[House Hearing, 111 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] THE FUTURE OF HOUSING FINANCE: THE ROLE OF PRIVATE MORTGAGE INSURANCE ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON CAPITAL MARKETS, INSURANCE, AND GOVERNMENT SPONSORED ENTERPRISES OF THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED ELEVENTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION __________ JULY 29, 2010 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 111-149 ---------- U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 61-853 PDF WASHINGTON : 2010 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts, Chairman PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama MAXINE WATERS, California MICHAEL N. CASTLE, Delaware CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York PETER T. KING, New York LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina RON PAUL, Texas GARY L. ACKERMAN, New York DONALD A. MANZULLO, Illinois BRAD SHERMAN, California WALTER B. JONES, Jr., North GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York Carolina DENNIS MOORE, Kansas JUDY BIGGERT, Illinois MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts GARY G. MILLER, California RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri Virginia CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York JEB HENSARLING, Texas JOE BACA, California SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts J. GRESHAM BARRETT, South Carolina BRAD MILLER, North Carolina JIM GERLACH, Pennsylvania DAVID SCOTT, Georgia RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas AL GREEN, Texas TOM PRICE, Georgia EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina MELISSA L. BEAN, Illinois JOHN CAMPBELL, California GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin ADAM PUTNAM, Florida PAUL W. HODES, New Hampshire MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota KENNY MARCHANT, Texas RON KLEIN, Florida THADDEUS G. McCOTTER, Michigan CHARLES A. WILSON, Ohio KEVIN McCARTHY, California ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado BILL POSEY, Florida JOE DONNELLY, Indiana LYNN JENKINS, Kansas BILL FOSTER, Illinois CHRISTOPHER LEE, New York ANDRE CARSON, Indiana ERIK PAULSEN, Minnesota JACKIE SPEIER, California LEONARD LANCE, New Jersey TRAVIS CHILDERS, Mississippi WALT MINNICK, Idaho JOHN ADLER, New Jersey MARY JO KILROY, Ohio STEVE DRIEHAUS, Ohio SUZANNE KOSMAS, Florida ALAN GRAYSON, Florida JIM HIMES, Connecticut GARY PETERS, Michigan DAN MAFFEI, New York Jeanne M. Roslanowick, Staff Director and Chief Counsel Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania, Chairman GARY L. ACKERMAN, New York SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey BRAD SHERMAN, California TOM PRICE, Georgia MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts MICHAEL N. CASTLE, Delaware RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas PETER T. KING, New York CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma JOE BACA, California DONALD A. MANZULLO, Illinois STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts EDWARD R. ROYCE, California BRAD MILLER, North Carolina JUDY BIGGERT, Illinois DAVID SCOTT, Georgia SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York Virginia CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York JEB HENSARLING, Texas MELISSA L. BEAN, Illinois ADAM PUTNAM, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin J. GRESHAM BARRETT, South Carolina PAUL W. HODES, New Hampshire JIM GERLACH, Pennsylvania RON KLEIN, Florida JOHN CAMPBELL, California ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota JOE DONNELLY, Indiana THADDEUS G. McCOTTER, Michigan ANDRE CARSON, Indiana RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas JACKIE SPEIER, California KEVIN McCARTHY, California TRAVIS CHILDERS, Mississippi BILL POSEY, Florida CHARLES A. WILSON, Ohio LYNN JENKINS, Kansas BILL FOSTER, Illinois WALT MINNICK, Idaho JOHN ADLER, New Jersey MARY JO KILROY, Ohio SUZANNE KOSMAS, Florida ALAN GRAYSON, Florida JIM HIMES, Connecticut GARY PETERS, Michigan C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: July 29, 2010................................................ 1 Appendix: July 29, 2010................................................ 47 WITNESSES Thursday, July 29, 2010 Goldberg, Deborah, Hurricane Relief Program Director, the National Fair Housing Alliance................................. 16 Ratcliffe, Janneke, Associate Director, University of North Carolina Center for Community Capital, and Senior Fellow, Center for American Progress Action Fund....................... 11 Rodamaker, Marti Tomson, President, First Citizens National Bank, Mason City, Iowa, on behalf of the Independent Community Bankers of America (ICBA)...................................... 9 Sanders, Anthony B., Distinguished Professor of Finance, George Mason University, and Senior Scholar, The Mercatus Center...... 13 Sinks, Patrick, President and Chief Operating Officer, Mortgage Guaranty Insurance Corporation, on behalf of the Mortgage Insurance Companies of America................................. 7 Taylor, John, President and Chief Executive Officer, the National Community Reinvestment Coalition (NCRC)........................ 14 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Kanjorski, Hon. Paul E....................................... 48 Goldberg, Deborah............................................ 50 Ratcliffe, Janneke........................................... 60 Rodamaker, Marti Tomson...................................... 68 Sanders, Anthony B........................................... 81 Sinks, Patrick............................................... 89 Taylor, John................................................. 101 THE FUTURE OF HOUSING FINANCE: THE ROLE OF PRIVATE MORTGAGE INSURANCE ---------- Thursday, July 29, 2010 U.S. House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 2 p.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Paul E. Kanjorski [chairman of the subcommittee] presiding. Members present: Representatives Kanjorski, Sherman, Hinojosa, McCarthy of New York, Baca, Miller of North Carolina, Scott, Perlmutter, Donnelly, Adler; Garrett, Manzullo, Biggert, Capito, Hensarling, Neugebauer, Posey, and Jenkins. Chairman Kanjorski. This hearing of the Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises will come to order. Without objection, all members' opening statements will be made a part of the record. We meet today to continue our hearings about the future of housing finance. As we work to reform this complex system, we must learn more about private mortgage insurance and determine whether to make changes related to this product. We will therefore examine the structure, regulation, obligations, and performance of mortgage insurers. Since its creation more than a century ago, private mortgage insurance has, without question, allowed countless families to achieve the American dream of homeownership. It has also worked to safeguard taxpayers by providing a first layer of protection against foreclosure losses for lenders and for mortgages securitized by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Over the years, the industry has had to respond to significant economic changes. During the Great Depression, inadequate capital reserves and an inordinate amount of mortgage defaults drove every mortgage insurer into bankruptcy. As a result, the private mortgage insurance industry disappeared for more than 2 decades. Many, including me, feared the recent collapse of the housing bubble could produce a similar result. For a while, the industry teetered on the brink of extinction. Some mortgage insurers also sought, but never received, direct TARP assistance. We had good reason to worry. Historically, about 4 percent of mortgages guaranteed by mortgage insurers go into default in an average year. During this crisis however, approximately one in three mortgages made in 2006 and 2007 and insured by mortgage insurers are expected to go into foreclosure over the life of the loan. As a result, some estimate the industry will lose between $35 billion and $50 billion when all is said and done. Nevertheless, it appears the industry will survive because of some economic luck, many regulatory waivers, and its distinctive capital structure. In particular, mortgage insurers maintain contingency reserves of 50 cents on every premium dollar earned for 10 years. Thus, they build up capital in good times in order to pay out claims in rocky financial periods. While these countercyclical reserves are unique to the mortgage insurance industry, they provide an important model for Congress to consider in reforming the structure of the housing finance system. If Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had held similar reserves, both Enterprises may have weathered the recent financial hurricane much better. Still, the industry's performance has been far from perfect during this crisis. Some have questioned whether mortgage insurers held enough capital. Because they had to seek regulatory forbearance and curtail underwriting, this reduction in new business has probably slowed the recovery of our housing markets. Others have raised concerns about whether mortgage insurers have increased the government's cost related to the conservatorship of the Enterprises. Specifically, mortgage insurers only pay claims on foreclosed homes. They have no affirmative obligation to prevent foreclosures. As a result, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, rather than mortgage insurers, have often had to bear the financial losses related to loan modifications. Mortgage insurers exist to provide the first level of protection against losses and should not evade their responsibilities by contractual technicalities. We must review this arrangement. We also need to explore the present credit enhancement requirements under the charters of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. While the standard U.S. mortgage insurance policy indemnifies against losses created by a default in an amount equal to the first 20 to 30 percent of the lost loan principal, an Australian policy covers 100 percent of the home loan amount. Additionally, we should examine the consumer protection issues, the State regulation of the industry, and its indirect Federal regulation. The problems of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac resulted, in part, from the competing mandates of two regulators. As we reform our housing finance system, we may therefore want to streamline the oversight of mortgage insurers. In sum, all options for reforming our housing finance system are on the table, including those related to private mortgage insurance. I anticipate a fruitful and productive discussion around these and other issues today. I now recognize the gentleman from New Jersey for 4 minutes. Mr. Garrett. I thank the Chair and I thank the witnesses. And I thank the Chair for holding this important hearing on the PMI, or the private mortgage insurance industry. Now, unfortunately, because of the current Federal Government policies, their role right now is very limited, almost nonexistent. If I could direct your attention, following yesterday's chart, to the chart over here, this chart illustrates the percentage amount of new high loan to value, or LTV, loans that PMI writes and the percentage that the government backs. Currently, the Federal Government, as you see in the chart there, which you can say is the taxpayer, is underwriting 99 percent of every high LTV mortgage through FHA and GSEs. And so, this level of taxpayer support for the mortgage market, you must admit, is completely unsustainable and also unwise. We constantly hear that the government has to play this large role because the private sector is unable or maybe unwilling to reenter the market and provide the needed capital. But if you look at the details, you will see that is false. Over the last 2 years, private mortgage insurance companies have raised roughly $7.5 billion in new capital that could support $260 billion in new high LTV loans. However, the current marketplace only allows the PMI industry to support between maybe $40 billion or $50 billion of such loans. So what are some of the specific factors preventing more private capital from returning to the mortgage market through the private insurance? First are the changes in the loan limits for FHA that were made during the financial crisis. So if I could now direct your attention to my second chart, you will see that, before the crisis, the GSE loan limits were $417,000 and the FHA loan limits varied from 48 percent to 87 percent of the GSE limits based on the area median price. Now, after the changes, the FHA loan limits vary from 65 to 175 percent of that $417,000 house price number. So most of the attention in the debate over loan limits centers on the top- line limit in the high-cost areas, as you see on the chart there. Now, while that is important, it is not the only area where the private market is being basically squeezed out. And as you can see on the chart, down there at the bottom, the changes that were made essentially increase the loan limits for the FHA in the lower-cost areas, as well. What does this mean? This means that in areas where housing is less expensive, say in Nebraska, where the average median home price is $150,000, the FHA can insure loans up to $271,000. And that is almost 100 percent more than the average price in that low-cost area. So you have to ask yourself, why should the taxpayer be insuring mortgages that are almost double the average median home price in those lower-cost areas? And this is after mortgage prices have, I would just note, declined by 30 percent over the last 3 years. This area is prime territory for PMI to become more active while we roll back the taxpayers' support and liability. Another way that the government is prohibiting the return of private capital to our mortgage market is a rule instituted by the Federal Housing Finance Agency, and that is the loan level price adjustment. You see, when these fees were implemented, it was a turbulent time in the economy when housing prices were declining, particularly in distressed areas. However, it is 2 years later now, and we are seeing some encouraging signs that house prices are stabilizing, in addition to the fact that loans are being originated today at full documentation, amortized, and being prudentially underwritten. What I have been told is that Fannie and Freddie are not reserving these fees, so they are not providing any additional stabilizing effect. And I think these fees need to be given more attention, and Congress should more closely examine how these fees are pushing more people to FHA loans and away from conventional mortgages. Finally, just 2 months ago, Treasury Secretary Geithner told Congress, ``The government's role in the housing finance system and level of direct involvement would change,'' and that, ``The Administration is committed to encouraging private capital to return to the housing market.'' However, as you can see from my first chart, if he and President Obama are serious about restoring the housing market and relieving the taxpayer of the risk--and that is a pretty big risk, all the blue area-- they must return to traditional and more responsible methods of financing. The current loan limits, coupled with new and arbitrary fees by the GSEs make it impossible for the private capital to compete in the market. And this is exactly the opposite of what we want. The government has created a perverse incentive to provide private capital from being used in this market and relieve some of the burdens. So, Mr. Chairman, if we don't make changes, the FHA and GSEs will continuing to service a radically disproportionate share of the market, and they will collapse under their own weight, and we will face another taxpayer bailout from the GSEs and FHA. We need to shift the burden of mortgage finance off the backs of the American taxpayer and back onto the private investor. With that, I thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Kanjorski. The gentleman's time has expired. We now recognize the gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman, for 3 minutes. Mr. Sherman. