[House Hearing, 111 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION OVERSIGHT AFTER THE DODD-FRANK WALL STREET REFORM AND CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED ELEVENTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION __________ SEPTEMBER 24, 2010 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 111-160U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 62-685 PDF WASHINGTON : 2010 ----------------------------------------------------------------------- For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts, Chairman PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama MAXINE WATERS, California MICHAEL N. CASTLE, Delaware CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York PETER T. KING, New York LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina RON PAUL, Texas GARY L. ACKERMAN, New York DONALD A. MANZULLO, Illinois BRAD SHERMAN, California WALTER B. JONES, Jr., North GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York Carolina DENNIS MOORE, Kansas JUDY BIGGERT, Illinois MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts GARY G. MILLER, California RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri Virginia CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York JEB HENSARLING, Texas JOE BACA, California SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts J. GRESHAM BARRETT, South Carolina BRAD MILLER, North Carolina JIM GERLACH, Pennsylvania DAVID SCOTT, Georgia RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas AL GREEN, Texas TOM PRICE, Georgia EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina MELISSA L. BEAN, Illinois JOHN CAMPBELL, California GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin ADAM PUTNAM, Florida PAUL W. HODES, New Hampshire MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota KENNY MARCHANT, Texas RON KLEIN, Florida THADDEUS G. McCOTTER, Michigan CHARLES A. WILSON, Ohio KEVIN McCARTHY, California ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado BILL POSEY, Florida JOE DONNELLY, Indiana LYNN JENKINS, Kansas BILL FOSTER, Illinois CHRISTOPHER LEE, New York ANDRE CARSON, Indiana ERIK PAULSEN, Minnesota JACKIE SPEIER, California LEONARD LANCE, New Jersey TRAVIS CHILDERS, Mississippi WALT MINNICK, Idaho JOHN ADLER, New Jersey MARY JO KILROY, Ohio STEVE DRIEHAUS, Ohio SUZANNE KOSMAS, Florida ALAN GRAYSON, Florida JIM HIMES, Connecticut GARY PETERS, Michigan DAN MAFFEI, New York Jeanne M. Roslanowick, Staff Director and Chief Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: September 24, 2010........................................... 1 Appendix: September 24, 2010........................................... 35 WITNESSES Friday, September 24, 2010 Alvarez, Scott G., General Counsel, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System......................................... 4 Baily, Martin Neil, Senior Fellow, The Brookings Institution..... 22 Cross, Meredith B., Director, Division of Corporation Finance, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission........................ 5 Steckel, Marc, Associate Director, Division of Insurance and Research, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation................ 7 Stuckey, Darla C., Senior Vice President, Policy & Advocacy, Society of Corporate Secretaries and Governance Professionals.. 25 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Alvarez, Scott G............................................. 36 Baily, Martin Neil........................................... 49 Cross, Meredith B............................................ 60 Steckel, Marc................................................ 70 Stuckey, Darla C............................................. 86 EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION OVERSIGHT AFTER THE DODD-FRANK WALL STREET REFORM AND CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT ---------- Friday, September 24, 2010 U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Barney Frank [chairman of the committee] presiding. Members present: Representatives Frank, Watt, Moore of Kansas, Green, Hodes, Ellison; Bachus, McHenry, Posey, and Lance. The Chairman. The hearing will come to order. I apologize, I lost track of the time, and I am sorry. We will begin with the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green, for an opening statement for 3 minutes. Mr. Green. I thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I thank the witnesses for appearing today. I am honored, Mr. Chairman, that you called this hearing and I thank you for doing so. I would like to mention very briefly a few pieces of statistical information that I think are exceedingly important. Currently, we have in this country a poverty rate that consumes about 43.6 million Americans. And this poverty rate is juxtaposed to persons who are making inordinate amounts of money and paying a capital gains tax. The numbers speak for themselves. We had in 2007 a person who made $69.7 million working for one of our leading firms. And by the way, I salute people who make large amounts of money. I want people to make as much as they can honestly earn. But it is interesting to note that $7.25 cents an hour, what this person has made in 1 year would take a minimum-wage worker 4,878 years to make. That person who made the $69.7 million is making about $9.3 per second. And, of course, this person has reason to envy the hedge fund manager who in 2007 made $3 billion, which would take a minimum-wage worker about 198,000 years to make, as the person making the $3 billion makes roughly $400 per second. Finally, I had mentioned the hedge fund manager who made $4 billion in 2009 which would take a minimum-wage worker 265,252 years to make, the hedge fund manager making about $534 per second. I mention these not because I begrudge the persons who make these sums of money. I mention it because we have people in this country who work very hard, who make minimum wage, and it is very unfortunate that the people who support the maximum- wage earners, the persons who can make these hundreds of dollars per second, $400 per second, $534 per second, support the maximum-wage earners but would eliminate the minimum wage. Support the maximum-wage earners paying a capital gains tax of 15 percent, but would eliminate the minimum wage. The minimum- wage workers deserve as much consideration as the maximum-wage workers. I stand for helping both, and I will not allow the minimum-wage workers to be left behind. I yield back the balance of my time. The Chairman. The gentleman from Florida is recognized for how much time-- Mr. Posey. I thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I want to thank you for calling this hearing. The Chairman. Three minutes for the gentleman from Florida. Mr. Posey. I want to thank you for calling this hearing, Mr. Chairman. This is a subject which has long interested me. When we had the major bank CEOs here, one of the members asked them for their compensation and they said what it was. And then they were asked what it was the year before as the ship was sinking and, to be sure, they included bonuses, and they went from I think about $12 million to $60 million, something like that. I wouldn't want to be held to that. And it left you to wonder, obviously, if one of them had gone down in a plane crash, if in fact their stockholders would have been hurt to the tune of $12 billion, $20 billion, $60 billion in their absence. So the question that begs for an answer, of course, is what relationship there is between the people on these compensation committees and the people they compensate? I hope you will address that in your remarks today and we will discuss it in questions: How much transparency is there now? How much transparency is opposed? Have there ever been any findings or prosecutions for an improper relationship for which the citizens, the stockholders, suffered? Those are some of the interests that I have and that I hope you will address today. And I want to thank the chairman again for holding this hearing. The Chairman. Any other requests for time on our side? If not, I will just take a few minutes to say that the genesis of this hearing, frankly, was an article in the New York Times by Robert Shiller with whom we have had good conversations, in which he wrote that he thought executive compensation had to be addressed, and I noted that we had in fact done that. He wrote about the Squam Lake Group which consisted, as I recall, of economic officials from the second Bush Administration, I believe, and the Clinton Administration not currently involved. And we noted that we had done some things, and I invited them to come and testify. We have given the regulators authority and we would like them to talk about how they are going to use it. One thing we should be clear on: At no point did any of our legislation, either on say-on-pay, which applies to all corporations or the more specifically financial ones here, have we addressed the dollar amount. That is not our job and we do not try to fix the amounts. We did, in the say-on- pay, try to empower the shareholders. In this, the financial area, the problem is not the level but the incentive. There is a widespread view among many analysts and subscribed, it seemed to be, by all the regulators including those appointed by the Bush Administration and the Obama Administration, that the incentive structure