The act of state doctrine is my last subject. On this, I need to be a little more complex, but there are some clear lines to be drawn. The act of state doctrine was the reason why in the one suit that has been brought to the level of the court of appeals that that suit could not proceed. The act of state doctrine was characterized as preventing that cause of action from being pursued. There is no question in my mind, as my written testimony indicates, that Congress has the authority to override the act of state doctrine to whatever extent it wishes to do so. Congress has done so in the past in a small number of very isolated instances, but there is no doubt in my mind, under international and constitutional law alike, that Congress has the authority to do so, even though you will hear and you will read that the act of state doctrine has constitutional underpinnings, and I quote the United States Supreme Court. Those constitutional underpinnings are separation of powers scruples, and it seems to me quite clear that Congress has the right to tell the courts that the courts do not need to defer to Congress. That does not strike me as a disturbance of the separation of powers. Finally, mention should be made of the possibility that other doctrines besides the act of state doctrine might get in the way of successful prosecution of a claim under the amended legislation. The political question doctrine, general principles of international comity, the forum non conveniens doctrine and foreign government compulsion strike me as the four most likely candidates, for reasons I don't have time to go into because I see a red light. I would simply say that I think none of those is a serious problem, and I would be glad to answer questions to that effect. I would simply add that I believe, however, that we should pay some attention to the fact that the Supreme Court, to the extent that it has spoken, has suggested that the Sherman Act itself in its own content incorporates considerations of international comity, and that those considerations might lead a court to decline to enforce the Sherman Act in certain international scenarios. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Bermann appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Dr. Cooper. STATEMENT OF MARK COOPER, DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH, CONSUMER FEDERATION OF AMERICA, ON BEHALF OF CONSUMER FEDERATION OF AMERICA AND CONSUMERS UNION Mr. Cooper. Mr. Chairman, members of the Subcommittee, the headlines in the energy news that are never written are about the domestic petroleum industry. They include the fact that domestic gasoline refining and marketing operations have increased pump prices by about $50 billion in the past 4 years, and domestic natural gas well head prices have increased by over $80 billion, separate and apart from anything that OPEC has done. The bottom line that is overlooked is an increase in the after-tax profits of domestic petroleum companies of well over $50 billion in the same 4 years. The story behind those headlines that doesn't get coverage is how a merger wave in the mid-1990's dramatically increased the concentration of the petroleum industry and enabled it to make business decisions that restricted capacity, eliminated competition from independents and rendered many markets uncompetitive and vulnerable to manipulation. When markets are tight, there are not a lot of suppliers around and prices get sticky. Individual companies can put them up quickly and don't feel pressures to lower them. This is especially true for energy products because large investments in physical facilities are necessary to deliver product, and that means that the flow can't be increased in the short term. On the demand side, these are necessities consumers can't cut back. So market power is augmented when supply and demand elasticities are low. It takes less of a market share to gain power over price, but the antitrust authorities don't adjust their thinking. Storage and economic stockpiles are critical here, but the industry has done a miserable job of ensuring that enough product is available to meet demand without dramatic increases in price. Just-in-time in the oil industry means never there when you really need it. Every accident or blip in the market becomes an excuse to trigger a price increase, and people wring their hands, oh, we didn't have supplies, we didn't have storage. Who chose not to have storage? Business decisions. Moreover, by failing to expand capacity, they are operating their facilities at very high rates of utilization, which makes accidents more likely to happen. If there were more competition, if there were the threat of losing your customers when the shelves go bear, they would have more facilities and they would keep more in storage and we would not have these wild price swings. Three years ago, we outlined a comprehensive policy to implement permanent institutional changes that would reduce the chances that markets will be tight and reduce the exposure of consumers to the opportunistic exploitation of markets when they do become tight. Those recommendations made sense then; they make even more sense today. We would all want a quick fix, immediate relaxation of prices, but what consumers need is the end of the roller coaster and the ratchet of constant volatility with ever- mounting prices. We would love to break the pricing power of OPEC, which would relieve a great deal of the pricing problem, but the short-term prospects are not promising there either. There, too, we need long-term solutions that address fundamentals. We must restore reserve margins by increasing energy efficiency that takes demand out of the world market, but also reduces demand in tight domestic markets, which also suffer from the abuse of market power. In the 1990's, we built two fleets of gas-guzzlers--SUVs on the roads and natural gas-fired power plants, particularly that fire up in the summer to run our air conditioners. They have kept domestic markets tight. Efficiency can produce a tremendous saving that has the double impact of relaxing the tightness of both international and domestic markets. We must increase the flexibility of downstream capacity in the gasoline industry. We closed those refineries--that is, the oil industry closed those refineries after mergers as a function of their business decisions to consciously tighten markets and increase profits. We are suffering from that today. We have to have policies that promote economically-and socially-responsible storage. There is no excuse for repeatedly being short. Those are business decisions. Public policy can influence those business decisions. The pending energy legislation does not substantially advance the four key elements of a national energy policy. We must expand domestic refining capacity by studying who closed what, why, and where are the sites that we could redevelop, instead of simply complaining about unidentified environmental obstacles. Those refineries were there; they can be reopened. We need a more competitive domestic sector. We need rules that dictate when you have to have storage and how you should use it. We have to take the fun and profit out of market manipulation. It may very well be that none of the behaviors I have mentioned violate the antitrust laws. That doesn't make them right. It simply tells us that we need a new set of laws that get at this behavior which is actually imposing immense pain on the American consumer and our economy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Mr. Cooper appears as a submission for the record.] Chairman DeWine. Senator Specter. Senator Specter. Mr. Kovacic, has the FTC ever considered antitrust action against OPEC? Mr. Kovacic. I don't know, Senator. I know the commission has certainly for a period going back over decades had an active hand in studying crude oil markets. Indeed, in the-- Senator Specter. I am interested in OPEC. If you don't know, you don't know. I would suggest the FTC ought to consider that, and I would also suggest that the FTC ought to send somebody today who could give us an FTC policy about OPEC. That is the central thrust of the hearing and that is the statute which we are looking at. Professor Bermann, isn't there at least a prime facie case to get to a jury on OPEC being