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First, I should congratulate the survivors. To think that you could be in the business of insuring real estate loans in America at this time and still be here shows, as I think the chairman pointed out, perhaps some luck, but it also shows that both the regulators of the industry and the participants in it were prepared for the thousand-year flood. Very few other entities in our country are prepared for the thousand-year flood or even the hundred-year flood. Right now, the taxpayers are involved in the real estate market to a greater degree than in the past. Taxpayers are, therefore, taking an extraordinary percentage of the risk. I look forward to returning to a more traditional level of taxpayer involvement. And while I don't think that we can return to 2007, in terms of who can get some sort of mortgage, we don't want to return to 1920 either. And so, as the taxpayers play less of a role in absorbing the risk, we don't want to say, as in some European countries, ``Wait till you have a 40 percent downpayment, and then you can buy a home.'' Therefore, there is a need for a robust private mortgage insurance industry. One way to make sure that it is robust is to turn to the financial regulatory reform bill, where we require that the securitizer retain, I believe it is 5 percent, of the risk in that pool, unless the pool consists of plain vanilla, safe, not-risky, not-possibly-risky mortgages. Regulations have to be written that define what is ``plain vanilla.'' I suggest that plain vanilla includes both American vanilla and French vanilla--that is to say, that it includes not only mortgages which by themselves meet the criteria, but mortgages that meet the criteria of low risk to the investors when one factors in the fact that private mortgage insurance applies to some or all of the loans in that pool. To do otherwise would be to ignore economic reality, but, worse than that, it would be to deny a route to homeownership that does not put the taxpayer at risk. And certainly, we want the lowest possible taxpayer risk with the best possible opportunities for people to acquire a home. I yield back. Chairman Kanjorski. The gentleman's time has expired. We will now hear from the gentlelady from West Virginia, Ms. Capito, for 2 minutes. Mrs. Capito. Thank you. I would like to thank Chairman Kanjorski and Ranking Member Garrett for holding this hearing today. I look forward to hearing from our witnesses on the current status of private mortgage insurance and how we can work together to get a more vibrant private mortgage market, or to restore one, in any event. As my colleagues know, over the last few years, the Federal Housing Administration has dominated the residential mortgage market, providing federally backed mortgage insurance to borrowers. While FHA does have a role to play in the market, I am very concerned--we have had hearings, and I have made numerous statements about my concern over this recent expansion in market share, especially when the FHA is struggling financially. In order to have a healthy residential mortgage market, we must reduce FHA's market share and restore the private market. Earlier this year, the House passed much-needed FHA reform legislation that I believe will make significant improvements to the FHA program. While more reform may be needed, the legislation that we authored will give the FHA the ability to charge higher premiums. And this is important not only for the health of the FHA capital reserve fund, but it could also have the effect of leveling the playing field between FHA and the private mortgage insurance industry. I also have concerns with sections of the recently adopted Dodd-Frank financial reform bill and the effect it will have on the return of the private mortgage market. Included in this large package is a section requiring risk retention for mortgages but an exemption from this requirement for FHA mortgages. I was able to insert an amendment that will study the effect of this dichotomy and what effect it would have on the private mortgage market. I look forward to seeing these results to see if there is an unfair advantage for FHA and to level that playing field. Again, thank you, Mr. Chairman, for the hearing, and I look forward to the witnesses' testimony. Chairman Kanjorski. I thank the gentlelady from West Virginia. And now, we will hear from the gentleman from Georgia for 2 minutes, Mr. Scott. Mr. Scott. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is difficult to deny that the American dream remains today to own a home. That is the American dream. However, once that goal is achieved, it has become increasingly harder for some Americans to hold on to their homes and avoid foreclosure. Indeed, right now, as we speak, the foreclosure pipeline is full and getting overflowing. More access to mortgages, and thus homeownership, often coming to fruition due to use of private mortgage insurance is, ideally, a positive aspect of the current system. However, with job instability and unemployment rates reaching over 10 percent in much of the country, many Americans are finding it difficult to hold on to their homes despite their initial success. And when a homebuyer has less than 20 percent as a downpayment for their home, they are required to purchase a PMI policy, private mortgage insurance. This permits an individual the ability to afford a home who otherwise could not purchase a home. However, the use of subprime mortgages and jumbo loans contains obvious risk, namely traditionally higher default rates. And about a third of the mortgages made in 2006-2007 and insured by PMI's providers are expected to go into foreclosure during the life of the loan. We need to ensure that risky mortgages that are unsafe to potential lenders are avoided. The American dream of owning a home is something that I hope most Americans will certainly someday see fulfilled, but without the excessive risk that come with the use of certain PMIs. I hope to learn more about what PMIs are doing to reduce mortgage defaults and to protect potential homeowners. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much. We will now hear from the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Hensarling, for 3 minutes. Mr. Hensarling. I thank you, Mr. Chairman. Private mortgage insurance is clearly a rarity in our mortgage market: a private-sector solution for a private-sector challenge that, number one, actually worked, seemingly free of Federal handouts, bailouts, and also an industry that survived this market turmoil in relatively good shape, and also--I don't know how--it managed to survive competition with the GSE oligopoly. It seems like ancient history now, but there was a time, very recently in America's history, where one could actually get a mortgage on a home without having to go through their Federal Government. But now we know that Fannie and Freddie, which were left untouched, if nothing else, affirmed in the recent Dodd-Frank financial regulatory bill, now control roughly three-quarters of the new loan originations. FHA, whose own capital reserve losses are currently 75 percent below its statutory minimum, has roughly 20 percent of the market. We don't need to have a Ph.D. in economics to know that this is neither healthy nor sustainable. Again, private mortgage insurance has been an exception to the rule. It has been a very valuable, consumer-friendly, private-capital-backed tool, sold in a competitive market, that allows Americans to buy a home, and keep a home, without exposing taxpayers to risk. And this is a market, I think, that we would want to see flourish. Again, it appears, relatively speaking, to have weathered the recent economic crisis well. And, as I said earlier, these companies did not succumb to the temptation to take TARP money, bailout money from the Federal Government. And, in fact, we see that this is an industry that is back to raising capital in the private market, showing again that private-sector competition can work if we allow it to work. But, clearly, the private mortgage insurance market faces challenges. They were articulated very well by our ranking member from New Jersey. And so I continue to lament and decry the fact that this committee has yet to take up any type of reform of Fannie and Freddie, notwithstanding the fact that we have $150 billion of taxpayer-spent money, trillions of dollars of exposure. They continued to flourish, and yet we need this market to flourish. There is an old saying, ``If it ain't broke, don't fix it.'' Please don't bail it out; just let freedom work and allow this market to flourish. I yield back. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much. We will now go to our panel. Thank you very much for being present today. And, without objection, your written statements will be made a part of the record. You will each be recognized for a 5-minute summary of your testimony. Our first witness will be Mr. Patrick Sinks, president and chief operating officer of the Mortgage Guaranty Insurance Corporation, testifying on behalf of the Mortgage Insurance Companies of America. And I would like every panelist to respond to Mr. Hensarling's opening remarks. Is there no further need for a secondary market? Shall we just allow the existence of financing of mortgages to be made in the tradition prior to the 1929 crash? If you could give that answer, it would be very helpful, because we are certainly thinking about that. So, Mr. Sinks, start off, if you will. And I would like to hear this panel say that the government should get out of supporting the secondary market and probably do away with any involvement in the mortgage market other than you folks doing it all in the private sector. That would be a welcome relief for me, because I anticipate it would probably save me the next 2 years of my life. STATEMENT OF PATRICK SINKS, PRESIDENT AND CHIEF OPERATING OFFICER, MORTGAGE GUARANTY INSURANCE CORPORATION, ON BEHALF OF THE MORTGAGE INSURANCE COMPANIES OF AMERICA Mr. Sinks. Let me go with my prepared remarks, and I will get to answering your question. First, thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Ranking Member Garrett. I appreciate the opportunity to testify on behalf of the Mortgage Insurance Companies of America, the trade association representing the private mortgage insurance industry. Mortgage insurance enables borrowers to responsibly buy homes with less than a 20 percent downpayment. Many of these borrowers are first-time or lower-income homebuyers. Since 1957, private mortgage insurance has helped 25 million families buy homes. Today, about 9 percent of all outstanding mortgages have private mortgage insurance. This afternoon, I would like to make four important points. First, mortgage insurance is essential to ensuring mortgages are both affordable and sustainable. These goals are not mutually exclusive, and such loans are vital to the housing recovery. Mortgage insurance is in the first-loss position on individual high-ratio loans, and, as a result, private-sector capital is at risk. If a borrower defaults and that default results in a claim, mortgage insurers will typically pay the investor 20 to 25 percent of the loan amount. Because we are in the first-loss position, mortgage insurers' incentives are aligned with both the borrowers and the investors. As a result, mortgage insurers work to ensure that the home is affordable both at the time of purchase and throughout the years of homeownership. My second point: The mortgage insurance regulatory model works. The mortgage insurance regulatory model has been in place for over 50 years. This model has enabled the industry to write both new business and meet its claim obligations through many different economic environments, including some severe housing downturns such as we are currently experiencing. The most important element of the model is that it requires capital to be maintained through one of three reserves, known as the contingency reserve. Private MIs are required to put 50 percent of every premium dollar into a contingency reserve for 10 years so adequate resources are there to pay claims. This, in effect, causes capital to be set aside during good times such that it is available in bad times. It serves to provide capital in a countercyclical manner. Since 2007, the private mortgage insurance industry has paid over $20 billion in claims. In fact, mortgage insurers have paid $14.5 billion in claims and receivables to the GSEs, which is equivalent to 10 percent of the amount taxpayers have paid to the GSEs to date. My third point: The private mortgage insurers are well- capitalized and can help with the housing recovery. Not only does the MI industry have ample regulatory capital, but it has attracted capital, even during these difficult times. We have raised $7.4 billion in capital through new capital raises and asset sales, and a new entrant has raised a further $600 million since the mortgage crisis began. In fact, based on industry estimates, the MI industry has sufficient capital to increase our total insurance exposure by $261 billion a year for the next 3 calendar years. If this additional volume would be realized, it would mean that approximately 1.3 million additional mortgages would be insured in each of those years. Many of these new, prudently underwritten insured mortgages would go to low- and moderate- income and first-time homebuyers. My final point: Mortgage insurers are committed to helping borrowers stay in their homes. Because mortgage insurance companies have their own capital at risk in a first-loss position, we have very clear incentives to mitigate our losses by taking action to avoid foreclosures. We have a long history of working with servicers and community groups to help keep borrowers in their homes. Mortgage insurers have fully participated in the Administration's loss-mitigation programs and other programs. These combined efforts have resulted in over 374,000 completed workouts from 2008 through the first quarter of 2010 by the MI industry, covering $73.8 billion in mortgage loans. In summary, the private mortgage insurance model has worked over many years. We have capital sufficient to meet the needs of the market, and we plan to continue to play a crucial role in the future of housing finance. Thank you for this opportunity to testify, and I will be happen to answer any questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Sinks can be found on page 89 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you. We will now have our next witness, Ms. Marti Rodamaker, president of the First Citizens National Bank of Iowa, testifying on behalf of the Independent Community Bankers of America. Ms. Rodamaker? STATEMENT OF MARTI TOMSON RODAMAKER, PRESIDENT, FIRST CITIZENS NATIONAL BANK, MASON CITY, IOWA, ON BEHALF OF THE INDEPENDENT COMMUNITY BANKERS OF AMERICA (ICBA) Ms. Rodamaker. Thank you very much, Chairman Kanjorski, Ranking Member Garrett, and members of the subcommittee. First Citizens National Bank in Mason City, Iowa, is a nationally chartered community bank with $925 million in assets. I am pleased to represent the community bankers and ICBA's nearly 5,000 members at this important hearing on ``The Future of Housing Finance: The Role of Private Mortgage Insurance.'' Residential mortgage lending, supported by conservative underwriting, is a staple of community banking, and mortgage insurance is an indispensable risk-management tool. The MI business model has been tested by the housing crisis, with repercussions for all participants in the lending process. I expect that it will emerge from the crisis looking significantly different than it has in the past, as a result of business imperatives but also as a result of policy decisions made by Congress. Any reform of MI must be made in coordination with the reform of other elements of housing finance, notably the GSEs. ICBA hopes to participate in all aspects of housing finance reform. Our members and their customers have a great deal at stake in the outcome. MI is used by lenders to insure mortgages of greater than 80 percent loan to value. It enables lenders to reach those borrowers who cannot make a 20 percent downpayment, which is a sizable portion of today's market. These borrowers include the younger, first-time homebuyers who have traditionally used MI, as well as current homeowners who don't have enough home equity to sell and make a 20 percent downpayment on their next home. Most Americans have also experienced a drain in their savings accounts, depleting yet another source of downpayments. MI will be used to serve a broader segment of homebuyers than ever before. Without MI, the housing recovery will take longer. With MI, the recovery can be managed prudently. From the lenders' perspective, perhaps the most significant function of MI is to allow for the sale of high loan-to-value loans to Fannie or Freddie, who require insurance for such loans. Fannie and Freddie provide secondary market access and critical funding to community bank mortgage lending. Lenders who hold high LTV loans in portfolio also require mortgage insurance because our regulators apply a higher capital charge to uninsured high LTV loans. In sum, the only practical means of making high loan-to- value loans, whether they are sold or held in portfolio, is with the credit enhancement provided by MI. If prudently underwritten, high loan-to-value loans can't be made, the market will take longer to recover, consumer options will be more limited, and banks will have fewer lending opportunities. Unfortunately for all parties, the MI market was severely disrupted during the housing crisis, and the MI companies have tightened their underwriting requirements in response to the market conditions. As a consequence, MI underwriting has fallen out of lockstep with GSE underwriting. Before the crisis, approval by Fannie or Freddie implied approval by the insurer--a linkage that greatly facilitated the loan processing. The breakdown of this linkage has impeded the recovery. We need to achieve a new consensus in which lenders, mortgage insurers, and Fannie and Freddie are all using the same underwriting and appraisals standards. This new consensus may not be achievable until the housing market stabilizes. In addition to tightening the underwriting of new loans, the MI companies are also disputing some claims. Denied MI claims on defaulted loans sold to GSE have become increasingly common and generally result in a buy-back request from Fannie or Freddie to the original lender. While some of these claim denials are supportable, many are based on questionable challenges to the original underwriting or appraisal. As a banker, I understand the reality of higher defaults and losses during difficult economic times. It is part of the price of doing business. However, high levels of denied claims and GSE buy-back requests have put an additional strain on all market participants, including community banks. In closing, ICBA appreciates the opportunity to participate in this subcommittee's review of MI. The recent dislocation in the MI industry has only underscored the critical role that it plays in housing finance. Restoration of a strong and competitive MI industry will be a critical part of the housing recovery. We would be pleased to comment on any proposals to reform MI that emerge from this subcommittee, and we hope to have the opportunity to share our views on other aspects of housing finance reform, as well. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Ms. Rodamaker can be found on page 68 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much, Ms. Rodamaker. Next, we will hear from Ms. Janneke Ratcliffe, associate director of the University of North Carolina Center for Community Capital, and senior fellow at the Center for American Progress Action Fund. Ms. Ratcliffe? STATEMENT OF JANNEKE RATCLIFFE, ASSOCIATE DIRECTOR, UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA CENTER FOR COMMUNITY CAPITAL, AND SENIOR FELLOW, CENTER FOR AMERICAN PROGRESS ACTION FUND Ms. Ratcliffe. Good afternoon, Chairman Kanjorski, Ranking Member Garrett, and members of the subcommittee. I am Janneke Ratcliffe, associate director at the UNC Center for Community Capital and a senior research fellow at the Center for American Progress Action Fund. I am honored to have the opportunity to share my thoughts about the role of private mortgage insurance, an industry that plays a key part in facilitating homeownership. Indeed, a discussion on the role of private MI must begin by stressing the importance of giving families the opportunity to buy homes when they have not yet accumulated enough wealth to make a big downpayment, which is what private mortgage insurance exists to do. To put that in context, to make a 20 percent downpayment on the median home sold in the United States in 2009 required $34,000, which is more than the annual earnings of 35 percent of U.S. households. When done right, high loan-to-value mortgages are essential for the U.S. housing system to offer opportunities and a pathway to the middle class. And the best way to put this opportunity within reach for more first-time and minority and low-income households is to reduce the downpayment barrier. Many of us started up the homeownership ladder with a modest downpayment and a loan made possible because of some form of mortgage insurance, be it private or a Federal Housing Administration or Veterans Administration program. In an average year, in fact, between a quarter and a third of all the mortgages made are to families with less than 20 percent equity. And among these are the families who will later buy another house, perhaps yours or mine. We have ample evidence that the risks associated with high LTV lending can be managed. One example is the Community Advantage Program that has funded affordable mortgages to 50,000 lower-income, low-downpayment borrowers nationwide. The results: Defaults are low, and the median borrower accumulated $20,000 in equity through the end of 2009. This is just one example of how high LTV lending makes sense for lenders and for households when done right, in this case through fixed-rate, 30-year amortizing mortgages underwritten for ability to repay. The private mortgage insurance industry provides on a larger scale another answer to the right way to support high loan-to-value lending. An industry built on insuring mortgages with low downpayments has weathered the mortgage crisis, paid substantial claims without Federal support, and even managed to attract new capital. Three principles contribute to this outcome. First, as we have heard, are the countercyclical reserving requirements imposed by State insurance regulators. These days, we hear a lot about regulatory failures, but here is one story of regulatory success. The system of State regulation, combined with Federal oversight, played a critical role in maintaining systemic stability, and its principal elements should be preserved. Second are the standards set by mortgage insurers themselves, because their interests are aligned with keeping the borrower in the home. From underwriting through foreclosure prevention, they live or die by whether they get this right. And a third virtue of the mortgage insurance industry lies in its role as a pooler of risk. Mortgage insurance companies smooth risk out more efficiently, across multiple lenders, across securities, regions, and by reserving across time periods. In this way, they bring efficiency and stability to the entire system. But mortgage insurance only covers a portion of the high loan-to-value loan market. During the bubble, less regulated alternatives became increasingly cheap relative to the institutional monoline sources, both primary mortgage insurance and FHA. Lack of consistent oversight enabled risk to be laid off where no or low capital requirements existed. At the time, this looked like innovation, but in hindsight it was recklessness. The lesson learned is that an effective mortgage finance system must consider total system capital at risk on each loan, inhibit capital arbitrage, and prevent a race to the bottom. Justifiably, private mortgage insurance has special consideration in the GSE charter and is a qualified residential mortgage factor to offset risk-retention requirements. But this implies that this industry will play a critical role in determining who gets access to homeownership. This is no small concern because today, barriers are actually growing, particularly for those households and communities hit by the full cycle: first, by lack of access to capital; then, by subprime lending; then, by foreclosures; and now, by income losses and tight credit. Rebuilding will require the affirmative involvement of all market participants. Going forward, PMI insurance should have an important role in the market, but let me suggest three provisos. First, policymakers should maintain a level regulatory playing field, one that considers long-term, systemwide risk-taking capacity. Second, mortgage insurers must be held accountable to public policy goals of enabling access to safe mortgage products under affordable and transparent terms that do not unfairly handicap some market segments. Finally, recognizing that some markets may still go underserved, it is important to ensure alternative channels exist for innovation and expanding constructive credit to those markets. Thank you for the opportunity to testify, and I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Ms. Ratcliffe can be found on page 60 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you, Ms. Ratcliffe. Next, we will hear from Mr. Anthony B. Sanders, distinguished professor of finance at George Mason University, and senior scholar at The Mercatus Center at George Mason University. Mr. Sanders? STATEMENT OF ANTHONY B. SANDERS, DISTINGUISHED PROFESSOR OF FINANCE, GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY, AND SENIOR SCHOLAR, THE MERCATUS CENTER Mr. Sanders. Mr. Chairman and distinguished members of the subcommittee, my name is Anthony B. Sanders, and I am a distinguished professor of finance at George Mason University and a senior scholar at The Mercatus Center. It is an honor to testify before you today. The Federal Government purchases or insures over 90 percent of the residential mortgages originated in the United States. The proliferation of government programs for homeownership purchase and insurance of low-downpayment loans by the GSEs and tax incentives for homeownership were largely responsible for the housing bubble that occurred in the 2001 to 2006 period. The problem is that public policy and risk management are intertwined, resulting in bubbles and devastating bursts. And the most vulnerable households are the ones who are most often hurt. The affordable housing crisis cycle must be broken. Even though trillions of dollars were pumped into the housing market during the last decade, homeownership rates rose from 67.8 percent in 2001, peaked at 69 percent in 2004, and declined down to 67.4 percent in 2009, less than where they started in 2001. The United States has comparable homeownership rates to other G-7 countries, even though they do not have entities like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Given that there is a reasonable housing alternative in the form of renting, rather than owning, it is time to rethink the crisis cycle. We can break the cycle by getting private mortgage insurance and banks back in the game and downsize the government involvement in the housing finance area. The problem is that the Federal Government offers explicit guarantees on residential mortgages, which makes it difficult for the private sector to compete. This crowding-out phenomenon is exacerbated by the raising of the loan limits after the stimulus for the three GSEs to $729,750 in certain areas, which has effectively crowded out the private insurance market. My recommendations are as follows: Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the FHA must downsize their market shares to open up the market for the private sector again. This can be done in the short run by curtailing the government purchase and insurance of low-downpayment mortgages and a lowering of loan limits to pre-stimulus levels at first and then a gradual phaseout of government insurance. Second, alternatives to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, such as covered bonds and improvement to private-label securitization, must be implemented. In order for capital to return to the market, it is necessary to restore confidence. The newly created Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection is generating significant uncertainty in the minds of investors as to how this agency will function. Congress should pass clear guidelines and provide assurances that limit the reach of this new agency. Fourth, the long-run structure of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac must be resolved as soon as possible. However, true changes are not possible if the Administration and Congress insist that there must be an explicit guarantee. I do not see any way that the explosive combination of public policy and prudent risk management can work together. It failed in the housing bubble and crash, and nothing has been done to prevent this from occurring over and over again. Thank you for the opportunity to share my thoughts with you. [The prepared statement of Dr. Sanders can be found on page 81 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much, Mr. Sanders. We will now hear from our next witness, Mr. John Taylor, president and chief executive officer of the National Community Reinvestment Coalition. Mr. Taylor? STATEMENT OF JOHN TAYLOR, PRESIDENT AND CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER, THE NATIONAL COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT COALITION (NCRC) Mr. Taylor. Thank you, Chairman Kanjorski, Ranking Member Garrett, and other distinguished members of this subcommittee. And congratulations to those members of this subcommittee who voted for and passed the Dodd-Frank regulatory reform bill. I think that effort was owed to the American public and bodes well for consumers across the land. Private mortgage insurance also serves a vital part of America's system of mortgage finance by protecting lenders from losses associated with mortgage defaults. Done responsibly, private mortgage insurance can help those working their way up the economic ladder to achieve the American dream of homeownership. Coupled with the Community Reinvestment Act, private mortgage insurance can help underserved people, including minorities, to gain access to safe, sound, and sustainable mortgages. Today, the business of mortgage finance has become the business of the Federal Government. Without FHA, VA, Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac, most mortgage lending in America today would not occur. NCRC is very concerned that the Federal Government is increasingly positioning itself as the sole gatekeeper to homeownership and mortgage lending in America. And much of this is done with the requirement of a government guarantee. It is imperative that we increase the role of the free market in producing and securitizing mortgages. The private mortgage insurance companies assist in this goal while remaining unsubsidized, without TARP funds--not that they didn't apply--and without government guarantees. The capitalization and reserve requirements placed on private mortgage insurance companies by the government is a perfect example of how government regulation, coupled with free-market enterprise, can result in healthy and profitable business. In spite of our great recession and the collapse of the mortgage banking sector in America, all the private mortgage insurance companies remain standing, indeed have even expanded their ranks. Having said all this, there are some improvements that I hope this subcommittee and the Congress might consider making to this industry. First, regulation of the private mortgage insurance industry occurs on a State level. We believe the industry and consumers would be better served by having Federal standards regulating this industry. Consumers, in particular, would benefit from having these new standards under the purview of the new Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection. Second, data currently available on the performance of the private mortgage insurance companies is limited and raises more questions than it answers. The FFIEC prepares disclosure, aggregate, and national aggregate data reports on the private mortgage insurance activity. To their credit, the private mortgage insurance companies voluntarily provide data on the disposition of applications for mortgage insurance using some categories of information used on the HMDA, the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act. In preparation for this hearing, NCRC analyzed the voluntarily provided data. There is enough evidence of disparity in the mortgage insurance access between Whites, Blacks, and Hispanics to suggest that Congress should enhance the data collection and increase the transparency on the performance of this industry. This data collection should be mandatory and include data on cost of premiums and amount of losses incurred by the various private mortgage insurance companies. Such additional information will assist us all in determining whether the denial disparities are based on sound business practices or have some basis in discriminatory practices. This will ensure fairness in that industry. NCRC would recommend that the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection make recommendations on reasonable pricing standards that the private mortgage insurance company industry can employ to ensure that premiums are not keeping working-class, responsible borrowers out of the homeownership market. Further, we should explore the possibility of the lender sharing in the cost of the private mortgage insurance, since the benefit of insurance really directly accrues to the lender. Next, when a homeowner has reached the 20 percent equity threshold of ownership in their home, there should be a seamless and automatic allowance for borrowers to withdraw from the mortgage insurance product that is no longer necessary for these borrowers. Currently, some lenders do a better job than others at alerting consumers about their having reached that 20 percent threshold. Finally, the appraisal methods, including automated valuation models, used by many private mortgage insurance companies ought to be scrutinized. We should learn once and for all from the injury done to our system of mortgage finance by shoddy, quick, and inaccurate appraisals. In conclusion, private mortgage insurance is vitally important to our national system of mortgage finance and can help refuel our economy by expanding opportunities for safe and sound mortgage lending to those who do not have the ability to make a 20 percent downpayment. Let me close by saying, to answer your question, Mr. Chairman, I do believe we need a federally sponsored securitization sector. And I think that what is prohibiting, really, the private sector from being successful today, more than anything, more than anything we will talk about today, is the fact that people no longer trust foreign governments, companies' pension funds. They don't trust America now to come and invest in here. We have to change that. And I think the law you just passed, more transparency, more accountability, sends a very strong message to the world that it is safe to come back and reinvest in America. Because the banks and everybody else do not have the money unless we have investors. So hopefully, we are beginning to turn the corner and say to the world, our economy is stable, we are bottoming out on housing prices and housing values, and there is more accountability, it is safe to come back to America and reinvest in America's economy. And I think that is going to help to, as much as anything, boost the private sector in being able to provide mortgages and to have the mortgage insurance companies support that. [The prepared statement of Mr. Taylor can be found on page 101 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much, Mr. Taylor. Our last witness will be Ms. Deborah Goldberg, hurricane relief program director of the National Fair Housing Alliance. Ms. Goldberg? STATEMENT OF DEBORAH GOLDBERG, HURRICANE RELIEF PROGRAM DIRECTOR, THE NATIONAL FAIR HOUSING ALLIANCE Ms. Goldberg. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Kanjorski, Ranking Member Garrett, and members of the subcommittee, I want to thank you for the opportunity to testify here today on behalf of the National Fair Housing Alliance. In the face of our current foreclosure crisis, some say that we put too much emphasis on homeownership. We at NFHA take a different view. We continue to believe that homeownership, done right, can be a viable path to building wealth and economic security. It is one of our most promising tools for eliminating the enormous racial and ethnic wealth disparities in our country. But we need to understand how to make homeownership both achievable and sustainable, and also understand clearly the forces that have worked to undermine sustainability in recent years. Only then can we avoid repeating our past mistakes. In this context, we believe that private mortgage insurance has a very important role to play in expanding access to homeownership for those with limited wealth, particularly people of color. The requirement for a 20 percent downpayment on a mortgage is a big barrier for many people who could otherwise be very successful homeowners. Private mortgage insurance makes it possible for families with limited wealth to put less money down and still get a mortgage. This benefits the homeowner, the lender, the investor, and, of course, the private mortgage insurance company. You asked whether additional consumer protections are needed with respect to the private mortgage insurance industry. And one concern for us is the fact that PMI is sold directly to the lender and not to the borrower. This means that borrowers can't comparison-shop for the best deal. It also gives insurers an incentive to make the product as profitable as possible for their customers, the lenders, rather than as cost-effective as possible for borrowers. A situation like this calls out for greater transparency and oversight than we have now in the private mortgage insurance market. In other markets, this kind of situation has opened the door to adverse practices and discriminatory treatment. And we urge the subcommittee to make sure that is not happening in this market. Another issue of great concern to us, from both a fair- housing and a broader consumer perspective, is the use of credit scores for underwriting and pricing private mortgage insurance. We have long had concerns about the impact of credit-scoring models on people of color, who have lacked access to the kind of mainstream financial services that help boost scores. Recently, we have seen credit scores drop even when consumers continue to make all of their payments on time, as lenders lower credit limits in order to minimize their risk exposure. And research suggests that certain loan features-- research that one of my co-panelists has done--certain loan features, such as prepayment penalties and adjustable interest rates, along with loan distribution channels, are more important in explaining loan performance than are borrower characteristics. But credit-scoring models do not make this distinction between risky borrowers and risky products. This places borrowers of color, whose communities have been targeted for risky products, at a tremendous disadvantage. We urge the subcommittee to look at this question in more detail. It has profound implications for the future, not just for access to PMI, but also for many other aspects of people's lives. The Federal Government has a unique relationship to the PMI industry, having done quite a bit to create a market for this product. One example that has been cited by several of my co- panelists is the charter requirement that prohibits the GSEs from purchasing loans with LTVs above 80 percent unless those loans carry a credit enhancement. The recently enacted Dodd-Frank Wall Street reform bill also creates a carveout for private mortgage insurance. As a result, it is our view that the Federal Government has both an opportunity and an obligation to make sure that the industry operates in a manner that is fair and nondiscriminatory. In particular, Congress, the public, and ultimately the industry, as well, would all benefit from having access to more detailed information about how private mortgage insurers operate. This includes information about underwriting standards and also where, to whom, and at what price mortgage insurance is being offered. It could also include information about the impact of mortgage insurance on loss-mitigation outcomes for borrowers facing foreclosure. This is a question the subcommittee raised, but there is no publicly available information on which to base an answer. Better data on a range of issues related to private mortgage insurance and its impact on the housing finance system would put us all in a better position to have an informed debate about what the system of the future should look like. You can make such data available, and we urge you to consider doing so. Thank you for the opportunity to testify here today. I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Ms. Goldberg can be found on page 50 of the appendix.] Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much, Ms. Goldberg. I guess I am the first one on the firing pad today, so let me go back and just see if I can pick up. Could everybody on the panel, just have a show of hands, who would support a secondary market? Okay. Oh, a slow ``yes.'' Mr. Sanders. Clarification. Chairman Kanjorski. I think the impression that I received, at least, from the opening statement of Mr. Hensarling, was that we ought to really do away with the secondary market and government involvement therein. And I think there is a large portion of the American population who are taking that sort of tea-party effect--I am sorry, I didn't want to suggest that comes from a particular element--but that they follow that thought process. And on the other end-- Mr. Garrett. Constitutionalist? Is that the word you are looking for? Chairman Kanjorski. Constitutionalist? I did not see that in the Constitution, but you may be right. This morning, I had the pleasure of sitting in on a briefing from Dr. Shiller and Dr. Zandi, which went over and explained the real estate market for the last 40, 50, 60 years, or perhaps 100 years, which was quite revealing and interesting, insofar as the bubble that occurred in 2006 to about 2009 was extraordinary and a one-time deal in the last 100 years. Other than that, real estate was in a relatively staid and standard position without great fluctuation. And, quite frankly, neither one of them attributed any particular action to that, other than the changing from risk investment in the stock market in equities to risk investment in the real estate market, for one reason or another. And they looked at it as the bubble in the early 1990's and late 1990's and then moving into real estate in the 2004 or 2005 period. That all being said, everybody is trying to do a postmortem here and find a guilty party. I thought we had one, but that slow motion of the hand said we did not. In reality, I think we all have to accept the fact that the real estate market is a fundamental part of the American economy. If the real estate market doesn't stabilize and then improve, we do not have a great deal of hope for stabilization of unemployment and for a good recovery to the middle-class economy that we were blessed with for almost 20 years. Would the panel agree? And if you disagree, speak up as to what your disagreement is. Nobody heard my question, so they don't know whether they want to commit. Does George Mason want to speak to that? Mr. Sanders. Oh, the guy from George Mason, yes. Thank you. I agree, the real estate market is a fundamental part of the U.S. economy. I disagree with Mr. Shiller and Mr. Zandi. Again, if you look clearly at the evidence, when we pumped trillions of dollars into the housing market over the 2000's and we, at the same time, lowered downpayment requirements, rates fell, etc., you were going to get a housing bubble, period. And I don't understand why I haven't talked with Mr. Shiller before about this, and-- Chairman Kanjorski. If I may interrupt you for a second, though, not too far from where you are sitting, if you moved over to Ms. Ratcliffe's position, about 5 years ago Alan Greenspan testified before our full committee, and he was sitting right in her seat. And he said he was not worried at all about a real estate bubble; it just was not going to occur, did not occur, and it was nothing for us or anyone else in the country to worry about. That was in 2005. Precipitous, because at that precise moment very strange things were beginning to happen in the real estate market, and all of us were a little worried. But, not having the expertise of Dr. Greenspan, we relied on him for his expert opinion. Subsequent to that, he has apologized for having been dead- wrong on the issue. And I think that shows a big man and a good man, but, nevertheless, he was wrong. You do not feel that he was wrong? Or do you feel it does not matter? I am not sure I get the-- Mr. Sanders. Oh, do I think Alan Greenspan was wrong? Two reasons: one, he confessed he was wrong; and two, when all of us looked at the housing prices going up like this, and simultaneously Freddie and Fannie's retained portfolio is going up about the same speed, we all knew that something has to give. Why Mr. Greenspan didn't choose to recognize that is--who knows? Maybe he thought it was a new plateau. But I can guarantee you other people at the time were scared about what was going on in the market. Chairman Kanjorski. Yes, sir? Mr. Taylor. Chairman Greenspan was the ultimate libertarian. And perhaps he was locked into that ideology as a way of not being able to respond to what was going on. The real estate market is absolutely an important part of our economy, but we need a system of checks and balances. And if we learn nothing else from this hearing today, it is the system of checks and balances over the mortgage insurance industry that required capitalization of 25 to one. Fifty cents of every premium dollar that came in was put into a reserve so that they could survive. Mr. Hensarling said earlier--I am sorry he is not here; I wanted to get to agree with most of what he said, and that is a rare occurrence for me--that it appears the MIs somehow weathered the storm. It wasn't ``somehow.'' It was because we had regulation that required them to be adequately capitalized. Had we done that with the rest of the industry, and if there was enough oversight of the rest of the industry, we could have avoided a lot of the problems and still had a healthy real estate practice. Chairman Kanjorski. So I am supposed to conclude that regulation may sometimes be a good thing? Mr. Taylor. Yes. Chairman Kanjorski. In this era, I do not often hear that. Ms. Ratcliffe, you were shaking your head. Do you agree with that position? Ms. Ratcliffe. I entirely agree. There are a couple of dimensions that are worth exploring. One is the issue of regulatory capital requirements being inconsistent across the industry that led lending to occur in places there were no capital or very cheap capital requirements that led to much of the bubble. One of the great ironies, I think, given the discussion we are having today, is the issue of AIG who, in their credit default swap business helped inflate the bubble and needed substantial billions of dollars of government support. They are the parent company of a mortgage insurance company who followed these capitalization rules when they took credit risk on mortgages. Right there within one company, you see this example of capital arbitrage that we need to make adjustments for in this. Thinking about the secondary market reform, we have to think beyond whatever quasi-government agency you have to the rest of the playing field. Chairman Kanjorski. Should there be a bar to the nexus of those two companies in the same structure? Ms. Ratcliffe. I'm sorry? Chairman Kanjorski. Should there be a bar to having a nexus or relations between those companies existing in the same structure? Ms. Ratcliffe. Again, I think if we set common capital requirements, that wouldn't necessarily be necessary. Mr. Sinks. If I may take a shot at that, not speaking on behalf of AIG, but speaking on behalf of the mortgage insurance companies, I would submit there is a bar. The mortgage insurance companies are controlled by the State insurance departments, and they have the ability to control what goes in and out of that company. So despite the fact it was part of the very broad AIG organization, I would submit, again in a general sense, that capital was, in fact, walled off and the policyholders were protected. Chairman Kanjorski. Very good. I now recognize the gentleman from New Jersey, since I have also taken additional time. Mr. Garrett. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me start, a quick show of hands, how many think anyone who wants to get a loan, a home loan, should have to, in one way or other, go through the Federal Government, rely upon the Federal Government? Okay. And how many think that the Federal Government should essentially be backstopping or underwriting where we are, around 99 percent of loans, high LTV loans or otherwise? Good. So somewhere in between then. All right. On your point, Mr. Taylor, that Mr. Greenspan is the ultimate libertarian; I don't know. A lot of people now in retrospect say his monetary policy was one of the reasons that brought us to that bubble that Mr. Sanders was speaking to before. And I think most libertarians would say that the central bank should not be playing that role. But you can debate that. Professor Sanders, you saw that chart, that is the chart. The blue is showing where 99 percent of the high LTVs are being underwritten by you and I, and everybody else in the room, the American taxpayer. Is that where we want to be? Are you concerned about this? Mr. Sanders. The answer is it is not where we want to be, and we should be extremely concerned about this. Again, the same thing I said before, if Genworth or MGIC or one of the other private mortgage insurance companies want to go out and underwrite a 3 percent down mortgage, and they are going to do it and suffer the consequences of their folly if it fails, so be it. Again, as I said, Fannie, Freddie, and the FHA have this combustible joint process where they are doing public policy and risk management. And guess which one wins out, so we end up with a market capture of 99 percent. In addition, although you didn't bring it up, if we take a look at the percentage, 99 percent and over LTV occurring now, you have all of the GSEs, doing about 40 percent of their business, is low LTV lending. Once again, I sympathize with all of the people who say that they would like to see homeowners get that. You just have to understand, that is bubble creating. That creates another one of these incredible wave-type effects, and it is not good for the stability of the economy. Mr. Garrett. Mr. Taylor, you talked about the adverse market fees? Mr. Taylor. Am I going to get to respond this time? Mr. Garrett. Yes. You discussed the adverse market fees that the GSEs are charging. Can you elaborate on the fees and what that all means? Mr. Taylor. Yes. They have defined that they get to charge 25 basis points in addition to what they define as adverse markets anywhere in the country. We are actually quite concerned about that. Mr. Garrett. Why? Mr. Taylor. Because we think it is unfair. The notion that because somebody lives in a declining market, that somehow they have to pay a premium seems fairly anti-American to me. You ought to be able to judge the person on their capability, their individual financial status, and their creditworthiness and so on, not by the neighborhood they necessarily live in. In fact, that is precisely why we created the Fair Housing Act and other laws to prohibit these kinds of discriminatory practices just based on geography. Mr. Garrett. What would the GSEs say if they were sitting next to you? Mr. Taylor. That they have an incredibly bad balance sheet, and they are doing everything they can to create strong, positive cash flow that will, when they separate out all of those bad assets, leave them standing. Mr. Garrett. Two points. Your one point you make is: Yes, that may be true, but they are making it on the backs of those people. That is your point. Mr. Taylor. I agree, yes. I agree with my point. Mr. Garrett. I just wanted to get that out. The second point here is, how are they using those fees? Mr. Taylor. I think they are using it to create profitability for the GSEs, and hopefully sustain themselves into the future. I'm not sure if that is getting at your point. Mr. Garrett. Yes. You can make the argument, hey, we have a bad balance sheet and we want to put this aside as reserves. Mr. Taylor. They are also concentrating on the safest and the easy to make--they have raised their credit scores in terms of who they are willing to make loans to. They are doing stuff that essentially is survival stuff for them. Mr. Garrett. Ms. Ratcliffe? Ms. Ratcliffe. I wanted to add that not only is it not fair to apply those kinds of pricing factors, but it is procyclical. That is exactly what we have been talking about. If you layer additional costs on in weaker times and take them out in good times, you end up exacerbating upsides and downsides. Mr. Garrett. I didn't think about that part of it. Thank you. Chairman Kanjorski. In fairness, before I recognize the next individual, the chart was beautiful, Mr. Garrett, except I do want to indicate it is misleading, because I think the chart showed 99 percent or 97 percent, but this morning, Inside Mortgage Finance released facts and information to indicate that it has fallen from 97 percent to 82 percent, and that was an extraordinary period of time that it went up to 97 percent. So I don't think we should allow the impression that it has been and continues to be at 97 percent. Mr. Garrett. These are LTV loans, high LTVs. I think they are still at 99 percent. Overall, it has come down, but not the high LTV. Chairman Kanjorski. We will check it out. Would it be surprising if they stay up and everything else goes down? Mr. Garrett. No. That is part of the consequence, and that is part of the concern. Chairman Kanjorski. We will check. Mr. Garrett. You put your chart over there. And we will have our chart here. Chairman Kanjorski. We will have the war of charts. With that, Mrs. Capito? Mrs. Capito. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Sanders, in my opening statement, I mentioned concerns I have. I am the ranking member on the Housing Subcommittee, and we worked on the FHA reform bill, and have been trying to work on, with the Administration's help, the FHA capital reserve fund. As you know, FHA has played a much, much larger role in mortgage insurance than probably historically. I don't know that, but I assume it is close to that. Have you looked at the announced changes on the premium changes and do you think this will have any effect on FHA market share and open up some of the private markets? Do you have an opinion on that? Mr. Sanders. First of all, I also want to point out, not to pick on Mr. Taylor, but when he mentioned Fannie and Freddie have horrible balance sheets, we should ask ourselves: And how did they end up with horrible balance sheets? What is happening right now is, true, Freddie and Fannie have increased their standards for purchasing loans. However, the FHA has jumped in and filled the void so the whole point is, we still have tons of these low-downpayment loans being made. It just shifted. The FHA is now growing faster than Fannie and Freddie. But having said that, I think that the proposed legislation on the FHA is a very good thing. I think the fee schedules make a lot of sense. I think even the FHA would agree that they would like to actually have higher downpayment standards. Absolutely. They have some data. They can see how this can happen again. Mrs. Capito. They did raise some of their downpayment requirements for those with FICO scores of 570 or 580. Mr. Sinks. 580. Mrs. Capito. They raised them up to 10 percent. So I think that is a recognition by the FHA. In your opinion, that may not be enough. Mr. Sanders. Baby steps. The direction is great. I love to see it. However, once again, I keep trying to make this clear, the more we rely on low-downpayment loans, while it is very satisfying for many households, and I appreciate it, the slow rental market, it is inflationary in housing prices. And again, and I want to make this point, I appreciate what the FHA and Fannie and Freddie have done. On the other hand, if you are sitting out in Las Vegas, California, Florida, etc., you have a 3 percent down loan, which you were encouraged to do, housing prices fall 20 percent, how did we help out homeowners by encouraging them to take out a low-downpayment mortgage? These households are devastated. Again, we have to rethink shoving everyone into low downpayment. To say that the housing market is now stable and will never go up again, like Mark Zandi says, I think that is ridiculous. We have set the table. Warning, we have set the table for another lurch and crash. I don't want to see that again, and I don't think anyone in here really wants to see that either. But I think the FHA is a good step forward. Mr. Sinks. If I may, first of all, the housing prices have dropped significantly in the markets that Mr. Sanders alluded to. And there is a sense, and Mr. Zandi, for instance, will forecast the drop a little more. But our sense of it at the Mortgage Insurance Companies is that the worst is over in terms of the price drops. From peak to trough, the worst is over, we believe. The other thing is, I would not overemphasize the importance of downpayment. It is a criteria, and the example used is an important one. However, there are a number of factors that led to what happened. We talked about low interest rates and we talked about how easy it was to get a mortgage. But also things like instrument types, subprime mortgages, reduced doc loans, things of that nature. It was much more than downpayment. High-ratio lending can be done properly. It doesn't necessarily equate into high risk. What you have to be careful of is layering risk, where you only have 3 percent down, you have 580 FICO score and a BPI of 45 percent, when you layer all of those things in, that is when you walk into a problem. So downpayment is an important criteria, but we would submit it is not the only criteria. Mrs. Capito. Excellent point. Thank you. Ms. Goldberg. If I may add a comment to that, one of the other things we saw in the dramatic increase in the subprime lending and other kinds of exotic lending was a misalignment of interest between the borrower and the folks on the other side of the table, where people on the other side of the table were getting paid tremendous amounts to put folks in loans that were not sustainable, that had these many layers of risk that several of us have talked about. So it is not like it happened organically. There were profit motives and strong market forces driving people into those loans when they were not really in their own best interest. Mrs. Capito. Thank you. I would add this to that, coming from a State like West Virginia which has some of the highest homeownership in the Nation and some of the lowest foreclosure rates, we don't have the bubble of the real estate. We have responsible borrowers who, when they sit down to pay their bills, they pay their mortgage. That is the first check that they write. And so, there is an element of personal responsibility here that sometimes I think, not to say this is the only thing, and certainly there are people out there taking advantage of other people, absolutely. But the borrower has to take responsibility here. Part of my frustration has been in some of the foreclosure modifications when we were doing the trial modifications, there was such pressure to get people into trial modifications, they weren't even taking documentation on those. That just exacerbates the problem. We all want to keep everybody in a home, but at the same time, we can't keep repeating the same mistakes that have led folks to be thrown out of their homes and have led to this crisis. I just wanted to make that point. But I appreciate your remarks. Mr. Taylor. Mr. Chairman, if I may comment, I do think personal responsibility is important, and I think everybody needs to understand that and needs to live by that. But I think when you see almost 10 million Americans in a situation where they are facing foreclosure, it is not like the American public overnight became personally irresponsible about purchasing things and going into homeownership. What really changed is not the desire for homeownership or the individual personal responsibility of taxpayers or voters, what really changed is the malfeasance of the industry willing to make loans that they didn't care what happened to them because all they cared about was the fee. There wasn't the regulatory apparatus that ensured integrity and ethics in the industry. That and the piggybacking, as I think Mr. Sinks said, it is the layering of all of these different things on these loans--interest rates, options, payments, changing exploding loans, no documentation, all of these things that they were actually willing to make loans to people they knew didn't have an ability to pay. That is what changed. The industry before that was pretty good at making loans to people who could afford to pay them back. It wasn't that all of a sudden, the American public became irresponsible. That is my perspective. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you, Mrs. Capito. We will now hear from the gentlelady from New York, Mrs. Maloney. Mrs. Maloney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Following up on the gentleman who just spoke, that what was happening was that no responsibility was in the process, but just fee-generated activity, could you elaborate? So it was more or less like a casino, and could you elaborate more? And are the safeguards put in the bill adequate with the 5 percent securitization and skin in the game and bringing everyone under regulation, does that, in effect, end these types of abuses, in your opinion? Mr. Taylor. I think the bill will go a long way towards addressing a lot of the abuses. I think what will be important is the real independence of the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection and its oversight and ability to respond to things. Look, I think what we had was an industry gone wild on Wall Street that had so much money that was looking for a home. And America had a reputation, you buy these CDOs mortgage-backed securities, you could get good rates of return, and we had rating agencies that were willing to slap AAA ratings on 80 percent of the high-cost loans. AAA rating on 80 percent of the high-cost loans. And you had appraisers-- Mrs. Maloney. And these mortgage-backed securities had no insurance behind them, and did the public know that, that there was no-- Mr. Taylor. The public, I remember sitting with some of the agencies before the crash and asking them, how could they be rating these things at triple A ratings, and sitting across the table, they would tell me, we are not really a due diligence agency. Mrs. Maloney. Then what were they? Mr. Taylor. I don't know. I think they were agents of the investment banks because that is who paid them. That is the fundamental problem. I know in the bill, you have language in there to recommend what to do with these agencies. But listen, it was top to bottom. It was appraisers. It was brokers. It was everybody getting fees, and nobody with the ability to step in and say, we can't have this kind of stuff because it is not sustainable, it is predatory, and it is going to cause problems for everybody, not only homeowners, but the investors. The investors, they are thinking they were buying American triple rated securities that are going to give them double digit, maybe high single digit rates of returns, safe as gold. That is what happened up and down the line. Hopefully, what you have in passing this financial reform, and God bless you for supporting it, is that you are putting sanity back into this industry, accountability, and you are protecting the American consumer in the process. And hopefully, we will get back to the business of banking in which they made loans to people who could actually afford to pay them back. Mrs. Maloney. Mr. Sanders, did you want to comment? Mr. Sanders. Thank you. Before we take the rating agency punching bag approach, I want to point out that a lot of investors bought many of these securities, and they didn't even take time to do due diligence and take a look because all of the loan files were available. They could have done their own modeling. I know this for a fact. Instead they just jumped in, said triple A rated, I will buy it, and then after they lost money, they said, ``Oh, my gosh, those damn rating agencies.'' From the street, and I am sure if you had Mr. Zandi in here again, most people on the street know rating agencies--ratings don't mean much. They have a 6-month lag when things go back. I put the onus on the buyers. Buyer beware. Remember that one. I think a lot of times they substituted in a quick decision when they didn't do proper due diligence, and now they want their pound of flesh for doing it. Mr. Taylor. So, personal responsibility of investors. Mrs. Maloney. I began this morning at a meeting, a briefing that Chairman Frank had on housing, and he had several economists there. And Mr. Zandi, who was the economist for Senator McCain, testified that housing is roughly 25 percent of the economy. If we don't have a robust housing market, then we are not going to have a recovery and our recovery is still somewhat fragile. One thing that the private mortgage insurance does is help us finance housing and thereby help us dig our way out of this recession. Would anyone like to comment on the way that the private mortgage insurance business successfully raises millions of dollars for us to finance housing which under the new guidelines is following investment principles? Would anyone like to comment on that? Mr. Sinks. On behalf of MICA, I would say, first of all I think the attraction of capital to the industry that we have experienced in the last couple of years is a realization that prudent underwriting has returned. While we have the legacy of the older business and how that develops, first and foremost, prudent underwriting has returned. I think that goes a long way towards it. I also think that the industry has taken numerous steps. One of the key values that we bring, and perhaps lost sight of during a period of time but now bring again is a second set of eyes. We like to use the term ``friction.'' In other words, there is a second set of eyes looking at that loan, looking at that loan file to make sure that it meets the criteria and to make sure that the loan is proper and people can afford the loan, not only at the time they originate the mortgage or day one when they move in the house, but 3 or 4 or 5 years later they can stay in that home. So in many respects, it is back to basics. That is what it is. Mrs. Maloney. Back to basics. That is a good ending. My time has expired, but Mr. Taylor has a comment. Mr. Taylor. It is more than a second set of eyes. It is having skin in the game. The MIs know that if that mortgage goes bad, they lose. So they will make sure it is a good loan. That is critical because they have financial skin in the game. Mrs. Maloney. My time has expired. I thank the gentleman. Chairman Kanjorski. The gentleman from Texas, Mr. Neugebauer. Mr. Neugebauer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate the rehashing. We have had a number of hearings where we rehashed what happened. I kind of am more interested in where we go from here because that is what is going to drive the economy, how to get these markets back functioning again and somehow divorce the taxpayers from having to subsidize and backstop these financial markets. Mr. Sinks, one of the things that people are kicking around is how we get the securitization market back operating again, and certainly the mortgage insurance industry plays an important part of that in the primary origination. One of the things that is being kicked around a little bit is instead of Fannie and Freddie basically securitizing and guaranteeing those portfolios, possibly there is room for private entities to do that. So instead of MI, you have SI, securitization insurance. Do you think that the industry would embrace a concept where there was another piece of business there where you would not only be, the private mortgage insurance on the underlying mortgages, but also on the securitization piece? Mr. Sinks. We would embrace it obviously if done correctly. In fact, we have in the past. We did insure private label securities over many, many years. I think the challenge and our position on it is, and we used to ask ourselves this at MGIC, many years in the boom time, is Wall Street patient capital? And they have proven that very well, they are not patient capital, for a variety of reasons. So to answer your question directly: Would we entertain it? Yes. However, we do believe the government needs to play a role because that ensures liquidity. And as long as there is liquidity in the market, again with proper oversight, with transparency, and the proper regulators, we are better and more in line with kind of a combination of private partner. And by that, I mean two different securitizers, not the Fannie Mae ownership. Mr. Neugebauer. People talk about how we need the government for liquidity. To me, liquidity is saying, if you need me to loan you some money against your securities for a period of time, I will do that. That provides liquidity. But then there is another piece of that. Some people say, we need the Federal Government to step in and take some of the risk with us. Certainly, I don't embrace that concept. We had a private securitized market before the crisis. We need to figure out a way to restore it. As Professor Sanders said, we need the industry to be willing to take risks, do their due diligence and make sure that understand what they are buying. But we also need to make sure that we don't take away the tools for some of those entities that are willing to make a market for those securities, to protect some of that risk. And that comes with hedging and derivatives. When we talk about liquidity, are we talking about for the Federal Government to take some of the credit risk when you say that? Mr. Sinks. We are talking in particular about liquidity to be able to move money in the secondary market, the capital markets. It is not so much taking credit risk. I think that is the role the private mortgage insurance companies can play. As I reported earlier, we have great capacity to be able to do it. That doesn't mean that the new entity, the new GSE wouldn't be exposed. It would depend on the layer of private mortgage insurance coverage you have. So on our terms, it would be more along the lines of the ability to transfer capital from those originating loans to this entity or into the secondary market and free up capital to make more loans. Mr. Neugebauer. Ms. Rodamaker? Ms. Rodamaker. From a community bank's perspective, I would wholeheartedly agree with that. As we originate loans, we need an avenue to sell those into the secondary market to free up capital to originate more real estate mortgages. We sell about 60 percent of our mortgages that we originate in our communities. We retain 100 percent of the servicing. We still manage those accounts and those customers, but we have to have a vehicle to get that sold and generate the liquidity. It does help us manage our interest rate risk because we sell our long-term fixed-rate mortgages. However, we utilize the same underwriting as if we were holding those loans in portfolio, and assume that credit risk even though we have sold it to Freddie Mac. I think that is true of most community banks. We are not looking to sell a credit risk; we are looking to generate liquidity. Mr. Neugebauer. I think that is important. I think everyone agrees that we need to get the secondary market back functioning again. Otherwise, we won't have much of a housing market if we don't have housing credit. And it will be difficult for us to address the Freddie and Fannie issue if we don't have an alternative because it has been pointed out that they are the only game in town right now, on top of FHA. I want to encourage the panel, as we begin to address Fannie and Freddie, we have to also I think simultaneously be addressing how we get the private securitization market back, started again, because otherwise we will be creating a very difficult situation to bring up any kind of a housing recovery, and really I think a long-term economic recovery for our country. I encourage, if you have some ideas, we will be listening. I yield back. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you. The gentlelady from New York, Mrs. McCarthy. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I apologize that I had to leave. I had constituents coming in that I had to see. I am hoping that the question I want to ask hasn't already been asked. Mr. Taylor, when I read your testimony, you indicated that the mortgage insurance can play a crucial role to help troubled homeowners. Can you further explain the proposed partnership of the industry with the Administration and explain how further we can work along towards economic recovery? If you have answered that, I have another question. Mr. Taylor. I have, unfortunately, had to be fairly consistently critical of the lack of success of the Administration's HAMP program, considering that 390,000 people got permanent modifications out of the 4 million goal that they set for themselves, from over 16 months of running the program. So, it has been difficult that I have had to take that position. I have tried to look for creative things that can be done. I think one of them is the role that mortgage insurance companies could play because what is coming now, as of October 1st, is the principal reduction, the call for principal reduction by the lenders on these mortgages to see whether that can save enough borrowers from going into foreclosure. And perhaps the role that the mortgage insurance companies could play is to offer mortgage insurance for those borrowers who are under 20 percent of value, loan to value, and perhaps encourage some of those lenders to be dropping the interest, and if necessary, principal, to reach a point where they are comfortable there will be mortgage insurance in play so if this redefaults, which is a concern for a lot of lenders, if there is a redefault, that there is somebody who can cover some of those defaults. I think the mortgage insurance companies, it is new. It is novel. I think the mortgage insurance companies, I urge them to work with the Administration and work with the lenders to see whether they can play a role in helping me make HAMP more effective. The final thing I will say on that is unless and until there is a mandatory requirement for lenders to participate in the HAMP program, as long as it is voluntary, we are going to see the poor numbers that we are seeing in that program. Ms. Goldberg. If I may just add one comment to that, because I think the mortgage insurance industry really deserves credit for stepping forward early on in this HAMP process, to recognize the fact that mortgage insurance exists on the loans, could be effectively the thumb on the scale, tipping the balance in the equation about what is going to be the best return for the investor towards going to foreclosure because that is when the claim, the mortgage insurance claim, is traditionally paid. I have been in a number of meetings with people from the industry and people from the government where they said this is a potential problem. We need to make sure that it doesn't happen. I think they have been trying very hard to work with servicers and to work with Treasury to prevent that from tipping the balance unfairly because it is not in their interest; it is not in the borrower's interest, and it is certainly not in the community's interest to have the fact that there is a mortgage insurance policy on a loan, make it go to foreclosure, when it could otherwise have been saved. Maybe Mr. Sinks can speak to this. It is my understanding that they have been trying to work with servicers to do some kind of preclaim advance or a partial payment that would tip the balance toward loan modifications. It is very hard to know how that is working or how widespread the take-up from the servicing industry has been on that possibility. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. We had a briefing this morning by Moody's, and they brought up the same exact points that you are bringing up. So the criticism has been out there. Mark Zandi gave us a great briefing. If something is not working, then obviously we have to try to fix it. Mr. Sinks, do you have anything to add to that? Mr. Sinks. I would add, we have done a great deal, the mortgage insurance companies, in working with servicers, and in certain cases, working directly with borrowers, to try to keep people in their homes. As we reported earlier, our interests are very much aligned with the servicer and the borrower, so it is important that we do that. The programs have evolved over the last couple of years. I think they got off to a relatively slow start, but we are now seeing more and more programs where the consumer's monthly payment is being reduced and that makes a big difference in keeping them in their home. So we are actively engaged there. I think there are 16 different programs we are involved with. In addition to that, I know many of the MI companies that actually place people on site at the servicers such that those loans that contain mortgage insurance are getting the attention that they deserve, and we can work them as quickly as we possibly can. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. One of the things--I am sorry, my time is up. Chairman Kanjorski. I recognize the gentlelady from Illinois, Mrs. Biggert. Mrs. Biggert. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for having this hearing. Mr. Sinks, in your testimony, you say that PMI has saved taxpayers billions of dollars. Do you think that we should require PMI on all loans in excess of 70 percent loan to value? Mr. Sinks. I wouldn't lock in necessarily on loan to value; but I would tell you that we are prepared to go as deep as necessary and as is prudent, as long as we can protect the policyholders in our capital support. We certainly would entertain that idea. Mrs. Biggert. Some people say FHA's market share has increased because the private mortgage insurers have pulled back. Do you agree with that? Is this a reason for FHA's increased market share? Mr. Sinks. I think there are a variety of reasons for the increase in market share. I think as the crisis developed in 2007 and 2008, we adjusted, ``we'' being the private mortgage insurance companies, adjusted our underwriting criteria to reflect the market conditions at that point in time. Since then, as the market has started to recover a little bit, we have adjusted those accordingly. So our underwriting guidelines have adjusted as markets have changed. But the other key reason why the FHA is getting the market share they are, first and foremost, they generally have pricing lower than we do. They have proposed, and I think it has been approved in the House, that their pricing will increase, and hopefully later this year that will happen. That will make the private mortgage insurance companies much more competitive. In addition, and it was alluded to earlier by members of the panel, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have added adverse market fees. They have loan level price adjustments to try to rebuild their capital base that has made the conventional market less competitive. So if a borrower looks at a monthly payment between the FHA and the private execution, more often than not, they are going to do FHA. It is just simply the borrower picking the best execution for them. Mrs. Biggert. Thank you. Ms. Ratcliffe, in the aftermath of the financial crisis, the government seems to have taken a dominant role in the single family mortgage market. The Federal Reserve has invested $125 million in mortgage-backed securities, Treasury has injected $145 billion to Fannie and Freddie, and now the FHA insures more than 20 percent of all new mortgages. In your opinion, is it appropriate that the government commit such extensive resources to support the housing market? Ms. Ratcliffe. Is it appropriate to what they have done, obviously it seems like in the heat of the moment, and the crisis, certain steps had to be taken. Whether every single investment and dollar put up, I think if I could turn your question a little more to the future and answer a question that has sort of been in the air here all day, whether going forward there should be some place for government in the secondary market. Mrs. Biggert. I guess I would ask then, is that investment sustainable over the long term? Ms. Ratcliffe. The current level seems inappropriate and unsustainable over the long term. Mrs. Biggert. What strategies would you suggest then for the private sector's role in the mortgage market? Ms. Ratcliffe. The private sector ought to play as big a role as it can while the mortgage industry can function to meet the public policy goal. To some extent, that may require some form of government support to build investor confidence and create constant liquidity and ensure access to standardized mortgage products, particularly the fixed-rate, long-term amortizing mortgage that is the staple of the U.S. market. But to the extent that the private sector, and mortgage insurance is a perfect example of that, the first loss position is on the private sector. They have skin in the game. They set the standards and they know the customers and the borrowers and the mortgage lenders. So the government role should be minimized. What we have proposed are things like private mortgage insurance, much more capital in front of whatever would replace the GSEs, and something like an FDIC fund before you even would touch a catastrophic government wrap. Mrs. Biggert. Mr. Sinks, to go back and maybe play on that, can you elaborate for us, you said, I think, that the mortgage insurance industry is very well regulated by the State insurance regulators. Are you concerned that there might be inefficiencies and burdens of having to deal with the different regulations and requirements among the States? Or do you still think this is the best way to go? Mr. Sinks. We still believe in the State regulatory model. It has worked successfully, as we have said. It has worked in good times and bad times. There are mortgage insurance companies over time, going back to the 1980's, for instance, that are no longer in the business because of regular steps, and addressed the situation. It is kind of a sense that the model works very well, and we don't need to fix it. If it is not broke, don't fix it. Mrs. Biggert. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you very much, Mrs. Biggert. We have now run out of our first round of questions. I am sure members would have additional questions if we allow it. So, without objection, I am going to start a second round. We have this bright, anxious, participating panel here, so why not tap them. My first question would be, looking to the future, how many of you would recommend getting the government totally out of the secondary market and out of the real estate market? Okay, George Mason has one vote, and five to the contrary. Let us start with you, Mr. Sanders. Why are you so convinced that it is not advantageous for the entire American economy to keep the real estate market relatively flat and not highly cyclical that would cause this great fluctuation? Or do you see that there would not be fluctuation, because if you do an analysis from the late 1920's until 2004, 2005, the real estate market has been a tremendously flat, stable market, and it only bloated with the bubble right at the end. What are we to think if we go to a total private market again, why should we not be returning to the days prior to 1929 when it was a very, very fluctuating market? Mr. Sanders. Mr. Kanjorski, I have seen that same study by Bob Schiller. What is misleading about that is that is a national portfolio of housing. There have been regional bubbles in housing markets all throughout time: Boston; Houston; and Denver. That was the source of my quote in the New York Times where I said don't put lower-income households in low- downpayment mortgages. You are going to hurt them because housing markets, by definition, can be bubblish. Now, having said that, I would disagree with what Mr. Taylor said. He said, Wall Street gone wild. I would say, government gone wild. We went through a period where government pushed housing over the cliff. And what did we get? We got a bubble; we got a burst; and we have a lot of heartache and pain. It almost crashed the banking industry and the private mortgage insurance companies ratings are not as high as they used to be. That is the downside of it. Having said that, can't we at least begin to withdraw the government support and go back and let the private mortgage insurance companies or the banks take risks they think are reasonable? Chairman Kanjorski. I do not have any question with that. Certainly we have to change the formula, perhaps how much government involvement there is. But to listen to the purists' argument, it is quite disturbing to me because you are willingly putting at risk, it seems to me, the entire economy of the United States since housing represents 25 percent of the economy. If we stay in the state we are in right now, there is literally little or no hope for recovery. That is a heck of a price to test against an economic theory, free market concept. I am glad you are able to make that price and argument, but would you want us to tie all of the support funds that the Federal Government supplies to your university based on that so if you are wrong, your university gets wiped out? Mr. Sanders. Absolutely, for the following reason: We are the only country that has Freddie Mac, Fannie Mae, and this extensive subsidization of the housing market. We got there because of that. You are right, if we suddenly removed it, it would be like a drug addict coming off of a heroin shot. We would probably have a terrible time afterwards. We need sort of a methadone period, where we withdraw it over time, say 3 to 5 years. But eventually, we have to let a target, let the private sector make bets and pay the price if they are wrong. Chairman Kanjorski. And I can understand that argument, but how do you justify what happened when securitization by Fannie and Freddie really substantially lessened in 2006, 2007, and 2008, and the private market of Wall Street took over, and the descriptions Mr. Taylor made of these people being on all one side of the transaction, getting their commissions and profit, that occurred when Wall Street was doing the securitizations, not when the government-sponsored agencies were doing it. Mr. Sanders. Again, I have seen that argument made before. Just using my hands because I don't have graphs, the housing bubble did this; at this point, Freddie and Fannie pulled out of the market and let the private sector come in. That is icing on the cake. This market was bubbled and was overheated before the private sector stepped in with the securitization, the private label market you are talking about. Mr. Taylor. That is not true. Mr. Sanders. Yes, it is. Mr. Taylor. Three years ago, FHA only had 3 percent market share. Mr. Sanders. We are talking Fannie and Freddie. Mr. Taylor. Let's talk Fannie and Freddie. Mr. Chairman, Fannie and Freddie in 2001 had $2.7 trillion worth of market share of these mortgages. By 2003, they lost a trillion dollars worth of market share to this so-called free market, it was free to abuse and do whatever they wanted, a trillion dollars of market share, that is when Freddie and Fannie got into this both feet, arms, legs, the whole body. That is when they really followed the market into this subprime abyss. But even then they had limits, and they wouldn't take no-documentation loans and they wouldn't do certain things that the market was still doing and willing to do. So let's be clear. We were led down this abyss, all of us, by a market gone wild. It wasn't low-income people. You look at the people who are in foreclosures, it is not just low-income people. It is all sorts of income levels. They keep blaming low-income people. I don't know what is going on with George Mason. It is simply not what has happened in America to this housing bubble. It wasn't created by low-income people. In fact, low-income people originations amounted to less than 10 percent of all the mortgages that were done in this malfeasant lending period. It had very little to do with lending to low-income people. Mr. Sinks. I would agree with what Mr. Taylor said here. When Wall Street came in and it created or extended the ``exotic products'' and Fannie and Freddie started to lose share, that is when they reacted. That goes to the private- public ownership of Fannie and Freddie, which is a different topic. But they were responding, trying to play to their shareholders, and they grew their share; and, therefore, accepted riskier loans dramatically. The flip side of that, and it goes back to something I spoke earlier about, is Wall Street patient capital, the answer is flat out no because they have a profit motive. As Mr. Garrett pointed out earlier with his charts, they disappeared and now the government has 99 percent of it, or 83 percent, whatever the right number is. So the pendulum swung completely the other way. And to your point, Mr. Chairman, as much as we want to see the