was the problem. That a problem of heads I win, tails I break even, did not appropriately incentivize people. So what the legislation does is not in any way to set dollar amounts or authorize anybody to set dollar amounts but to deal with the question of the incentive structure and try to empower the regulators and to mandate them to so structure the rules so that people are not incentivized to take risks excessively, by which we mean assist, whereby people take a risk and if it pays off, they do well; and if they take a risk and it does not do well at all, they break even. That is not a rational incentive structure. And so we are pleased to have with us a couple of economists who have been--one of the economists who has been involved in this and also someone from the industry. And that is the genesis of this hearing, it did come from an article by Professor Shiller and a representative of the group, the Squam Lake Group, will be here. We have given the authority to the regulators and we want to talk about how it should be used. The gentleman from Alabama. Mr. Bachus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. General Counsel Alvarez and Directors Cross and Steckel, I am not sure how you were assigned the job to draft these rules, but I suppose you are going to use your real names on the draft; is that right? I guess it is a thankless job and it is a difficult job, but it could be more difficult if you were charged with looking into the pay of athletes or entertainers. So there is probably some silver liner there. Obviously, this is a subject that is very popular and almost everything has been said about it that can be said, but at least this hearing, the scope of this hearing is limited to executive compensation oversight after the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, so this hearing is limited, and I think maybe something newsworthy will come out of the hearing. We look forward to your testimony, but I know you have a difficult job and there are literally thousands of different opinions on what you ought to do. And it is a difficult subject. I thank you. The Chairman. Any further requests for time? If not, we will begin with our witnesses and we appreciate their testifying. We should note that when we originally called this hearing, the assumption was the House would be in session. It is not, and therefore you have fewer members, but that may or may not distress you. I remember touring a Hollywood studio in 1981 in my first year, because I was on the Judiciary Committee and dealing with copyrights and they were giving me a tour of the studio. They were making a movie with Nastassja Kinski, and I forget who else, and it involves people who turned themselves into panthers or who were turned into panthers by some other force. And when we toured the site, the people from the studio apologized to me because the panthers weren't there. I said I wanted to be very clear. As far as I was concerned, no one ever had to apologize to me for not putting me in the presence of panthers. And so maybe, that is the way the witnesses feel; no apology is needed for the fact that there are fewer panthers here than there might otherwise be. But in any case, we do appreciate their coming, and we will begin with Scott Alvarez and your statement, Mr. Alvarez. STATEMENT OF SCOTT G. ALVAREZ, GENERAL COUNSEL, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM Mr. Alvarez. Thank you very much, Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and all the members of the committee. I appreciate the opportunity to discuss the oversight of incentive compensation practices, an area in which the Federal Reserve has undertaken significant initiatives. Incentive compensation is an important and useful tool for attracting and motivating employees to perform at their best. At the same time, poorly designed or implemented compensation arrangements can provide executives and other employees with incentives to take imprudent risks that are not consistent with the long-term health of the financial organization. To help address these problems, the Federal Reserve led the development of interagency guidance on incentive compensation that was adopted by the Federal banking agencies last June. We are also close to completing a horizontal review of incentive comp practices at large complex banking organizations. Section 956 of the Dodd-Frank Act provides important support to these efforts by requiring that the Federal banking agencies, the SEC, the NCUA, and the Federal Housing Finance Agency prescribe joint standards governing incentive compensation. The guidance adopted by the Federal banking agencies is based on three key principles: First, incentive comp arrangements should provide employees with incentives that are appropriately balanced so they do not encourage employees to expose their organizations to imprudent risk. Second, these arrangements should be compatible with effective controls and risk management. And third, these arrangements should be supported by strong corporate governance, including active oversight by the organization's board of directors. The guidance applies to senior executives. It also applies to non-executive employees who either individually or as a group have the ability to expose the banking organization to material amounts of risk. The guidance recognizes that activities and risks may vary significantly across banking organizations and across employees within a particular banking organization. As a result, one approach to balancing risk and reward will certainly not work for all. Moreover, the guidance includes several provisions designed to reduce burdens on smaller banking organizations. At the same time, in order to help ensure that large banking organizations move rapidly to bring their arrangements into compliance with the principles of safety and soundness, last fall the Federal Reserve initiated a special horizontal review of incentive comp practices at a number of large complex banking organizations. We are currently reviewing a substantial amount of information collected in this horizontal review and expect to provide each firm with individualized feedback this fall. After the assessments are completed, implementation of the incentive comp plans will become part of the supervisory expectations in normal supervisory process for each of these organizations. Firms have put forth significant effort to find constructive solutions to the issues we and they have identified. In addition, over the course of the horizontal review, we have observed and encouraged real, positive change in incentive compensation practices. While significant improvements have been achieved, it should not be surprising that time will be required to implement all the improvements that are needed, given firms' relatively unsophisticated approach to risk incentives before the crisis, the complexity of compensation issues, and the large number of employees who receive incentive comp at large banks. Importantly, the Federal Reserve expects large complex banking firms to make significant progress to improve the risk sensitivity of their comp for the 2010 performance year. After 2010, the Federal Reserve will prepare and make public a report on trends and developments and incentive comp practices at banking organizations in order to encourage improvements throughout the industry. Section 956 of the Dodd-Frank Act supports these efforts and improves the ability of Federal regulators to collect information about incentive compensation arrangements at a wide range of financial firms. The Dodd-Frank Act also empowers the appropriate Federal agencies to prohibit any type or feature of incentive comp payment arrangements that encourage inappropriate risks by a covered financial institution. By expanding the scope of coverage to include many large nonbanking firms, as well as supporting the Federal banking agencies' efforts, the Dodd- Frank Act helps level the playing field and reduces the potential for sound practices at banking firms to be undermined by arrangements at other financial competitors. I appreciate the opportunity to describe the Federal Reserve's efforts in this area and I am happy to answer any questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Alvarez can be found on page 36 of the appendix.] The Chairman. Our next witness is Meredith Cross, who is the Director of the Division of Corporation Finance at the SEC. STATEMENT OF MEREDITH B. CROSS, DIRECTOR, DIVISION OF CORPORATION FINANCE, U.S. SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION Ms. Cross. Good morning, Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and members of the committee. My name is Meredith Cross, and I am the Director of the Division of Corporation Finance at the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. I am pleased to testify on behalf of the Commission today on the topic of executive compensation oversight. The Commission's role in this important area has traditionally been to require timely, comprehensive, and accurate disclosure to investors about a company's executive compensation practices and procedures. One challenge the Commission faces is that compensation practices continually evolve and become increasingly complex. The Commission has revised its disclosure rules to address these changes, including most recently in 2006 and 2009. Currently, we are focused on implementing