in violation of the antitrust laws on conspiring to restrain trade when they are working with other countries to limit production and in a context where there is a rising cost of gasoline? Where you have a couple of doctrines on sovereign immunity and that turns on whether it is a commercial activity or a governmental activity, it seems to me that it is clearly a commercial activity when they are selling oil to us. And you have the act of state doctrine where the courts have said there is flexibility and it depends upon the evolution of international legal principles. A great deal has happened in the intervening time since the International Association of Machinists case was decided. Just to cut through it, without taking them up one by one, couldn't an aggressive prosecutor make a case that would get to the jury or the fact-finder if it is a bench trial? Mr. Bermann. Well, certainly, as to the merits--that is to say you asked whether the activity in question would represent anticompetitive behavior within the meaning of the Sherman Act. I think the answer is most certainly yes, and one court has so held in an action brought in the year 2001 that hasn't yet been mentioned against OPEC. Senator Specter. The one in Alabama? Mr. Bermann. Yes, the suit in Alabama that actually rendered a judgment adverse to OPEC and issued an injunction to OPEC, but which was vacated, and which vacatur was sustained on appeal on the ground of inadequate service of OPEC in Vienna, Austria, on technical grounds. Senator Specter. Well, I am glad you brought that case up because at least there is a Federal court determination that there was a violation of the U.S. antitrust laws. The judgment was vacated because OPEC didn't defend. They were disdainful of coming into the Federal court, and they later raised technical objections and came in after a judgment had been entered against them. But at least that is authority for the proposition that U.S. antitrust laws were violated by OPEC. Mr. Bermann. Well, the district court actually found that the violation was per se. The district court actually found it was a per se violation of the antitrust laws. Senator Specter. I know what per se means, but somebody who may be watching on C-SPAN may not. Mr. Bermann. A per se violation is an act that in itself, without more, constitutes a violation. Senator Specter. That means it is a pretty clear-cut situation? Mr. Bermann. A clear-cut case of a violation. It was vacated only on grounds that service was technically inadequate, and it was technically inadequate because OPEC refused to accept service of process in Vienna, Austria, where it was located. Senator Specter. Certainly, they had notice. They knew they were being sued. That wasn't any surprise to them, but we all understand that service and jurisdiction are matters to be decided under technical rules. Mr. Bermann. They conceded notice. Senator Specter. They conceded notice? Mr. Bermann. OPEC conceded notice, yes. Senator Specter. Well, we have got too much to discuss to get into the issue as to whether the court inappropriately dismissed the case on technical grounds. When you talk about causation, that is a fact question. Where you have OPEC limiting production by 2.5 million barrels, and doing so at a time when gasoline prices are rising, that would depend upon the skill of the prosecutor in putting on the evidence as to whether the evidence was sufficient to establish a causal connection. Mr. Bermann. You are entirely right about that. It is a matter of a combination of basic factual showing and a skillful and convincing characterization of the facts. Senator Specter. Well, I am a little at a loss to know why our law enforcement agencies have not pursued the matter. It is a matter of great concern to the American people. It is a matter of enormous financial cost on gasoline going up--we have already seen all the fancy charts and heard the statistics--and heating oil going up. In your judgment, an action could be maintained under existing law which would get to the fact-finder or get to a jury? Mr. Bermann. It could be maintained under existing law. My remarks about the bill were oriented toward the fact that the bill removed doubts. Any doubts about the principal matters are subject to one or two lingering doubts that I alluded to. Senator Specter. Well, I am glad you took up the bill because I think it is a good bill. I have already complimented Senator DeWine on it for initiating it. The legislation is good, so that we don't have to get into the intricacies as to whether you have a commercial activity or a governmental activity, or the flexibility of the act of state doctrine. So I think we ought to pass it. Mr. Bermann. You are right in those respects. Senator Specter. It is pretty hard to pass something in Congress these days. So my hope would be that the FTC would take a look at this matter, or that the Justice Department would take a look at it. Mr. Kovacic, the FTC ordinarily exercises jurisdiction on gasoline matters, but there is nothing to stop the Department of Justice from initiating an antitrust violation, is there? Mr. Kovacic. There would not be. Any matter involving a criminal allegation would be handled by the Department of Justice, and we do have a process between us by which, if the Justice Department said they had better capability to pursue a matter, they could. Senator Specter. Professor Bermann, there could also be a private action under the antitrust laws for treble damages, could there not? Mr. Bermann. That is correct, and both lawsuits to which reference has been made--the one from 1979, on appeal in 1981, and 2001, on appeal in 2003--were private lawsuits seeking damages and/or injunctive relief. Senator Specter. Do you have any idea why some aggressive private lawyer--there are lots of antitrust suits brought as private prosecutors--why such an action has not been initiated? Mr. Bermann. Well, those two were initiated. Senator Specter. Beyond that, something more recently. Mr. Bermann. Why there haven't been more? Well, I think the act of state doctrine and the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act have operated as some sort of brakes on that process. I didn't mention this in my oral testimony, nor, in fact, in my written testimony, but I think that, as I read the bill--and I sought clarification on this question--the Federal Trade Commission and the Attorney General would have exclusive authority to enforce these provisions. Now, I stand to be corrected in my understanding of the bill, but I understand the bill to so state. That would seem to me, while it would prevent any future private parties from bringing antitrust suits against the OPEC countries, it would go a very long way to defeating any arguments that might be based on the act of state doctrine, because after all the act of state doctrine is intended to protect the political prerogatives of the legislative and executive branches. And if those actions are authorized by Congress and decided upon to be brought by the Federal Trade Commission or the Department of Justice, then there is no reason left for anybody to even think about the act of state doctrine. Senator Specter. Professor Bermann, do you think that the provision as to enforcement being with the Attorney General or the Federal Trade Commission would raise any question as to the right of a private litigant under the treble damage provisions to initiate a private lawsuit? Mr. Bermann. Well, I think it would raise that question because I believe that the bill is ambiguous on that point and it is more than arguable that a recital that enforcement shall be--the exact language is ``The Attorney General of the United States and the Federal Trade Commission may bring an action to enforce this section.'' That is ambiguous as to whether that is exclusive or not exclusive of the existing rights of private parties to do so, and I would recommend that any such legislation clarify that point. The consequences of clarifying that one way or another are quite significant. Senator Specter. Well, I think we ought to make that modification. My judgment would be that there could be private enforcement. When you say ``may,'' I think that leaves the leeway, but there is no reason to have any doubt about it. Taking up the issue of a legal action under