FHA and the GSEs back off a little bit, we wouldn't have a housing market today if they weren't there because the private capital market sure isn't stepping in. Ms. Goldberg. Mr. Chairman, in addition, it is important to stop blaming the low-downpayment loan made to low- and moderate-income people because I think there is a lot of evidence that those loans done properly actually perform quite well, and are very stable over time, at least when the economy is not going whacko, because unemployment now is obviously driving foreclosures at a level that it hasn't before. I think it is important to be clear about what are the kinds of loans that have caused this crisis, and what are the kinds of loans that haven't, and not just say every loan with a low downpayment is a bad loan that is destined to go back. One other piece related to that, one of the critical roles for the Federal Government and its involvement in the secondary market and direction of the primary market is to make sure that lending is done fairly so people, not just low- and moderate- income people, people of color, families with kids, women, people with disabilities, that they have access to mortgage credit in a fair and equitable manner, and in a safe and sound basis, which if we go a little ways back in history, we know is not the case with a market left to its own devices. So in terms of that kind of equity, and how we make sure people are treated fairly and have fair access, the government has a really critical role to play as well. Chairman Kanjorski. I really need an explanation for the record and that is why I have encouraged you all to go back to what caused this thing. I am firmly convinced that we need to find some way of defining some of the important causes we agree upon. Apparently, here on this panel, we have five witnesses who would agree this is not all of the government's fault, and one witness who says the solution to this would be going back totally to a free market system. Now this panel and the Congress has to write new rules and regulations and decisions need to be made as to whether we have a secondary market. And if so, who is responsible to encourage it, what kind of subsidization should be made for housing, if any, and should we get involved at all? It seems to me we cannot get back to that unless we get more uniform agreement as to what some of the basic causes for the crash were. And then leading off that, what are some of the solutions or cures we can put in place to prevent some of these things. One question, because we just recently passed the Regulatory Reform Act, do you think we have totally failed in doing the right thing there and we should have done nothing? Mr. Sanders. The Regulatory Reform Act? Chairman Kanjorski. The Dodd-Frank bill. Mr. Sanders. It is all about systemic risk, etc. We don't know what is going to be in the new agency that has been formed up that is going to moderate the markets. And it didn't mention Fannie and Freddie. Congressman Frank says we are going to do this. I say to my friend, Mr. Taylor, and I gave this presentation in front of Mr. Frank, I said we have pumped $8 trillion in money, guarantees and loans into this mortgage market prior to the private sector getting involved. That is bubblish. By the way, I am not saying that the private sector didn't make some mistakes. Absolutely, there were. But what I am saying is, without the public sector's prodding into housing so heavily, we may not have seen that. Would the market have responded that way had they thought there wasn't this huge demand for it? Because remember, I took it out of my testimony for Mr. Taylor. I wish I had put it in. Take a look at the housing prices in cities. In some major cities, housing prices quadrupled during this bubble period. How do we get affordable housing people into those? There is only one way to do it, 3 percent down. And again, I understand that. But that is bubblish. Chairman Kanjorski. But we were all worried about the tulips. Mr. Sanders. You are absolutely right. The private sector screwed up. Chairman Kanjorski. I would like to go on, but I have to let Mr. Garrett have some of the time. Mr. Garrett? Mr. Garrett. So the last exchange was I guess interesting and telling that here we are, ending in July, and we still don't know what was the underlying cause, at least have a consensus on what was the underlying cause of the economic morass we were just in. Why that is curious and maybe a little ironic is several weeks ago, we just passed a 2,300 page bill fixing the problem. When we were in this room and I was sitting over there and it was the first day of the first joint conference committee, House and Senate conference committee, and we were ready to start voting on the bill and I asked, may I have a show of hands of anyone in the room who actually has read all 2,300 pages. No one raised their hand on the committee. So what you had was no one actually having read the bill. And as we have seen in this last few minute dialogue, we still don't have a consensus as to what was the cause of it. We have a commission that is out there that is going to be coming up with their interpretation, after exhaustive studies and talking to experts like you and others to tell us what the cause was. That, I understand, is not going to get back to us until some time at the end of the year. But here we are already implementing a bill, 2,300 pages, and to what end. A couple of you already made the comment that what we need is certainty, and we need to get capital back into the marketplace. In the last week or so, it was reported in the Wall Street Journal that Ford was trying to get more capital into the system. And how did that work for them, as Dr. Phil would say. Not too well. It wasn't because of anything that Ford did, it wasn't because of anything that the private markets did, it was all because of this ill-conceived, not thought out what the ramifications of the bill is, and those are not my words, I am sort of paraphrasing Senator Dodd when he said we have see how this bill passes before we see how it all plays out. We saw how it played out with Ford. Thank goodness Mary Shapiro was able to come back and fix that situation in a band- aid sort of approach for 6 months. Think about how much uncertainty there is there. Think of with the SEC, we don't even know how many regulations that they have to promulgate. I know someone is saying it is 95 regulations, somebody else says it is 102 regulations at the SEC. We don't know how many regulations they have to promulgate. How can anyone say we have just brought certainty to the marketplace? We have brought uncertainty into the marketplace, and that is just going to be a detriment for a time to come for your industries and the rest. I think what all of us want, whether it is the free markets or otherwise, is proper allocation of capital. That is the best way for any economy to perform, is if you have the proper allocation of capital. You have had a misallocation when the government encourages to go in one way when it shouldn't. I will concede with Mr. Taylor and others that there were mistakes made all of the way around, private sector, public sector, individuals, investors, and the like. But you have to, I think, agree that a lot of this was prompted by government activity. I think Ms. Goldberg was saying it is not the low-income loans and what-have-you, and I think some of the documentation sort of points that out. But you have to see what the government did on this to encourage the high income. Remember what the Federal Reserve up in Boston said several years ago just prior to the collapse, they published a report that says, what, that when you do the underwriting, you no longer have to look at traditional valuations, you no longer have to look at income sources, you can consider welfare payments as a proper source of income in the consideration of developing risk assessment and the like. They were talking about low-income loans in the urban areas, but what happened right after that or some time after that, they said if you don't have to look at those for low- income loans, okay, because there are no longer the traditional values that banks used to use, you would probably say should we be looking at welfare payments as a proper source of income for a bank loan, you would say probably not. But the Federal Reserve of Boston was saying it was okay to consider it. So if it is okay for the Federal Reserve of Boston to do it on that loan, then you had Bear Stearns and others come out on the private sector saying, hey, we must be able to do it on the middle income and the upper income levels as well. And that then skewed the marketplaces. Ms. Goldberg, you talked a little bit about the downpayment aspects and what-have-you. Is the percentage of downpayment an appropriate indicator of risk? Ms. Goldberg. Sir, if I can take a second and speak to your previous point briefly, one thing on welfare payments, it is often true that people who get welfare don't have the income to support a mortgage, but it is a steady stream of income. And I am not familiar with the Federal Reserve of Boston's paper on this topic, but I suspect that is what they were getting at. I don't think you would find community advocates suggesting that should be the only underwriting criteria. I think we all want to see that loans are underwritten, looking at the borrower's ability to repay the loan. So it is not just are you getting welfare as a criterion for deciding whether you are eligible or should be eligible for a loan or not. There are a lot of factors that go into it. Several panelists have spoken, what we saw in the unregulated part of the private market was risk layering with lots of different loan features that together contributed to tremendous risk, loans that were not sustainable, and were not underwritten to the borrower's ability to repay. Having said that, I forgot what your question was. Mr. Garrett. Is downpayment an appropriate indicator of risk? Although now, you say that welfare payments may be appropriate. Ms. Goldberg. I will say that I don't believe my organization has a position on the level of downpayment that ought to be required. But I think we would say that we think it is a good idea for people to have a downpayment and to have, as a borrower, some skin in the game. However, just like with high-income people and lower-income people, that should not be the only factor that is evaluated in deciding whether someone is a good credit risk, and whether the loan product that is being offered to them is the appropriate product for them. Mr. Garrett. Do you have an answer? Ms. Rodamaker. When we talk about the downpayment, that is absolutely one aspect that we use of underwriting. We have gone through and we study every loss, every foreclosure, everything that happens in our mortgage market. The most common cause of foreclosure in our market is divorce, and you can't use that in underwriting. Mr. Garrett. This is not the committee that deals with that. Ms. Rodamaker. Right. When a couple comes in and applies for a mortgage, they are happy. When they start making payments, maybe that is when they become unhappy. Chairman Kanjorski. So all we have to do is outlaw divorce. That is the solution. Mr. Garrett. Just a technical question, Mr. Sinks. When the person comes in and makes their application to the bank, to your colleague to your left, you are doing all of your underwriting and then paperwork, if she is hooked up with one of your clients and they are doing that, what percentage of the cases that she will be sending, applications that will be coming in for PMI, are accepted on average and what percentage are not? Or is it accepted all of the time with just a higher premium? Mr. Sinks. I will speak on behalf of MGIC because I don't know the industry statistics, but historically, we would have rejected the application probably 2 or 3 percent of the time. In this environment, because we are so cautious, that number is closer to 25 percent. Mr. Garrett. But normally it is 2 or 3 percent? Mr. Sinks. Yes. As you came through the 1990's and 2000 decade, it would be 2 to 3 percent. As the market changed, and we had to adjust our underwriting guidelines accordingly, it is probably in the neighborhood of 25 percent. The primary reason for that is because of concerns over valuations. It is not the credit score. You can verify income and things like that. It is really about the value of the property; is that appraisal good. And in certain markets, in Iowa, it is just fine. But in other markets, we still have concerns about those. I would expect that over a period of time to revert to the mean. Mr. Garrett. I will close, I know a couple of you made the comment as for the need of additional information and uniformity in regulation, and your suggestion was along the line with what the GSE has done in the past. Rest assured, the Frank-Dodd bill takes care of all that. We now have an Office of Financial Research that will get every single piece of information that anyone can possibly conceive of in that agency, and they will be a new systemic risk regulator all unto themselves. So every bit of information that you have ever been looking for, and any information as far as uniformity will come from them and the CFPA, because ultimately, there is no limitation on their power of information and there is no limitation as far as their power for setting some of the standards you need and inasmuch as these are consumer financial products, we have just created everything you need in this bill. So I will close where I began. We don't understand what caused the problem, but we have solved it. Chairman Kanjorski. I guess that office will be able to tell us just who is going to get divorced. The gentlelady from New York, Mrs. McCarthy. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for having a second round. I wish we always had more time to have an open debate. I always feel bad for the witnesses--5 minutes. You travel from all over, and you get 5 minutes. It is not enough for some of us. We would like to go back and forth with questions. Again, I am going to go basically back to the Moody's report that we got this morning. We might not have solved all of the problems, but going back when we started doing the financial reform, the goal was certainly not to put anybody out of business, but obviously there had to be some rules and regulations. I always said if I could legislate morality, we wouldn't be dealing with a lot of the things that we are doing, mainly because so many of these corporations knew what they were doing. They had been warned by their inner controls, and they ignored it because the money was so good coming in. Having said that, I have absolutely no qualms that what we did was the right thing. Is it perfect, there is no such thing as a perfect bill coming out of Congress. I don't care if you are Republican or Democrat, it just doesn't happen. That means we do corrections as we go along. This committee spent a year-and-a- half going section by section by section, and working hard trying to get it right. I am not going to speak about the Senate. I didn't agree with a lot of things that the Senate did. With that being said, I certainly think that we have put Wall Street and some of the financial industry on notice. We are going to be watching you. For anyone who was planning on retiring, or those of us who actually grew up with parents who came from the Depression and saved so that I would be ready for my retirement, to see that wiped out when I did nothing wrong, and millions of other people in the same boat; and yes, the homeowners. And I agree, going back in 2002, 2003, 2004, this subcommittee, with a Republican chairman, saw that the subprime and the unlicensed mortgage brokers, what they were doing in this country was wrong. We had a good bipartisan bill that I believe could have possibly prevented a lot of things that happened in the housing market. And it came out of this committee with a good vote. It was never allowed on the Floor. Everybody wants to blame this side of the aisle, believe me, we tried and a number of Republicans tried back then. With that being said, and we solved those problems with unlicensed subprime mortgage brokers going from State to State, they are not going to be able to do that any more. And I think that is a good thing. With that being said, and again, I also know we are going to have hearings in September on Freddie and Fannie, basically going a little deeper on exactly what went wrong, and we have a lot of information on that already. But I want to go back to why this hearing is being held. Again, I apologize if it was talked about during the 20 minutes I was gone. If any of you have any ideas about the regulatory or legislation changes that must occur for the private mortgage insurance market to be able to play a larger role in the repair of our housing market, because again that is what we are going to be dealing with, I would certainly take your comments. Mr. Sinks. I will give the first shot. To make us more competitive and bring more private capital or more private exposure, and kind of bring that chart that Mr. Garrett had back into balance, the first thing we need to do is get the FHA prices back in line and commensurate with the risk that they are taking on. They are underpriced from where the private industry is right now. They have new pricing proposed. We know that we expect it to happen. That will clearly expand the pie, if you will, for the private mortgage insurance sector. In addition to that, they are planning on loan dollar limits that are a little higher than they should be, we believe. Those dollar limits need to be adjusted. And finally, as I alluded to earlier, the conventional market which is Freddie and Fannie, they have a series of fees on their loans as they attempt to rebuild their capital base that make the private execution versus an FHA execution less competitive. What it comes down to is when you add in the FHA having lower prices, and the fees that the GSEs have on the conventional side, when the consumer gets a piece of paper in front of them that says which is the lowest mortgage payment every month, it is, far and away, the FHA these days. The private mortgage insurance industry, as we alluded to earlier, has been able to raise billions of dollars worth of capital, and we have the capacity to do it. We are ready, willing, and able as an entire industry. And each company is ready, willing, and able. We just can't compete in the market with that kind of pricing, and we can't control that pricing. So that would be the primary influence on what we need. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. Just to follow through, and I don't remember who mentioned it when I was listening to the testimony, the appraisals, the appraisals of homes going back a number of years ago. I used to have the real estate people coming in and saying, what is going on here? I had a woman who basically came in, she was buying a home that she certainly couldn't afford and the house was appraised much, much higher than what it was ever worth. And there was no money down. One of the new exotic pieces to get people to buy homes. She herself backed out. She wouldn't be part of it because she thought it was fraudulent. How do we get the appraisals to be honest? You bring three appraisals in, and I saw that with my son and daughter-in-law. One was the top end, which nobody in the neighborhood had; their house was not any better, if anything, it wasn't updated as some of the other houses. And then a really, really low price. I know everybody goes high, low, and then in the middle. But how do you know you are getting a good appraisal because, you are the insurance, do you use different appraisers? Mr. Sinks. Yes, we do. We have an approved list of appraisers. This is an issue that has been around certainly since the private mortgage insurance industry has been around. As I said earlier, you can verify income, verify FICOs, but that appraisal is the great unknown. It plays havoc when the market is rising. When you see California double in value over a period of time, or it can have an impact when values are dropping. When you look at Detroit and you see values dropping and someone is trying to buy a home, and what is that house really worth? I think what needs to be done is, most importantly, it needs to be done locally. You need to have trust in people who are in those local markets and truly understand it. In addition to that, you have to have some other checks and balances, whether it is automatic valuation models and things like that might not be the exact answer, but it gives you a reasonableness check on what that appraised value should be. Mr. Taylor. First and foremost, in FIRREA you mandated there be independence between appraisers and financial institutions, and that never happened. Countrywide had their own appraisal shop. Citi, a number of these financial institutions owned the appraisal units. Yes, the guy who ran the mortgage department didn't oversee the appraisers, but they worked for the same company. There has to be independence in those businesses, so there is an arm's length transaction. Furthermore, there has to be the independence so you can make an appraisal and the lender simply doesn't turn around and never do business with you again. There has to be a process that allows for fairness, mediation, and oversight that protects the appraisers from giving honest appraisals. Finally, it has to be in person. These automatic valuations have proven not to be very effective. Yes, they work some of the time, but they don't work a lot of the time. We used to have people come into the house, look at what was going on in that house, not just sit in front of a computer and theorize what the value might be. One of the biggest overlooked groups in this crisis, this foreclosure crisis, was the appraisal industry. And a lot of the ones who tried to stand up and be independent, they are gone because businesses, banks, stopped doing business with them until they got appraisers who did what they said. You absolutely must fix this. I think in the financial reform bill, there is language that allows oversight for this to happen, and it is critical going forward that we really address this problem. Ms. Goldberg. If I can add one note to that, I completely agree about the need for additional oversight. I want to caution you that while I also agree appraisals in many cases helped to fuel the rise of housing prices in a way that didn't make sense, and bore no relationship to reality, appraisals can also work on the opposite end, to harm neighborhoods where property values are undervalued, underpriced. One of the footnotes in my testimony, I give some of the history of the appraisal industry predating FHA and applying to FHA where appraisers were actually trained that you could judge the value of the neighborhood based on who lived there. And there was a listing of different racial and ethnic groups according to whether they helped inflate property values or sustain property valuation, or whether they diminished property values. While those standards have been dropped from the industry, the effect of that really institutionalized kind of racial approach to valuing property. It is not really erased from the industry, and we need to make sure that kind of discrimination is not happening in appraisals, as well as the artificial inflating of the property values at the other end of the scale. Mrs. McCarthy of New York. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank all of you for coming in and enlightening us. Chairman Kanjorski. Now the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Manzullo. Mr. Manzullo. Thank you. Can anybody on the panel advise me if private mortgage insurance had anything to do with the collapse of the real estate market? Mr. Sinks. The literal collapse of the market? Mr. Manzullo. Yes. Did you do anything wrong in your industry, Mr. Sinks? Mr. Sinks. Sure, we did. I think we are one participant amongst many. We were talking earlier about perhaps we haven't figured out exactly what went wrong. I think fundamentally, what went wrong was that basic principles of risk management were done away with. There was no fear in the market. People had different motivations, whether it be the government wanting to house all of America, whether it wanted to be Wall Street to make a buck as quick as they possibly could. I think everybody who was in that food chain from borrower to servicer, and investor at the end, played some role. Mr. Manzullo. The big problem is that the Fed has always had the authority to do two things: number one, govern instruments; and number two, determine the underwriting standards. At least as to those banks that the Fed covered. It wasn't until October of last year that the Fed came out with a written rule that said, voila, you had to have written proof of your earnings. Whenever MI was purchased, if this is within the purview of your knowledge, Mr. Sinks, how far did MI go? Did you actually look at closing statements? Or you just got an order to provide insurance based upon salary and the value of the property? Mr. Sinks. We did look at the documents. We do underwrite the file and provide the second set of eyes. What happened, I think in a sense was that as the market expanded, as Freddie and Fannie took on a greater role, they expanded the underwriting criteria under which they would buy loans. The old idea of 38 percent-- Mr. Manzullo. Did that influence your issuance of mortgage insurance? Mr. Sinks. Yes, it did. The reason it did was because competitively, and we touched on it earlier, what happened was there was an expectation within the lending community, which is our customer base, that if Freddie and Fannie had underwriting guidelines, and I am going to use an example of 45 percent debt to income ratio, then private mortgage insurance, you need to play in that game. For us to remain competitive in that environment and be able to participate in the market, we stretched our underwriting guidelines. We reviewed the file, but we allowed the guidelines to expand due to competitive pressures. Mr. Manzullo. Let me go to a second area. On the appraisers, we have heard horror stories from many lenders back home. I remember reading in the Post some time ago where an appraiser from Richmond came to appraise a townhouse, or a stand-alone house in Alexandria, Virginia. And we are getting people from Chicago who are driving to Rockford, Illinois, 80 miles to the west, who know absolutely nothing, nothing, I mean, nothing about Rockford, that are giving appraisals. And the Realtors are scratching their heads and saying: Where did these guys come from? They came from Chicago. The home valuation code of conduct, we had the hearings on that. I looked at that. I have been through probably a thousand real estate closings myself as a private attorney. In fact, I started practicing before RESPA, and we actually had more honest closings before RESPA. There are eight people at HUD working day and night on trying to revise RESPA at any given time. Now you have a situation where you have an out-of-town appraiser come in, and he doesn't know the fact that there are rumors that the highway may be expanded in front of the house, or he reads the newspaper and hears about the city council which may exercise powers of condemnation and taking a parcel of property, he knows nothing at all about the locality, and yet he is presumed to be dishonest simply because he is local. That is going to really hurt the real estate recovery as far as I am concerned. John, you are nodding your head. It may be the first thing you and I agree with in a long time. Do you agree with that? Mr. Taylor. The second thing, actually. The lack of government oversight in the Fed to put out rules that prohibited these practices. Mr. Manzullo. There you are, John. Mr. Taylor. Yes, I totally agree. It is all about local and having that person who really knows the property, and it is all about that person having the independence from not being overly influenced by the broker or the lender. You do that, build that, which is what you supposedly built with FIRREA when you created this separation, and we will clean up this mess with the appraisers, notwithstanding Debbie's comments about making sure that it is not done in a discriminatory fashion. Mr. Manzullo. The mess is done now. The Realtor goes out there. It is not hard nowadays to get comparables. When I started practicing law, no one had heard about the Internet. You had to research it the old-fashioned way at the courthouse. And that was always interesting because in Illinois, we had the green sheets. The green sheets would tell you which portion of that real estate was actually attributed to personal property. Mr. Chairman, I wanted to bring that up because I just don't think when the GSEs and FHA adopted the HBCCs by reasons of Attorney General Cuomo somehow forcing them to do that, that is going to help in the real estate recovery; do you agree with that, John? Mr. Taylor. I don't know about Attorney General Cuomo being the one who forced them into that position, but I agree that we need local. These appraisal management companies I think are not a good model to get accurate appraisals. We need inside; somebody needs to go into the house, and somebody needs to know the neighborhood and know what is going on. I think that will get us back to sane, accurate valuations. Mr. Manzullo. Do the rest of you agree with Mr. Taylor's statement? Good. On that note, I will end. Chairman Kanjorski. Thank you. If I may comment, the regulatory reform bill contained about 200 to 300 pages of revolutionary ideas about appraisals and how we handle them. And the bill did not take 18 months; it took 6 or 7 years of bringing that about. I think we are going to go on for another hour-and-a-half. No, Mr. Garrett has reined me in. I got carried away. A lot of times when we get down to a few members, we get extended questioning periods. I appreciate the response and the back- and-forth nature of the panel. I was hoping we could get everybody to join hands and say we agree on everything, but we probably have failed. We will try that next time, or we will come down hard on the universities again. Mr. Sanders. If I may make one closing remark on my behalf, Mr. Garrett asked the question, and I wanted to provide some clarity on it. At one point, believe it or not, I was an advocate for Fannie, Freddie, and the FHA. Unfortunately, something happened at the beginning of the last decade. Freddie and Fannie were the gold standard for underwriting, 20 percent down, we don't need private mortgage insurance for 20 percent down. Everybody believed Freddie and Fannie was right on target. FHA was small. A question for you: What happened? Why did Freddie and Fannie balloon in size and why did the FHA balloon in size? I think if you are trying to look at a source of what happened in the housing market, why not look at that? Chairman Kanjorski. I don't blame the Bush Administration for selling real estate at any price. I think Mrs. McCarthy put her hands on it. We can sit here forever and blame one political party or another political party, or one Congress or another Congress, or one President or another President. The reality is, I would hope we can get to a common understanding of what happened because until you identify a problem, it is hard to come up with a solution, and we really do have on both sides of the aisle a gross disagreement on what really fundamentally caused this problem. I am hoping when the Commission gets done, we will come closer together on that issue. Regardless of what happened and what did cause it, it is not going to cure a thing. The future is going to cure something, and I think we should take on the rewriting of what happens to lessen the opportunity. We will never stop risk and we will never stop ridiculousness in a free market society, and we should not, but we can do things to improve it. The one impression that I may have left that I want to remove, I think the mortgage insurance market has played a very good role in real estate in the United States. But we have to recognize that for 2 decades after the Great Depression, it disappeared. And sometimes market situations will not cause it to come about and come back when there is such a tremendous disruption. I really do believe Fannie and Freddie fulfilled a great function in our society in the period from the war on until we lost control of them for one reason or another and they went overboard. But they are manmade institutions and therefore correctable and lend themselves to solutions or something similar to an enforced solution. I think what is important, if we can bring the temperature down and get serious, and I am inviting my friends on the right side to join us in that, and I don't mean right side, it is on my right. What disturbs me the most, and I will shut up after that, is that we have been through a real trauma in the country and the average family has been through a real trauma, and at this point, there is a lot of fear in those families and they are looking for more level heads to prevail. Sometimes we in the Congress do not provide the right image for that level head. I am hoping now we can get down to being levelheaded. If we can, we can solve this problem. I think we are on our way to the solution to the problem. I am absolutely convinced of that. The faster it happens, the better off we are. I agree with Mr. Zandi. And the fact he work for Moody's and was a Republican and supported Mr. McCain for President, that may be good. Because he did that, he probably should be more reliable to my friends on the other side. Notice I didn't say ``right.'' He basically said we are not going to really resolve this problem on real estate until we resolve the unemployment problem. Conversely, the real estate problem is going to stabilize the whole economy for a pretty good picture into the future. I tend to agree with that. So I say regardless of what side of the aisle we are on, let's get on with the work. Let me say, thank you all very much. I was a little annoying and snippy to all of you. I didn't intend to do that, to be that way. I was trying to extract out of you some good comments, and we certainly got some. Mr. Sanders, you and I sparred very well. I appreciate that, with a good sport. Mr. Sanders. Mr. Kanjorski, after today's panel, I am changing my name to George Mason. Chairman Kanjorski. I had a much stronger comment than that, but I did not use it. Thank you all very much. We hope you still make your planes and trips back. You have done a great service. It is one of the elements that we are going to take up as we are going through the reformations of the GSEs and other problems of establishing a better focus for real estate in the country. Thank you very much. The Chair notes that some members may have additional questions for this panel which they may wish to submit in writing. Without objection, the record will remain open for 30 days for members to submit written questions to today's participants and to place their responses in the record. Before we adjourn, the following will be made a part of the record: a letter from Essence Guaranty to Secretaries Geithner and Donovan regarding reform of the housing finance system. Without objection, it is so ordered. The panel is dismissed, and this hearing is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 4:35 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X July 29, 2010 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]