the requirements in the Dodd-Frank Act which address an array of compensation issues. I will briefly summarize those provisions and our plans to implement them. Section 951 requires a shareholder advisory say-on-pay vote at all companies subject to our proxy rules at least once every 3 years, and a separate advisory vote on the frequency of say- on-pay votes at least once every 6 years. This section also calls for new merger proxy disclosure about, and a shareholder advisory vote on Golden Parachute arrangements. Although no rulemaking deadline is specified, the Commission's goal is to adopt final rules in time for the 2011 proxy season, since the say-on-pay and say-on-frequency advisory votes apply to shareholder meetings beginning January 21, 2011. Section 957 requires the national securities exchanges to amend their rules to prohibit brokers from voting uninstructed shares on certain matters including executive compensation. On September 9, 2010, the Commission approved changes to the New York Stock Exchange rules that implement this mandate, and the Commission expects to approve corresponding changes to the rules of the other exchanges soon. Section 952 requires the Commission to mandate new listing standards concerning compensation committee independence and compensation consultant conflicts of interest, and to adopt related disclosure requirements. These rules generally must be prescribed by July 16, 2011, and the Commission anticipates proposing these rules soon. Sections 953 and 955 direct the Commission to amend our rules to require three new disclosures concerning executive compensation: First, the relationship between executive compensation actually paid and the financial performance of the company. Second, total annual compensation of the CEO, the median total annual compensation of all other employees, and the ratio between these amounts. And third, whether employees or directors are permitted to engage in certain hedging transactions against the downside risk of company equity securities. Section 954 requires the Commission to adopt rules mandating changes to listing standards so that listed companies will have to adopt and disclose clawback policies for recovering compensation from current and former officers in certain circumstances. The Act does not specify deadlines for rulemaking under Sections 953, 954, or 955, but the Commission's goal is to publish proposals by July 2011. Finally, Section 956 requires the Commission and other Federal regulators to jointly prescribe regulations or guidelines applicable to covered financial institutions, including, from the SEC's perspective, registered broker- dealers and investment advisers with assets of a billion dollars or more. The regulations or guidelines, which must be prescribed no later than April 21, 2011, will require disclosure to the appropriate Federal regulators of the structures of incentive- based compensation and prohibit incentive-based payment arrangements that the regulators determine encourage inappropriate risks. We are working with our fellow regulators to develop these regulations or guidelines within this timeframe. The SEC's Web site has a series of e-mail boxes to which the public can send comments before the various Dodd-Frank implementation rules are proposed and the official comment begins. So far, comments on the executive compensation provisions range from those expressing general concern about compensation practices, to others providing detailed suggestions for implementation of specific provisions of the Act. The Commission is committed to ensuring that our disclosure rules provide investors the information they need to make informed voting and investment decisions and to implementing the provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act, addressing compensation issues as required by the Act. Further, we are committed to working with our fellow regulators to prescribe regulations or guidelines for covered financial institutions to prohibit incentive-based payment arrangements that encourage inappropriate risk, as mandated by the Act. Thank you again for inviting me to appear before you today. I would be happy to answer any questions you may have. [The prepared statement of Ms. Cross can be found on page 60 of the appendix.] The Chairman. And finally, Mr. Marc Steckel, who is the Associate Director of the Division of Insurance and Research at the FDIC. STATEMENT OF MARC STECKEL, ASSOCIATE DIRECTOR, DIVISION OF INSURANCE AND RESEARCH, FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION Mr. Steckel. Good morning, Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and members of the committee. I appreciate the opportunity to testify on behalf of the FDIC at this hearing on the oversight of executive compensation after passage of the Dodd-Frank Act. The structure of employee incentive compensation programs can affect banks' risk profiles and long-term performance. Without question, compensation programs that rewarded short- term profitability without accounting for risk were one in a series of factors that contributed to the recent financial crisis. As deposit insurer, the FDIC brings a unique perspective to the regulation of incentive compensation practices. When a bank's compensation programs encourage the poorly managed risk- taking that precedes many bank failures, the Deposit Insurance Fund pays for the consequences of that excess. Prior to the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act, the FDIC began to increase its efforts to curb the risky compensation practices that helped precipitate the financial crisis. As early as November 2008, the FDIC and other Federal banking agencies issued a statement addressing the need to rein in risky compensation practices in an interagency statement on meeting the needs of creditworthy borrowers. In January of this year, the FDIC issued an advance notice of proposed rulemaking to examine whether the FDIC's risk-based assessment system should be updated to consider the risks presented by poorly designed incentive compensation programs. The ANPR solicited public comment on whether the deposit insurance assessment system could be used to complement supervisory standards--to incentivize banks to use compensation programs that are even less risky than those allowed under safety and soundness guidance and regulations. Using the deposit insurance pricing system in such a way would be consistent with existing features of the system, which, for example, provides a comparative advantage to banks that choose to operate with capital levels greater than those mandated by supervisory standards. The FDIC has reviewed the comments received in response to the ANPR and continues to work with the proposal. While our work isn't done yet, I can share that the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation does not seek to limit the amount of compensation that employees can earn. Our view is that addressing the structure of compensation programs would be a more effective approach. Moreover, we do not believe that a one-size-fits-all approach is the best policy either. Our view is that employee incentive compensation programs that are balanced and aligned with the long-term interest of all the banks' stakeholders present lower risk to the Deposit Insurance Fund. Based on the comments received from the public, academics, and others, and our own research, FDIC staff has identified certain features of incentive compensation programs that we believe can help protect the Deposit Insurance Fund. First, boards of directors and senior managers of financial institutions must take primary responsibility for ensuring incentive compensation programs effectively align employees' motivations with the long-term interests of the institution. Second, portions of employees' incentive compensation should be deferred and subject to meaningful lookback mechanisms that allow awards to be reduced or rescinded if the original justification or the award proves over time to be invalid. Employees who have a portion of their incentive compensation deferred have less incentive to engage in risky behavior and, furthermore, must be concerned with the long-term health of their employer to ensure that they will receive the award at a later date. In early 2010, the FDIC joined the Federal Reserve to review compensation practices used by large banking companies. Later, in June of this year, the FDIC joined the other Federal banking agencies in issuing the interagency Guidance on Sound Incentive Compensation Policies. Turning to the implementation of the compensation provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act, I would note that Section 956 is the provision that most involves the FDIC. This section will strengthen the authority of the FDIC and other regulators over incentive compensation practices at covered financial institutions. The FDIC has begun discussions with other regulators on how to implement the requirements of Section 956. The FDIC will continue to work with our fellow regulators and continue to seek ways to bring our unique perspective and capacity as deposit insurer to bear on this important issue. I appreciate the opportunity to testify and will be happy to answer any of your questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Steckel can be found on page 70 of the appendix.] The Chairman. I thank all of you. First of all, let me ask--we