existing law, is there any real basis, where you have the sovereign immunity question which turns on whether it is commercial activity or governmental activity, to conclude that this is a clear-cut commercial activity? Mr. Bermann. Well, courts have differed over that, and one reason they differ over that is because sometimes the judgment as to whether an activity is commercial is based upon the nature of the activity and sometimes it is based upon the purposes or policies underlying the activity. Senator Specter. Where it is to make money, is there any doubt? Mr. Bermann. No doubt, no doubt. But where natural resources are involved, a good many courts, including in cases outside this sector altogether, have held that the management of a country's natural resources--even if dealt with in ways that are commercially familiar to us, the very fact that they are natural resources renders it governmental. The courts have a bit of a problem with characterizing foreign countries' control of their natural resources as purely commercial. Some have and some have not. The virtue of this bill is that it would make it no longer necessary for the exception to sovereign immunity to depend upon whether we accentuate or don't accentuate the natural resources character of oil and petroleum. Senator Specter. Okay, that is fine. I think we ought to get the bill, but in the interim I would like to see the Justice Department do something about it. I think your opinion is a solid that there is a basis to pursue, notwithstanding the sovereign immunity doctrine, on the ground that this is really a commercial activity. May the record show that there was a nod in the affirmative. Mr. Bermann. Yes, sir. Senator Specter. On the act of state doctrine, the International Association of Machinists case talked about the flexibility of it and on the availability of internationally- accepted legal principles. Since the Ninth Circuit opinion in 1981, there has been in the 1990's a significant increase in efforts to seek compliance with basic international norms through international courts and tribunals, and an emerging consensus in international law that price-fixing by cartels violates such international norms. Would you agree with that? Mr. Bermann. Yes, I would. Senator Specter. Well, then I think the stage has been set for an aggressive prosecution here, Professor Bermann. I appreciate your background and your insights and your research. I think an aggressive prosecution would be well received. The worst that could happen, Mr. Kovacic, would be to lose, and that is not such a dire consequence when the stakes are as important as they are. Mr. Bermann. Mr. Senator, if I may, in the case that began in Alabama and went up to the Eleventh Circuit, the act of state doctrine was found to be inapplicable to the action against OPEC. It was found to be inapplicable because OPEC's activity was commercial, and, secondly, because OPEC's activity was taking place in Vienna, Austria, which is not on the territory of the states in question. So the most recent decision that we have been referring to is a decision that addressed the act of state doctrine and found it to be inapplicable to these circumstances. That is a decision of 2001 and not in any respect weakened in the appellate ruling of 2003. Senator Specter. Well, that is an important observation to show that some of these legal hurdles have already been overcome and that there is precedent. Senator DeWine and I used to be prosecuting attorneys, and a prosecuting attorney ought not to take a case that doesn't have a sound policy and that he doesn't have sufficient evidence to get to a jury. But when you weigh the importance of the matter, as I would weigh the importance of going after OPEC in their collusive practices and the consequences at least sequentially of rising gasoline and rising oil prices in the United States, we are dealing with very substantial financial matters for the American consumer. Dr. Cooper, would you like to see a test case brought representing consumers? Mr. Cooper. We are big fans of test cases. Frankly, clearly, one of our problems is that, in my opinion, OPEC has fought an economic war against the American consumer and we have not responded at that level. Senator Specter. That is not the only war they have fought against us. Mr. Cooper. I understand, but the point is that we definitely think that we support this legislation to remove any doubts. There is absolutely no reason why we can't defend ourselves from this sort of attack. Senator Specter. Mr. Kovacic, would you think it appropriate for the FTC to consider an enforcement action against OPEC under the antitrust laws? Mr. Kovacic. Senator, I don't have instructions from the commission to address this, so I answer in my own capacity. Senator Specter. Sure. Mr. Kovacic. I see this as involving a number of extremely complicated issues. I agree completely with the suggestion that the behavior would be unmistakably illegal. By any of our standards, if these were private enterprises, our Department of Justice would highly likely prosecute them criminally and seek to imprison the individuals involved. So the culpability of the behavior under our legal standards is unmistakable. If I could mention for a moment the things that might make us hesitate, one is that obtaining discovery in such a matter might be relatively difficult. Enforcing a judgment might be relatively difficult. Senator Specter. Offending the sovereign, you say? Mr. Kovacic. Obtaining discovery and enforcing a judgment would be complex. If I think of the practical steps that would be taken, these would likely be fairly elaborate and long- running as we dealt with those issues. Senator Specter. If you can't get discovery, if they don't submit to discovery, you get a default judgment. If you go after assets, OPEC has plenty of assets within the long arm of U.S. law. Mr. Kovacic. If I could offer another possibility, in the international work we do a number of countries raise objections to policies that the United States follows which they allege to be matters of cartelization. I wonder if they would pass their own accord collateral legislation to bring their laws to bear upon our own policies, and I think of the matter of agricultural commodities as being one. Senator Specter. Supply for the record--I don't want to go on too much longer--where the United States might be exposed. Dr. Felmy, do you think an aggressive prosecution here might be warranted? Mr. Felmy. Senator, I am not an attorney. I am not qualified to make a statement on that particular issue. Senator Specter. Well, because you are not an attorney may make you well qualified, Dr. Felmy. Senator Specter. Dr. Hastings, you are a Ph.D. That certainly gives you qualifications. Ms. Hastings. Yes, but in economics, unfortunately, not in law. So I joint have a joint J.D.-Ph.D. I am an economist and I examine industrial organization, so market structure and firm behavior. So I am really not able to speak to the extent to which we could successfully litigate antitrust laws against OPEC. Senator Specter. Okay, thank you. This transcript ought to be sent over to both the commission and the Attorney General, at least with my thinking, and I will discuss it with my colleagues beyond. Both Senator DeWine and I, as a I said before, were prosecutors, and I initiated many actions which were original actions, sued under the nuisance laws people who were spraying asbestos and closed down commercial buildings; prosecuted for first-degree murder a defendant who did not touch the victim, made new law on first-degree murder without contact. The law is an evolving body which responds to aggressive prosecutions when you have a good factual basis and you have a policy to be enforced. Senator DeWine, thank you very much for convening the hearing and thank you very much for the latitude on my questioning. Chairman DeWine. Well, Senator Specter, thank you very much. I think you all can see why we brought my senior partner here to prosecute the case for the DeWine-Kohl bill here today. Thank you, Senator, very much. Senator Specter. Thank you. Chairman DeWine. I will reserve my questions. Senator Schumer. Senator Schumer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to thank the witnesses. I apologize for missing a few of you. We had a Banking hearing at the same time. First, I want to ask a little bit about natural gas to Kovacic and the others. We had a dramatic price spike in natural gas last year. This last winter, it was much higher than it had been before. Yet, if you looked at supply and demand, it wasn't terribly different. In fact, it was a little less stringent this past winter than it was in the previous winter. Has the FTC investigated last winter's price spikes? If so, what is the status of the investigation? If not, since you can't speak for the commission, what are your thoughts? Gas just went through the roof. Obviously, it is a different type of market than oil, with pipelines and everything else. Tell me what you think. Mr. Kovacic. Senator, our work to date has basically been focused on looking at mergers involving natural gas companies, seven in the past two-and-a-half years. In the course of those investigations, we have had some occasion to look at behavioral issues in the industry. But to my knowledge, we don't have a current investigation simply looking at conduct, but I would be happy to check that and to report to you. Senator Schumer. Would it be within the purview of the FTC? Mr. Kovacic. Yes, it would, sir. Senator Schumer. And would it be in the purview to see if the mergers that have occurred have helped contribute--one of my premises is we have had less and less competition in the energy industry, and that has in part increased the price, whether it be overseas with Senator DeWine's bill, with OPEC, or domestically with the mergers that we have seen throughout the 1990's, by the way many of them under Democratic administrations. This is hardly a partisan-type issue. Mr. Kovacic. We have several projects underway to look at the consequences of past petroleum mergers. Again, speaking for myself, I think it is a wise policy for the commission to expand its efforts to assess the effects both of past decisions to prosecute and not to prosecute. In one area not involving petroleum or natural gas, the commission has begun to do this in health care. Without being able to predict how the agency will act in the future, I see a growing interest in looking in the rear view mirror to see the actual consequences of what we have done. So my view is that is wise policy. Senator Schumer. Good. That would be very helpful. I hope you will do it. Tell the commissioners about that. Mr. Kovacic. I will, sir. Senator Schumer. Dr. Hastings, as the economist with only a Ph.D. and not a J.D. who has maybe studied these markets a little bit-- Ms. Hastings. I am not an expert in natural gas markets. I am an expert in gasoline markets, and they are very different. Senator Schumer. But just using your knowledge as an economist, given the fact that we have pipelines from gas fields connected and they are generally monopolies--that is, you can't go to two different natural gas producers and the natural gas companies have a limit in terms of who they can get the gas from. I have asked lots of people and no one has come up with a good explanation as to why natural gas spiked so in price last year, this past winter. Ms. Hastings. I am not an expert to speak to that. Senator Schumer. Do you, Dr. Cooper, have anything to say about it? Mr. Cooper. Well, in my testimony we look at natural gas and we observe that over the past four or 5 years, natural gas has risen much more rapidly than crude oil. Senator Schumer. Correct. Mr. Cooper. The domestic market has changed in the last 5 years to close that gap. What changed was the majors, the same folks who are concentrating the refinery industry, moved into the natural gas market in a big way. They invest differently, they behave differently, they manage their assets differently. So the same attitudinal factors that look at the way they maximize their profit as opposed to compete for market share afflict the natural gas market, in my opinion, as they do the domestic gasoline market. The other point is that the natural gas price is now set in the spot markets, the hubs. Well, it turns out that most of those hubs didn't even exist 10 years ago and we are now discovering that all of them have been afflicted by manipulation. Almost daily, you read press accounts from the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission discovering that people were mis-reporting gas, et cetera. So these are very thin markets. There is a court case going forward. Just a couple of weeks ago, I believe a Federal district court judge allowed the case to go forward and he pointed out that on any given day in 2001, Enron accounted for 40 percent of the gas being transacted at the Henry hub. Now, the Henry hub is the key referent price. The Department of Energy has discovered that that is setting the price of natural gas, and it is tracking crude much more closely than it used to do. Enron controlled 40 percent of the transactions in that market. When Enron went away, for clearly very, very nasty reasons, these markets got to be very thin and they have been laboring along. They are not transparent, and the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is struggling to figure out how to get real clear price signals out of the gas market and still doesn't have a program. Again, the fundamentals in this industry are exactly like the gasoline industry--inelasticity of supply in the short term, inelasticity of demand in the short term. So last spring, with a natural gas crisis, the prices popped up and everyone was wringing their hands about how storage wasn't adequate again. How did that happen? It is a business decision. When the stocks finally moved up over the course of the summer, by the end of the winter people pointed out there was more in storage than there was in the previous 2 years and the price is still too high. So this is market that is not setting prices in a competitive, pro-consumer manner. Senator Schumer. So you would recommend the FTC do what Mr. Kovacic said maybe they should do? Mr. Cooper. But they have to begin to look at these markets given what we know about the inelasticity of supply and demand. If we just do routine antitrust analysis, as Senator DeWine, if you look at their market shares, they don't look very concentrated, although certainly some of the gasoline markets have gotten very concentrated. But knowing the economic fundamentals, knowing about how inelastic are supply and demand, that magnifies market power. And maybe we can't do that under the antitrust laws. Maybe we need different laws that are on different premises, but that is a fundamental problem. Senator Schumer. Like I mentioned before, my great concern is this sort of triangle I mentioned--OPEC, a small number of large oil companies and administration friendliness to that. In your testimony, Dr. Cooper--and I am going to ask Mr. Kovacic and Dr. Felmy this--you made a point that when OPEC raises its international price, American oil companies greatly profit even more from their domestic production, where their cost of production stays the same or is on the same curve as it was before. But because the international price has gone way up, they make much more in profit. Certainly, the profits of the oil companies seem to be quite in sync with the increase in price, not exactly, but pretty close. Just give me a yes or no on that. Is that true, Dr. Cooper? Mr. Cooper. There is price-following behavior in both the domestic oil market and the natural gas market. The interesting thing is that one of the reasons the large industrial gas users in this country are screaming is because in the rest of the world gas is not exhibiting that price-following behavior. They are losing their jobs to other markets where the price of natural gas doesn't run up every time the price of crude runs up. Now, we can have a debate about why those foreign markets behave differently. Senator Schumer. It means it is not inexorable. That is what it means. Mr. Cooper. That is right. It is not inexorable. Senator Schumer. The big oil companies sort of like it when OPEC raises prices because then the world price goes up and their domestic production is more profitable. Do you agree with that, Mr. Kovacic? Again, you can speak for yourself, not for the commission. Mr. Kovacic. Yes, sir. I know that we have done work looking at trends in profitability and attempting