did try to work with you-- the provisions of the bill that you all work with, my impression is that those are generally consistent with the direction you were going in on your own. Are there any things in the bill that could be a problem for you and that need to be fixed? We don't think so, but my sense is that we were basically empowering you and encouraging you to do what you wanted to do anyway. Mr. Alvarez? Mr. Alvarez. I agree with you, Mr. Chairman. We think this has been very helpful. If there is anything that comes up as we get further into this process, we will certainly come talk with you. The Chairman. Anybody else? Ms. Cross. We agree. The Chairman. The question, then, is what we are told of course, is nice try, but all those smart business people will outwit all those bureaucrats and they will come up with some new ways. I think we anticipated that by giving you general authority not to circumscribe. But let me ask you, do you believe--first of all, you have obviously begun talking to and have been talking to some of the people you variously supervise. What is your sense of their approach? My own view is that, frankly, if this is done uniformly, a number of companies would welcome it; that is, we have control for the competitive advantage, that if everybody is under a set of fair rules, they appreciate that because you don't have a kind of a competitive effect and the reaction you are getting from the various institutions under your jurisdiction. Mr. Steckel, let's start with you. Mr. Steckel. Thank you. We got comments on the Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking that we issued earlier this year. We got over 15,000 responses and most of them--in fact predominantly, they were in favor of us pursuing some approach. The minority of the comments we got were not supportive, and a lot of those were sort of on technical matters, and there were a few that were just philosophically opposed to the government having any role in compensation. The Chairman. Of course the FDIC had moved--the Federal Reserve, before we acted, but I take it the statute is in general consult with the direction were you moving in. Mr. Steckel. That is right. I think the statute is supportive of the approach that we were pursuing. The Chairman. Let me ask you the final question I have, which is the argument, yes, but all those smart people in the financial institutions will outsmart all you stodgy bureaucrats and all of us benighted politicians and find ways around all this. A two-part question. Is there any indication that they are trying to do that? And if there is, do we need to give you more authority in case they do? Let's start with Mr. Alvarez. Mr. Alvarez. I think one of the things that is helpful here is that the banking institutions at least understand the problem as well and accept the problem as well. So we don't sense the motivation to get around what we are trying to do. We find the institutions are really embracing the opportunity to limit risk in incentive compensation. I think your first two points, though, were very key to this; we are not trying to limit the level of compensation. We are not putting caps on salaries, so there is less incentive to try to get around that. We are trying to align incentives and aligning incentives is what the industry wants to do as well. And also by having this broadly based across all banking and financial firms, we remove the disincentive. I think firms were very worried that if they were the first one to move, the first one to limit this compensation, they would lose the best people, and we are taking that away. The Chairman. I think that was one of the things we had in mind, which is as you were doing this through your various agencies, unless you could have all done it in total lockstep, which is hard to do, there would have been a complaint about institutional advantage versus another. Ms. Cross? Ms. Cross. I would first note this will be a new role for the SEC as it relates to the broker-dealer and investment adviser compensation oversight. So my fellow regulators have a head start, but we are learning from them and working with them to get there. I think there are a few points worth noting that should make this successful. I think first off is that it is a principle-based approach as opposed to caps and so it is hard to find--avoid a principle, the principle being that you are not supposed to structure your compensation to create inappropriate risks. Another aspect that I think makes this successful is that the compensation committee is responsible for oversight of compensation, at least as to higher paid executives, and they are subject to fiduciary duties and they will be accountable; and there will be the say-on-pay vote so there are enough different pieces of this to make it have a lot of sunshine and a lot of shareholder input. And then lastly we have--the SEC adopted disclosure requirements last year that would require disclosure if you have risks that expose you--have compensation programs that expose you to inappropriate risks. So I think that combination of factors suits us well and it should be successful. The Chairman. Thank you. Mr. Steckel, do you have anything you want to add? Mr. Steckel. Yes, I do. There are two points, I think. The FDIC has pursued a lot of thinking around the idea of deferral. Large bonuses can be awarded and in many cases are earned and deserved. We don't have an argument about that, but in some cases they have been paid out but later the risks that were assumed blow up and cause problems for an awful lot of people and sometimes the public interest. We think meaningful lookback mechanisms are an important part of this. Also we have explored the topic of aligning employees' interests, incenting employees to consider all of the banks' stakeholders. We think current practice currently aligns employees' interest with those of shareholders pretty well, probably to the detriment of some other stakeholders. The Chairman. Thank you. Not as a question, but as to procedure, we are going to be going to the second panel, which includes Mr. Baily who is, again, a representative of the Squam Lake Group. So I would hope that either you or some of your staff could stay behind. We thought that was a very thoughtful, bipartisan cross- Administration approach, and we hope you would able to listen to what they say and work with them as well. Mr. Bachus? Mr. Bachus. Thank you, Chairman Frank. In my opening statement I mentioned entertainers and athletes. But the distinction that I would argue and I think is correct is athletes and entertainers don't lose billions of dollars of the assets of their corporations, and therefore there is no negative impact on the shareholders and on the broader economy. And certainly in the run-up to the Wall Street crash, we had numerous instances of traders or employees who took what I would call bad-tail risk, what you all--if that is the proper word for it--which actually resulted in insolvency for those institutions, to the shareholders, and taxpayers and the general economy suffered. So there are obviously--I think to address this and financial reform was the proper thing, and I want to make that clear. Incentive compensation packages, I think all Republicans would agree with our members in the majority, a need to be consistent with safety and soundness practices, particularly if you have a Federal backstop or Federal safety net. As we found with systemic risk, our large corporations I think it is essential, because of the interconnectivity of the economy, as we have all learned. I do think with bad-tail risk, that is something I would assume you are all going to focus on, because we found out that really one employee, or one or two employees can bring down the largest insurance company in America. I think bad-tail risk, you have defined it, or the regulators or the industry, as a low probability of occurring, but if it does occur, a very high risk of threatening the insolvency of the institution. So I would say that is something that you really need to focus on. I don't know with smaller companies where there is not a Federal backstop, not a systemic risk if the role is not a little bit different. But let me say this; your testimony was very thoughtful, every one of you. Let me conclude with a question. I usually ask questions. That was a statement. But I do want to make it clear to Chairman Frank and to the public that there is widespread consensus not only among the public, but I think within the financial industry and within the Federal regulators and all of us, that compensation practices can threaten the safety and soundness of institutions and that there has to be some governance and oversight of that. My question is, Nell Minow testified last year and she said, ``I have a low confidence in politicians and bureaucrats.'' So she actually addressed us in the least favorable terms, but I will change that to Members of Congress and government officials, that she has very little confidence in them being able to review incentive compensation plans at financial institutions not to micromanage. She's afraid, and I think that is a fear we all have, that there will be too much micromanagement. How will your agency embark on this joint rulemaking and supervision without micromanaging compensation? I will just ask, do you see that as a problem or could it be a problem? Mr. Alvarez. So