to explain them. I don't have a good sense of exactly what our research has shown on the point you ask, but I would be happy to check that and submit that in writing to you. Senator Schumer. You could submit that in writing. Do you have any thoughts on that, Dr. Hastings? Ms. Hastings. On the profitability of oil companies coinciding with the profitability-- Senator Schumer. The price that OPEC sets, yes. Ms. Hastings. No, I have not looked into that issue. Senator Schumer. Okay, and I will bet Dr. Felmy doesn't quite agree with what I said, so let's give him a chance. Mr. Felmy. Well, actually, Senator, because domestic prices move with world prices, because oil is an international commodity, you will see for that roughly, I guess, 35 percent of the crude oil that we actually produce here to use, higher margins for that crude as world prices go up. Senator Schumer. So if an oil company were interested, at least in the short term, in maximizing their profits, they would be happy, at least--let's not get into collusion, but they would be happy to see OPEC raise its price? Mr. Felmy. Well, it depends on whether or not you are a refiner or a producer. If you are refiner, the answer is a decided no. If you are a producer, it tends to benefit you. Senator Schumer. Overall, let's take Exxon Mobil--something that never should have existed, in my opinion; it should be Exxon and it should be Mobil. Those were the two biggest in my area and they were allowed to merge. Doesn't Exxon Mobil do better profitability-wise when OPEC raises its price, because at least the domestic share-- Mr. Felmy. I am not an expert, sir, on the split between the refining, production, chemicals and all the other businesses that large corporations such as Exxon Mobil have ongoing. So I can't speak to that, sir. Senator Schumer. Do you want to say something, Dr. Hastings? Ms. Hastings. Well, I don't know Exxon Mobil's exact ratio of production to consumption of crude oil. If they are a net producer of crude oil, then they benefit from it. If they are a net consumer of crude oil, they don't benefit from it. It depends on the balance of their-- Senator Schumer. Assuming that there is pure competition at the selling end, which there isn't. Ms. Hastings. I am sorry. I didn't quite understand. Senator Schumer. Even if they are a consumer, if they can pass all of that along in an inelastic way to the person who buys gasoline, home heating oil or whatever else, it is not going to hurt them even on their consuming side. They gain on the production side. Because of these mergers, they have an inelastic demand curve on the consumption side and it is a win- win. Ms. Hastings. Not necessarily. Senator Schumer. Go ahead and explain to me why. Ms. Hastings. Well, it depends. Imagine the opposite happening, the opposite being, as Mr. Felmy pointed out, suppose that Exxon was actually not a producer, but only a refiner. Before Tosco merged with Conoco Phillips, Tosco would have been in this category. So they are only going to be purchasing crude oil. Then your assumption is actually that they are going to pass a hundred percent of that crude oil price on to retail. Senator Schumer. But Tosco is not a fair example because they didn't own gasoline stations. Ms. Hastings. They did own gasoline stations before they merged with Conoco Phillips. They owned the West Coast refining and marketing assets of Unocal Corporation. They owned the Circle K chain since 1996. Senator Schumer. Did they have the same kind of market dominance that, say, Exxon Mobil has at the pump in my area or any part of the country? Ms. Hastings. Most definitely, in Arizona. Senator Schumer. In Arizona? Ms. Hastings. Most definitely, in Arizona. Senator Schumer. So Tosco would have made money in Arizona. Ms. Hastings. And they most definitely had a large market share. And I am not agreeing that they would have made money in Arizona. They also had a large market share in California. Senator Schumer. Do you know what percent? Ms. Hastings. It depends on the metropolitan area. So I am thinking somewhere between 12--no, probably about 10 percent, 12 percent. I could be off on that. Senator Schumer. I think that is a lot less than Exxon Mobil has in my area. True? Ms. Hastings. Perhaps. Senator Schumer. Oh, yes, more than perhaps. Ms. Hastings. I actually just looked at the percent that Exxon Mobil has in the New York metropolitan area. Senator Schumer. Good. What is it? Ms. Hastings. I am just not remembering off the top of my head, but I think it is probably closer to 20 percent. So, yes, they have a large market share in your area. Senator Schumer. What do you say to this, Dr. Cooper? Mr. Cooper. Well, the point is that they are integrated, and that has been one of the trends is that you have got more integrated refiners. So it is more and more difficult to talk about the refining sector because this is an integrated operation. Senator Schumer. Right. That is what I was trying to say. Mr. Cooper. So the point is that if you look at the bottom line of Exxon Mobil this year, folks, it is through the roof, and it is driven significantly by crude oil prices, but also by the ability to keep--if there were price resistance at the point of sale, the rise in crude prices would have squeezed down the domestic spread, and it did not. If you look at our testimony, the reason we are having so much shouting today is that both domestic spread and crude oil prices, the input prices, are at historic highs for an April, and it is the combination of that. I understand you could hypothesize other reasons, but the simple fact of the matter is that there is no elasticity of demand at the point of sale. Senator Schumer. Right, and Dr. Hastings made the point because she had to go to something that doesn't exist now, a large refiner that didn't have production. That was Tosco, and who bought Tosco? I don't even know. Who bought them? Ms. Hastings. Conoco Phillips. Senator Schumer. Conoco Phillips, a seller and a producer. Ms. Hastings. By the way, Tosco was just the first thing that came to my head. Senator Schumer. I understand, I understand, but I don't think Tosco was the biggest sort of refiner qua refiner. Ms. Hastings. It might have actually been the largest independent refiner at the time of the purchase. Senator Schumer. That is what I am saying. The point I am making is the greater consolidation, vertical and horizontal, in this industry over the last several years has created less competition and has created not only higher prices, but a greater incentive, either implicitly or even explicitly, for OPEC and the oil companies, the big ones, not everybody, to cooperate. I just have one more question here, and the Chairman has been very generous. This is about ethanol. Last week, there were rumors that the administration might have granted both New York and California a waiver from the ethanol mandate, and prices dropped for energy futures on the NYMEX. I think they went down 5.2 percent for gasoline and 4.2 percent for crude oil. Anyone can answer this. Isn't this empirical evidence that the waivers, if we were to allow New York, California and whatever other States wanted to that are far away from the corn-growing ethanol-producing centers--if we were to allow those States to meet the clean air standards by cracking gasoline somewhat differently, prices would come down some. Does anyone want to agree or disagree? Yes, Mr. Kovacic. Mr. Kovacic. We haven't tried to measure the exact effects of the substitution you mention, Senator, but an unmistakable finding that we have made is that measures that can be taken to preserve general levels of air quality while introducing more flexibility into the supply system, have possibilities in many areas to put greater downward pressure on prices. A more flexible supply and distribution system consistent with broad air quality goals is better for the competitive process. Senator Schumer. Dr. Felmy. Mr. Felmy. I would agree, Senator, that any measure that allows you to be able to increase the flexibility so that refiners can meet clean air without prescriptive solutions for that introduces flexibility. It also introduces the possibility of additional imports. So we would agree with that position and we support waivers for everyone. Senator Schumer. Does anyone disagree with that? Mr. Cooper. I agree with it, with a caveat. Bigger markets are better for consumers as long as the players in the markets are more. If it is the same players in the same big markets, I am not sure you diminish their market power. So when we look at making these bigger markets, we have to also make sure we increase the competitiveness of those markets or we may end up on a treadmill. Senator Schumer. One final question. This is for Mr. Bermann. We left the legal questions to the former prosecutors, Senator DeWine and Senator Specter. But as a cosponsor of Senator DeWine's legislation, given that OPEC is a cartel specifically designed to manipulate price, does the involvement of U.S. companies with OPEC raise any domestic antitrust issues? In other words, does the fact that some of the oil companies also own some of the production in the OPEC nations, such as whatever the name of that company is that I mentioned in my opening--Motiva, the old Aramco--does that raise any antitrust issues independent of the good legislation that Senator DeWine has offered? Mr. Bermann. Well, the fact that those companies might be dealing with foreign governments would not immunize them in any respect. The law has never gone any further than to say only the compulsion of a foreign government would operate as a defense. So if you had the kinds of predicate acts that you are thinking of, there is no question that I think the Sherman Act could apply to them. And the fact that they are dealing with or consorting with foreign governments will not immunize them. Indeed, if I can revert to the act of state doctrine, the courts have held routinely that the act of state doctrine only applies when the legality of what a foreign government does is in question and not when, if you will, the good faith or bad motivation of the foreign government is indirectly implicated. Senator Schumer. Do you agree with that, Mr. Kovacic, and does the FTC agree with that? Mr. Kovacic. Again, speaking in my own capacity, I think Professor Bermann has accurately described the requirement that there be compulsion. So the issue of fact would be, in the concession arrangements that govern their activities in these countries, are there measures in those arrangements that provide the requisite compulsion. I think his technical assessment is correct. Senator Schumer. So would that mean that, say, Shell, which has ownership in Saudi Arabia and is part of this Aramco, which is part of OPEC, is susceptible to FTC action for what they do here because of their big network and operations here? Mr. Kovacic. In any instance in which we would look at foreign behavior in these circumstances, we would generally take the view that without compulsion, for example, the behavior in question is fair game. So that would be the crucial factual issue. Senator Schumer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate your having this hearing. Chairman DeWine. Senator, thank you very much. Mr. Bermann, you have made some good suggestions on how we can improve this bill and we are certainly going to take a look at that. I want to thank you for that. That is one of the reasons we have these hearings. You made the point about the state of the law and told us a little bit about that, and we appreciate that. I might say there has been some editorial comment about this proposed bill that we couldn't do this because there are legal impediments. And I would just say your testimony has pointed out, I think, the fact that this bill would remove any legal impediments. Whatever legal impediments are out there-- and that is an open question--but whatever legal impediments are out there, this bill eliminates them. That is why we introduced the bill. It is problematic whether or not suits could be brought now or not. I think they could be, but the whole purpose today of this bill is to make it so that prosecution can move forward, and make it clear that the antitrust laws of this country do, in fact, apply. The idea of the Department of Justice enforcing the antitrust laws against cartels is something that happens all the time, and they do it against not just domestic companies; they do it against foreign companies. It wasn't too many years ago there was a lawsuit brought by the Department of Justice. It was an international cartel case against, I believe, German and Swiss firms for a vitamins cartel. That case was successful. Foreign executives, I believe, were sent to jail. Two firms paid a fine of over $700 million. So the United States can reach the assets; the Justice Department can reach those assets. We can attach those assets. We can bring those people into court. I have faith in the ability of the lawyers at the Justice Department to get the job done, and that is why we have this bill to remove the impediments and let them go about their business and do their job and enforce our antitrust laws. This is the only major area that I know of where we say they can't do it, and we think they should be able to do it. Mr. Kovacic, we have heard testimony today complaining about the FTC's efforts to investigate the petroleum industry. In your testimony, you talked about a number of actions and investigations that the FTC has conducted in this area, but it seems clear to me that consumers still believe that they are looking at a very dysfunctional market. What else can the FTC do? Mr. Kovacic. I think one of the most important things, Mr. Chairman, is to bring to a complete conclusion a great deal of the research that we have been doing that comes both from the active, almost real-time monitoring of price changes, the consequences of our retrospective assessments of completed transactions, the continued work that we are doing to enlist expert outsiders to tell us more about the industry--to bring that to a successful conclusion so that our understanding of the precise phenomena in question is more complete, to have a better sense, for example, of precisely how specific transactions or activities have affected market outcomes. I have heard on a number of occasions Senator Wyden express his frustration, his disappointment with the inquiries. But our view has been in this and other areas that are terribly complex that the sound empirical foundation is the indispensable basis for making good policy. One of the first and most important things we can do is to bring those efforts to a close as a foundation for doing more work. Second, I think bringing to a successful close cases such as the Unocal case that I mentioned before, which we allege-- our opponents in this case would strongly dispute my characterization--literally involves hundreds of millions of dollars for California consumers, direct pass-through effects, to establish the principle that the regulatory process which is so important to the operation of this industry--clean air and clean water controls, other controls that govern the behavior of the industry--cannot be gamed, that firms subject to them cannot lie or misrepresent their behavior. And again I must emphasize I am offering the allegations in the commission's complaint. These aren't proven facts. To demonstrate that principle successfully would be, I think, a critical addition to our competition policy about what it says in petroleum and elsewhere about the manipulation of regulatory schemes that do affect competitive outcomes. I think we have the humility, Senator, in listening to all of the representations here about additional avenues for research and analysis, to continue to pursue those paths. I am quite at peace with the process that continues to bring upon us possibilities for additional analysis, new research, new areas for examination. Our process of policymaking takes those into account, so most certainly we would carefully consider and reflect upon the results of this proceeding as well. Chairman DeWine. Let me ask you, do you agree with Dr. Cooper's assessment that refining is excessively concentrated, and if so, does that mean that the FTC got it wrong when it reviewed the big mergers of the 1990's in the petroleum industry? Mr. Kovacic. When we look carefully at the contributions that the mergers in question made to concentration in refining, we find that those adjustments were modest, at most. Indeed, it is very difficult to detect, I believe, direct, convincing links between