the approach that we have taken is, first, we are not trying to set the level of salary of individual employees, we agree we are not good at that; that is up to the corporation to deal with itself. So we have been focusing on structure and process. We are making sure the board of directors is involved in the decision-making. We are making sure that the management can explain why it awards bonuses in one situation and not in other situations. We think that in order to deal with things like tail risk, the corporation should take into account deferral practices and clawback practices and a variety of other practices that are being developed by the industry, by academics, by HR professionals, risk management professionals, and bringing that to bear so the risks that come about from incentive compensation are not unintended and don't encourage greater risk to the organization. So we are not about micromanaging the actual pay for individuals. We are about making sure the incentive structure and process leads to a good result. Mr. Bachus. And if I could get the other two to answer? Ms. Cross. Although we are at the beginning of this, from the SEC's perspective, we have the same approach in mind. And I don't think we have any interest in micromanaging the pay. We want to make sure we do what Congress directed us to do, which is to work with our fellow regulators to come up with standards that should decrease the risk of incentives that are dangerous. Mr. Bachus. Okay, thank you. Mr. Steckel. The FDIC has taken a fairly slow approach to this, because as you study this and you try to do good policy, it does become apparent that it is difficult and we want to avoid unintended consequences. I agree with the others in that we do not want to micromanage. We will not be setting pay levels. But I think conceptually we do have an interest in the structure of compensation and that large discretionary awards in many cases should at least in part be deferred to see if the tail risk does come up and cause a problem later. We have spent a lot of time talking to industry professionals over the past year to help us form our views, and we are familiar with the work of the Squam Lake Group which has influenced our thinking somewhat. Mr. Bachus. Thank you very much. I appreciate it. I think your written testimony is going to be very helpful to us and I think, too, to the industry and to the public. The Chairman. The gentleman from North Carolina. Mr. Watt. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think I will pass. I was hoping to try to get to hear the second panel's testimony before I left, so I am going to try to expedite that. This testimony is very clear. So, Mr. Chairman, I am passing. The Chairman. The gentleman from Florida, I guess, was here first by Republican rules. Mr. Posey. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairman. We will get to you. Mr. Posey. I kind of want to echo the comments made by the gentleman from Alabama. Your intent and your advice is thoughtful and well-intended and I hope will be very effective. But if we tend ever to use a cannon to kill a sparrow, it causes a little bit more collateral damage than we intend sometimes. And I just want to express that I think the more complex you make the regulations, as the chairman said, the more wiggle room you are going to have and the more plans to circumvent it or take away the intent of what you are doing. I think probably the absolute best accountability that we can have is the absolute best possible transparency, and I am not sure how all the compensation was arrived at. I am sure much of it was made in contractual deals downstream that said, if you do this you are going to get this. And so it may not have been decisions made after the fact at all, and may not in the future be made after the fact. It may be a predetermined set of guidelines that you may or may not have any control over. I think with the transparency goes responsibility to have strict enforcement and prompt prosecution for violations. As we know, at the SEC we don't have a long history of that. And the FDIC activities that I have seen most recently in my district with the bank regulators gives me less confidence than ever in that agency. I think they are--just as I mentioned in some discussion yesterday-- going off in a wrong direction out of fear or self-protection or whatever. But I would appreciate during whatever time is left if you could explain briefly the difference between a typical--and I don't mean everyone would fit in that category--but a typical executive compensation and the relationship between the compensation committee and the chairman, or whoever they are compensating, and the difference between that relationship in the future as you foresee it under your guidelines. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairman. Was there a need for comment? Mr. Posey. I would like a comment briefly from each of them, if you don't mind. The Chairman. I am sorry, go ahead. Mr. Steckel. The FDIC, as a policy goal, I think our focus is on material risk-takers. We are not interested in targeting many, many bank employees who may get small referral bonuses or small end-of-year performance bonuses that in no way could influence them to affect the overall health of an institution. But some higher paid employees can take those sorts of risks and can get paid an awful lot of money for that. I think we would tend to focus on those employees. There is really not a problem to fix with lower paid employees, I don't think. Ms. Cross. I will mention a couple points. Under the Act, there will now be a requirement for listed companies that the compensation committee be comprised solely of independent directors, and there will be enhanced disclosures about compensation committee independence. So I think that might get at part of your concern. On the who will do this work and what is their relationship to the people that they are overseeing, boards of directors in general are responsible for risk oversight at companies. Sometimes they delegate that to a committee like a risk committee. At companies these days, what has been happening is the compensation committee stays responsible for the executive compensation and so including, for example, the CEO pay, and there would be the requirement for independence in the future. And then the risk oversight would be from the board overall and that would be for the broader employee programs. So I think there will be several different checks and balances within the board, and particularly strengthened by what you did in the Act. Mr. Alvarez. I agree with the previous two about the involvement of the board of directors, and independent compensation committee in particular, in reviewing the CEO salary as you raised. The point I would add is that for the most senior executives, I think we place particular emphasis on deferral of incentive compensation awards with adjustment of those awards as the risks mature and show up in an organization, so that CEOs in particular have their incentive compensation adjusted for the health of the company and the risks that show up in the company in the future. Not all risks show up immediately, so they need some time for those to mature and we would like those to be reflected in the incentive compensation award. Mr. Posey. Can I ask a follow-up question, Mr. Chairman? Thank you. But suppose that I am the person in charge of hiring a CEO for my big bank, and I go to you and I say, look, I am going to pay you the average salary, $800,000 a year, and I am going to pay you a bonus based on, hypothetically, let's say 1 percent of the net profits. And he performs. I got what I wanted, he gets what he wanted; it will be $4 trillion under those circumstances. But he wrecked us in the meantime. What are you going to do? Mr. Alvarez. The expectation is that the incentive compensation award would have a way of reducing--deferring that payment. So that 1 percent that you spoke of, the bonus wouldn't be paid immediately; it would be deferred over some period of time to allow the company to realize whether it has been wrecked. And if losses do indeed show up, then that award would be reduced. And what that does is, that removes the incentive for the CEO to take big risks immediately because they know those will show up in a reduction in their incentive compensation at a future time. Mr. Posey. I think that would be--one more question, since we don't have very many people. The Chairman. We are already 2 minutes over. Mr. Posey. Okay. The Chairman. The gentleman from Texas, thanks to the generosity of the gentleman from Kansas. Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Again, I thank you and the witness as well. I would like to just briefly explain why in my opinion it is very important to talk about the amount of the compensation. If we don't talk about the amount--and I am not begging the witnesses to do so--but it is important for us to do so. If we don't talk about the amount of the compensation, we don't really get an understanding as to why people would assume the types of risks that they assume, why they have this incentive to do these things. And systemic risk is not created by persons who make minimum wage, not created by persons who are making $50,000, $60,000, or $70,000 a year, generally speaking. This systemic risk is created by persons who make hundreds of dollars per second. I mentioned the CEO who made $534 per second, which in about 28 seconds allows him to make what a minimum worker makes all year. This is the kind of compensation what we are talking about. And I applaud the bill, I applaud Chairman Frank, and Chairman Dodd. I applaud you for indicating that we are not going to micromanage the pay of individuals; that is not what it is about. It is about making sure that the pay doesn't produce systemic risk, that is what it is about. But people in the American public have to understand what the pay is, so that they can see why people assume this type of risk and why they will do these kinds of things. It is huge. The amounts of money are escalating, they are not deescalating. The amount of executive compensation has been consistently going up, while creating this gap between low-income workers and maximum-income earners. We are doing the right thing by putting into place regulations that will curtail the taking of systemic risk, which, in my opinion, helped to create the crisis that we had to contend with. And finally I will say this, as I am about to make my exit. I have spoken longer than I actually intended to, but I do want to say something about the athletes, if I may, and whether they bring down a team. If they don't perform, the tickets don't sell. If the tickets don't sell, the stockholders do lose money. But that is besides the point. The point that I really would make in terms of making a distinction between the athletes and some of these persons who make $500 a second is that the athletes pay ordinary income taxes, the hedge fund manager pays capital gains tax, 15 percent ordinary income; it could be 36 to 40 percent depending on how you count it. But it is not about athletes, it is about systemic risk, and it is about the inordinate amounts of moneys that I salute people for making because they have a talent to make, but that in some way can create liability for others when systemic risk is produced. Mr. Chairman, I thank you and I yield back the balance of my time. The Chairman. The gentleman from New Jersey. Mr. Lance. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Good morning to you all. I think this is a very important discussion. The bill states regarding incentive-based compensation that the regulation community will decide what is inappropriate. Could each of you briefly give me your thoughts as to where you might be headed, as to what you might consider to be inappropriate. And I know it is a very broad question, but your initial thoughts as to that. Mr. Steckel. I think one thing that comes to mind is an exorbitantly large guaranteed bonus that gets paid regardless of the performance of the institution. Mr. Lance. And would you likely place an amount as to what is exorbitantly large? Mr. Steckel. No, I don't think we are prepared to do that, and I am reluctant to. Mr. Lance. So ``inappropriate'' would be translated as exorbitantly large. Mr. Steckel. I think we need to have some policy discussion. Mr. Lance. Yes. Ms. Cross? Ms. Cross. I would describe it in a more principle-based fashion as pay where the risks to the institution outweigh the rewards to the institution. So you would need to consider, looking at the type of pay structure, whether it has that impact. And if it does, it is inappropriate. You shouldn't be paying people more to expose the company to more risk than the company would be rewarded if it worked out well. Mr. Lance. Thank you. Mr. Alvarez? Mr. Alvarez. I agree with Ms. Cross. It is very nuanced, there is no number, there is no automatic piece. It is about the risk that is incented by the compensation and whether that is something the company can handle. Mr. Lance. Thank you. I am sure we will be reviewing it with you as the process continues. Shareholders, of course, will have the right on say-on-pay. I think the bill may be somewhat ambiguous as to whether it should be an advisory or binding vote. Does the panel have a position on that? I think that is particularly directed at Ms. Cross. Ms. Cross. I am happy to address that. I think the bill is actually clear that it is nonbinding as it relates to both say- on-pay and say-on-frequency. Mr. Lance. Yes. Ms. Cross. There is some ambiguity as to whether the frequency vote is nonbinding, but our view is, reading the entire provision, that the part at the end that says it is a nonbinding vote applies to the whole Section, so-- The Chairman. If the gentleman would yield, that is certainly our intent, and if ever they felt we needed to clarify it, we would I am sure be able to do that quickly. But the intent was and, I think, in fact it is nonbinding. Mr. Lance. Thank you. That is clarifying. And I am pleased that the SEC is of that opinion, and I certainly defer to the Chair. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back the balance of my time. The Chairman. Let me say, by the way, if I can have a minute of unanimous consent. One reason that has to be nonbinding is that if it was binding, you couldn't pay them anything. It is just a practical thing. And the English experience which we have looked to is that nonbinding is pretty influential. The gentleman from Kansas. And I appreciate his deferring to our colleague from Texas. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. One of the major concerns that continues to be raised by my friends across the aisle and the business community is a lack of certainty when it comes to the new rules businesses face. But given the near collapse of our financial system, I don't know how anyone can responsibly argue that a complete overhaul of our financial rules, as we did with the Dodd-Frank Act, was not warranted. And while businesses want certainty, they also want well- thought-out rules that are not hastily written, creating unintended consequences. Given this strain between speed and quality rulemaking, what steps are your agencies taking to implement the new rules quickly, while also performing due diligence to improve executive compensation rulemaking? Mr. Alvarez. The banking agencies have already issued guidance. We sought public comment from the industry and from consumer advocates and others about the policies. And we have already begun, actually, our horizontal review or examination of the practices at large organizations, which involves a dialogue with them about how best to improve their systems, the philosophy they bring to incentive compensation, and then the principles that we are trying to get them to adopt. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you. Ms. Cross? Ms. Cross. With regard to the SEC's rulemaking initiatives, both for the executive compensation matters and all the other matters under Dodd-Frank where we have rulemaking, we set up public e-mail boxes where people can send in their comments even before we start with public rulemaking, so that we are able to take those into account as we get the rules ready for the public; and then, as always, will benefit from the public comment that comes in. We are also meeting with many interest groups and posting the agendas from those meetings on the Web site so the people can see the topics that are under consideration. We agree it is very important that we have all the due diligence we can have so that these rules work well. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you. Any comments, Mr. Steckel? Mr. Steckel. Yes. Chairman Bair has made this issue a priority, before and after passage of Dodd-Frank. We think Dodd-Frank helps us to our end and we are going to continue to pursue this vigorously. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you. And I have one more question. We have all focused on what went wrong in the financial crisis and I think it is very appropriate, but I think it is equally as important to learn from the responsible actors and build on their successes. So last month the oversight committee I chair held a field hearing in Kansas to learn from responsible Midwest banks and credit unions who were not the cause of the financial crisis. And my question is, with respect to the new executive compensation rules that your agencies are drafting and implementing, what will it mean for community banks and credit unions? And in the rulemaking, are you avoiding one-size-fits- all approaches that may unfairly discriminate against smaller firms? Mr. Alvarez. Sir, we have been quite clear in our guidance that we expect the types of adjustments on incentive compensation to vary based on the complexity, size, and use of incentive compensation by firms. So smaller banking organizations tend to not use incentive compensation very much, and they also have short, flatter organizations, much easier to police, and understand the risks that are associated with incentive compensation. So we haven't seen a problem coming up with smaller organizations. So our guidance makes allowance for that. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you. Ms. Cross? Ms. Cross. I will cover your question as it relates to the other executive compensation rulemakings since the banks are really for my fellow regulators. There are numerous provisions in the Dodd-Frank Act that tell us to consider the impact on small business as we implement the rules, and we will carefully, carefully do so and request comment so that we can calibrate the rules appropriately, so that we don't unduly burden small business. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you. Mr. Steckel? Mr. Steckel. Yes. I think you are right. There are an awful lot of small banks that use limited, if any, amounts of incentive compensation as part of their business model, and we will specifically not target them. I don't think they are the problem that we are trying to address here. Mr. Moore of Kansas. Thank you very much to the witnesses. Mr. Chairman, my time is nearly up. I yield back. The Chairman. The gentleman from North Carolina. Mr. McHenry. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I certainly appreciate your testimony. I wasn't here for your verbal testimony, but I have read your testimony. How do you plan to deal with multinationals? Section 953 has been cited by some as a logistical nightmare. How do you intend to deal with an individual's compensation to the overall firm's earnings and income that is not simply a domestic bank but a multinational? Ms. Cross. I think that one is for me. We are just beginning the rulemaking process, and we expect to propose the rules under 953 next summer. It doesn't have the same deadline, so we will have the opportunity as we prepare the rules to get input from everyone about how we should address those concerns. We have heard that there are worries about the logistics of figuring out the pay in a multinational firm. So we are looking through those provisions now, working with all the interested parties, and we will put together a rule proposal we think can best implement it in a way that is workable. Mr. McHenry. Okay. So, generally speaking, you are going to do what you normally do, which is you are going to input and make a rule; that is basically what you are telling me? Ms. Cross. The Act directs us to adopt a rule to implement that provision. So we are doing what we are tasked to do under the Act. If we run into problems, we will let you know, and we will come back if it is something that isn't workable, but we would first like to try to see if the rule can be implemented in a way that results in implementing what we have been tasked to do in a way that is workable. Mr. McHenry. Okay. Yes. Mr. Alvarez. One thing I would add, in the banking area, there is an awareness worldwide that incentive compensation practices need to change, and we have been working with some of our foreign counterparts, especially through the Financial Stability Board, to develop standards that are being used on an international basis. Our guidance is very much in tune with the international direction of the FSB. So we are actually heartened that the other parts of the world are seeing the importance of all of us moving down this road together. Mr. McHenry. How important do you think that is with basically foreign standards that are similar to ours? Mr. Alvarez. I think it is very important because of the incentives that are created. We don't want to lose our best talent to foreign competitors or have businesses move offshore in order to avoid incentive compensation rules. So it is important that this be an international work. Mr. McHenry. Certainly. Now, Ms. Cross, you mentioned to my colleague from New Jersey that weighing the balance of pay, an individual's pay, whether that--the potential gain outweighs the systemic risk, that is basically what you are--similar to what you said; isn't that right? Ms. Cross. That is right. Mr. McHenry. Isn't that in many respects in the eye of the beholder? Ms. Cross. Again, I think that I would like to emphasize that we don't envision micromanaging the pay of any particular individual. It is much more of a structural question. So, as you develop guidelines or regulations that set forth standards for how the pay is to be structured, limitations really on the structure of pay that would present those risks, as in the guidance that has already been issued, you would look in terms of, what risk does it pose for the company, and are they appropriately calibrated? Yes, it is in the eye of the beholder, but the compensation experts have significant input and have, I think, reflected in the guidance that you can calibrate it to appropriately reflect risk. Mr. McHenry. So, therefore, a trader and a CEO can have different rules? Ms. Cross. I think that is right. I think there would be different structures that would be appropriate for a trader versus a CEO. Mr. McHenry. Okay. But even in the case of some similar failed institutions that the Federal Government has a significant ownership interest in currently, in different sections, different divisions of the company, you have people compensated in very similar ways. One lost billions of dollars for the institution; the other made hundreds of billions of dollars for the institution. So even with basically the same incentive packages, you are going to have widely variant outcomes and widely different systemic risk based on the nature of their business; is that fair to say? Ms. Cross. I think that has historically been the case. And I don't want to speak for the folks who have already done this, but the horizontal review they have been going through to find out what are the compensation practices throughout these organizations should help us as regulators develop guidelines that would be appropriate so that is more appropriately calibrated throughout the organizations. The Chairman. If the gentleman would yield, I would acknowledge when I called this hearing I was thinking frankly about the provisions that we initiated, which was the say-on- pay and executive piece. The Senate added that other piece, and I share some of the questions about that. I think it was imprecisely worded. It is not clear. It seems to me if you look at the wording literally, an inappropriately large number of people are involved in the comparison, and obviously if that can be worked out, okay. But we are very much open to try to fix that legislatively because that was the Senate piece, and you are right. It is appropriately on the table. Mr. McHenry. And let's understand that truly the debate is not between Democrats and Republicans. The true enemy is the Senate. The Chairman. In this case, there is the House-Senate difference. Mr. Bachus. Could you further yield? And I appreciated those questions. I thought they were insightful. One of the things that I know in the written testimony that you address, similar to that last question, is that compensation doesn't vest immediately, and therefore, although a trade may have a short-term positive, it may be a long-term disaster. And we talked about the bad-tail risk, and even if you have one trader who makes a half billion dollars, you have another trader who gets wiped out for $2 billion--which we have seen, a very large amount. So the fact that one could make and one could lose, if the one that loses bankrupts a corporation, that is a serious risk. But the other thing is, that often you can maximize short- term profits at the sacrifice of long-term profits. The Chairman. If the gentleman would yield. I think we all agree that is why we haven't tried to be too rigid but have given discretion to the regulators, precisely on that compensation. The gentleman from Minnesota. Mr. Ellison. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thanks for pulling this hearing together. I only have a few questions. My first question is, in light of the passage of the Frank- Dodd bill, the provisions on compensation, have you seen adjustments within the industry? Have you witnessed any sort of a self-correcting conduct that would sort of align compensation with proper incentives for the company? Mr. Alvarez. We have been doing a horizontal review where we are actually looking at the practices, and we are finding that institutions are taking steps on their own. They have identified some of the very same problems that we had identified in the guidance. They want very much to remove incentives to folks to increase risk behind the backs, as it were, of the control systems these organizations have put together. So we are finding good cooperation. There are still a lot of uncertainties. There is still a lot of work that needs to be done. One of the things, for example, that is difficult is getting good metrics for risk. Some areas are easier to identify risks than others. You may be able to identify, for example, mortgage loans and the loss rates on mortgages, but it is not always easy to identify if a certain strategic move is going to work out. So it takes some time for those things to develop. So we continue to work with organizations to find good metrics and to use judgment that is well informed when there are not good metrics, but as a general matter, we think the institutions are willing and interested in making change. Ms. Cross. I would note that the concept of finding out whether pay creates inappropriate risk is a relatively new idea that people are just learning about, and so, for example, particularly at the nonbanks, the sort of rank-and-file public companies, they are in the process now of doing inventories of their incentive programs and figuring out, do these create inappropriate risks for the companies? And it has been a very good exercise I think for boards to hear what kind of programs there are and what kind of risks they may pose, and then the companies over time can revise those programs. So I think this is not just at the financial institutions. I think it is throughout our capital markets, which