the mergers we permitted, with conditions, with large divestitures, and notable increases in concentration in these markets. So I think that we and Dr. Cooper would have quite a debate about exactly how those mergers influenced refining concentration in those markets. Chairman DeWine. Well, let me move to another area. There seems to be widespread agreement that petroleum companies run their refineries at a very high capacity, yet don't build up new capacity to meet potential demand increases. We know that there are some difficulties in increasing refining capacity. We have talked about this a little bit today; environmental permitting, for example. But on balance, it seems as though there ought to be some way the industry could boost refining capacity. Why don't we see more refining capacity come on line? Is there any other industry that comes to mind where producers run at this very high capacity year after year and don't take any steps to increase capacity? What is the difficulty here? Mr. Kovacic. I think part of what we have observed, Mr. Chairman, is that utilization rates, at least in the past couple of years, to some extent have been falling a bit, so that we don't have the level of tightness that prevailed before. I would have to check, Mr. Chairman, to look at exactly what our experience base tells us about actual improvements in the capacity of specific facilities that do remain on line. And if you will permit me to do so, I would like to supplement my answer with a fuller response. Chairman DeWine. That would be fine. You can submit that. Mr. Kovacic. But our impression is that certainly in some areas with respect to some facilities, we are seeing enhancements that do increase the capacity of existing facilities. Chairman DeWine. Dr. Felmy, have you ever done a study estimating what price we would pay for crude oil if it were subject to the free market instead of being fixed by OPEC? Mr. Felmy. I have really not, Mr. Chairman. An economist looks at cartels and has an academic view of how things go, but then when you transfer that analysis to the real world, there are many other things that happen. Cartel behavior is very complex. Behavior of non-cartel members is also very complex. You also have dramatic changes in demand over time which can also affect the prices. So I don't have an analysis of that. Chairman DeWine. Dr. Hastings, do you? Ms. Hastings. I do not have an analysis of that. Chairman DeWine. Dr. Hastings, your testimony mentions that the Energy Information Administration of the Department of Energy collects data, but does not let academics have access to detailed data for research purposes. You also note that the Department of Energy does not have grant programs for economists to do research on energy policy, and as a result the economic research into energy policy suffers. Can you explain your thoughts about these two points maybe in more detail to us? Ms. Hastings. Sure. In order to examine many of the questions that we have been discussing here, an applied economist needs to be able to get access to detailed data that would allow them to understand better issues. For example, suppose I wanted to look at the following question: Was there strategic capacity entry into markets that were regulated by reformulated gasoline requirements? How did firm choose capacities to enter into these markets? Are we going to be ready to supply Milwaukee's market when they introduced a specific type of gasoline only for that market? Price volatility went up substantially there, so did mark- ups, and the number of firms supplying unbranded gasoline decreased substantially after that introduction. So suppose you might want to ask the question, how tight are markets? Did firms anticipate this tightness when setting capacities when they went into the market? In order to look at something like that, you would actually need to look at refinery-level production decisions, and there is no way to actually get that information even though the Energy Information Administration has such information. Typically, the only thing that one can get access to is very average data across the whole country or perhaps across a large part of the country on an aggregated basis, kind of monthly or yearly information. One of the things that maybe Mr. Kovacic might agree with me on is that there is a real need for sound empirical work in industrial organization to look at a lot of these questions. What is going on in natural gas? What is the effect of having these micro markets for different reformulated gasoline on prices, on competition, on who decides to enter and who doesn't? Those questions could be answered with good data. Currently, for the projects that I have done, it is incredibly difficult to get such detailed data and it takes a long time for an academic to get a hold of this data. Labor economists were in a similar position before the Census Bureau introduced a program that allowed labor economists to look at detailed data at the Census Bureau, confidential data on firm production decisions, for example, in manufacturing, on consumer behavior at the consumer level. What they did is introduce a program by which academic could apply to get access to the confidential data. It is a very stringent application process. Once they are granted this application, they actually have to go to the Census Bureau to use the data. They can't take confidential data off-site. But having this access, this program set-up, led to a huge boom in the sound empirical knowledge base of labor-related policies such as minimum wage laws, et cetera. Before that time, labor economists and labor issue policymakers were in the same position that many regulatory policymakers find themselves in today. Having a program modeled after what the Census Bureau did perhaps at the Energy Information Administration may lead to the same boom in knowledge and understanding of what is affecting these energy markets. Chairman DeWine. Dr. Cooper, we have heard testimony that it is too hard to open a new refinery due to such reasons as huge costs, environmental issues and local opposition. Do you disagree with these reasons? I mean, is that what the problem is? Mr. Cooper. It is not that I disagree with the reasons. It is that we have observed the closure of refineries, which were clearly industrial sites that supported those refineries. They were permitted to exist in those locations. They were closed, we know, as part of a business strategy to diminish capacity. So what we asked for several years ago was a study of those sites, a detailed analysis of why were they closed, what would it take to get them open, would there be people who are interested in reopening them. I think Dr. Hastings has sort of raised the interesting question, because the really interesting thing is that the Federal Trade Commission which studied the first price spike in 2000 actually asked exactly that question, the question she asked about: How do strategic decisions in the reconfiguration of refineries to meet the reformulation requirements affect supply in that market. The FTC asked that question not with the detailed data that she would like to have, but by interviewing all of the behaviors and the actors in those markets. And they concluded that, based on those interviews, strategic decisions had been made about how much capacity to have in a market that tightened them and cut off independents. Two years ago, the RAND Corporation did another study, based again not on the detailed data that she would like, but on the same sets of interviews, and they concluded exactly the same thing. So now we have the qualitative evidence on business decisions. Senator Wyden repeats his internal memos almost on a daily basis that those decisions were made. So the answer is you hear the excuse that it is too hard to locate, it is too expensive, but you look at the people who have studied it and you discover that this was intended to increase the profitability of refineries, that it was intended to accomplish certain sets of things. The definitive answer comes in a backward look around each of those price spikes with the data that Dr. Hastings has mentioned. But I submit that there is another explanation. Now, we are through 4 years of unhinging in the gasoline market and nobody has looked at this issue in detail repeatedly, aggressively. What we get is excuses rather than explanations and analysis. Chairman DeWine. Well, I want to thank you all very much for your testimony. It has been very, very helpful and it has been a very instructive hearing. We have had a lot of interest in this hearing and we do appreciate your testimony. This Subcommittee will continue to monitor this issue and we are going to continue to push forward and move forward on our bill. Thank you very much. [Whereupon, at 5:08 p.m., the Subcommittee was adjourned.] [Questions and answers and submissions for the record follow.] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.001 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.002 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.003 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.004 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.005 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.006 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.007 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.008 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.009 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.010 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.011 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.012 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.013 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.014 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.015 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.016 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.017 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.018 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.019 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.020 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.021 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.022 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.023 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.024 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.025 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.026 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.027 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.028 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.029 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.030 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.031 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.032 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.033 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.034 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.035 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.036 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.037 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.038 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.039 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.040 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.041 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.042 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.043 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.044 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.045 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.046 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.047 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.048 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.049 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.050 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.051 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.052 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.053 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.054 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.055 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.056 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.057 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.058 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.059 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.060 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.061 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.062 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.063 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.064 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.065 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.066 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.067 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.068 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.069 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.070 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.071 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.072 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.073 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.074 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.075 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.076 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.077 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.078 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.079 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.080 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.081 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.082 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.083 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.084 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.085 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.086 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.087 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.088 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.089 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.090 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.091 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.092 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.093 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.094 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.095 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.096 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.097 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.098 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.099 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.100 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.101 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.102 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.103 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.104 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.105 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.106 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.107 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.108 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.109 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.110 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.111 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.112 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.113 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.114 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.115 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.116 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.117 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.118 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.119 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.120 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.121 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.122 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.123 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.124 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.125 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.126 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.127 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.128 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.129 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.130 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.131 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.132 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.133 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5551.134