is a very healthy thing. Mr. Steckel. I would add that we see banks paying a lot more attention to this recently than say a few years ago. Both the passage of Dodd-Frank and also a lot of bad press that was out there about these companies pushed them in that direction. We also think that the rulemaking that is required under Dodd- Frank is also necessary to make sure we don't, over time, backslide to some of the bad practices that occurred years ago. Mr. Ellison. Can you all report on what you are seeing about these rules and the legislation and the application of the rules that are being promulgated on people who work below the top executive level? So many decisions are not made at the top executive level, and I think it is important we pay attention to those incentives as well. Just a very quick story. I met with a group of people who worked in a bank, and they were told they couldn't hand back over overdraft fees that they were urged to push people to open up new accounts, and these are people on the bank level working with customers. Their incentives were to have people open up more accounts so they would generate more fees, have, you know--not push back overdraft stuff, and there is just a lot of pressure on these line employees. I don't think this will work--do you see that this bill could affect the way they are compensated? Do you see it traveling down that far? Mr. Alvarez. Our guidance specifically provides that it must. We don't deal just with senior executives. We deal with any employee or group of employees who can increase materially the risk to the organization. And what we had in mind, another example, are mortgage originators. Mortgage originators may not make very much money themselves individually. On the other hand, it is important that a firm understand the incentives it creates when it gives bonuses to those folks. Is it encouraging them to just increase volume without regard to risk or increase the volume without regard to compliance with the law? There are lots of things incentive compensation practices in the mid-2000's did that I think we all regret now. So one of the things we have been trying to do--and this is an area where I think there needs to be a little more work by banking organizations--is to identify those groups who are lower paid employees but who do receive incentive compensation and do, as a group, add risk to the organization. Mr. Ellison. Are you in a position to hear from some of those employees? Because I can tell you that some of them are a little nervous about talking to me. I had to promise not to identify their company. They told me about a lot of pressure tactics they were under. Is this something you have been able to do is to hear directly from them? Mr. Alvarez. We do hear directly from some employees through a variety of ways. We also are getting the actual incentive compensation policies that apply to them so we have a chance to look at the actual document. The Chairman. If the gentleman will yield, that is a very important point. We will work with our colleague to make sure that we have channels whereby that kind of information can be sent along in a way that would protect the individuals. We will work with you. The time has expired. I thank the panel. This has been useful. We have a work in progress here. I will say there are some of these things initiated in the House, some in the Senate. My own view, as was indicated by the questions from my colleague from North Carolina, is that the House pieces were somewhat better organized than the Senate piece and that more work will have to be done on that, and we will be working with you on it. We don't rule out the possibility that it will have to be further amended. I thank the panel. I now call up Martin Baily and Darla Stuckey. Thank you. And we will begin with the testimony from Martin Baily, who is a senior fellow at the Brookings Institution, and was part of the Squam Lake bipartisan group of economists who had significant government service who met to discuss this, and Mr. Baily is a former chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers. Would someone please close the door, as you will never know who will wander in here? Mr. Baily? STATEMENT OF MARTIN NEIL BAILY, SENIOR FELLOW, THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION Mr. Baily. Thank you, Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and members of the committee. It is a great privilege to be here. In a sense, I guess, I am representing the Squam Lake group. I do want to mention that I think they see themselves primarily as a group of finance academics. There are a few of us who have served in government. I was in the Clinton Administration, as you mentioned. Fred Mishkin was at the Federal Reserve. Matt Slaughter was in the Bush Administration. But most of the group are actually finance academics, and they got together in an attempt to see if there is anything from finance theory and practice that could contribute to financial sector reform. It is also, as you said, a range of views. Sometimes, we have had to be sort of dragged together to form a consensus, and I do want to say one or two of the things that I will say today may not represent the views of the whole group. Let me get started then. I think the Dodd-Frank Act made substantial steps forward towards improving regulations but, obviously, left a fair amount to be done by the regulators. So I think it is very appropriate. I applaud you for holding meetings such as this. Some of this, as was mentioned earlier, has to be done at the international level, and historically, the international level hasn't been a great forum. The Basel process has not been either timely or effective. There is some sense, I think, that the financial crisis lit a fire under them, and they are doing a better job now, but that is something certainly we have to monitor. Now, the two recommendations from the Squam Lake group that relate to compensation are, first, to discourage any regulation of the level of the compensation, and we have had already quite a bit of discussion of that, and that is in line with the Dodd- Frank Act. So I don't know I need to say a lot about it. I think if I were to make one comment it is that we do indeed have a very wide and widening income distribution in our economy, but it is a much more fundamental problem than just the financial sector. It has to do with, are we providing the right skills to people; do we have the right tax system, and so on. So I don't think that was a matter for financial regulation. I agree with you, the decision you have made about the level. Our recommendation is that the regulators should look at the structure of compensation to make sure that it is aligned with the interests, not only of shareholders in the institution but also of taxpayers who may get called upon to bail out this institution, and I know we have put in place various steps so that we should not have to bail out financial institutions, but we don't know what is going to happen in the future, and I think it is an important tool in the arsenal to make sure that we have the right compensation structure to reduce that possibility. We want to make sure that when executives are making decisions about the risks they are taking in their own institutions, they are not sort of in the back of their minds thinking, if things go wrong, I can get supported by the taxpayer, either in the form of the FDIC or somewhat in the way that happened, unfortunately, in the crisis. A major goal of capital market reform should be to force financial firms to bear the full cost of their own actions, and as I said, we propose several mechanisms and there are such in the Dodd-Frank Act to do that, but compensation is a useful tool. Systemically important financial institutions should withhold a significant share of each senior manager's total annual compensation for several years. The withheld compensation should not take the form of stock or stock options. Rather, each holdback should be for a fixed dollar amount, and employees would forfeit their holdbacks if the government goes bankrupt--excuse me, if the firm goes bankrupt or receives extraordinary government assistance. So we want to make a very direct link between taxpayer interest and incentive on the senior managers of the company. We want to hold them accountable for the possible failure of their company. Now, I talk in my written testimony a little bit about what is currently in the Dodd-Frank Act versus our proposal. I talk a little bit about what regulators are doing. We have heard about that already here. I talk a little bit about what has been proposed in the U.K. financial services authority because, as was noted earlier, it is a good idea to have harmonization, and obviously, London is the other main financial center. This should be more broad than London, but that is obviously the biggest alternative to New York as a financial sector. So let me just draw my conclusions. I am running out of time already. Here I will express my one concern about whether the Squam Lake-- The Chairman. We understand. Take another couple of minutes. We have only a few people. So take another couple of minutes. Mr. Baily. You shouldn't encourage me to blab on, but I will finish quickly. My only concern with the Squam Lake recommendation is whether or not it goes quite far enough, deep enough down the organization. If you have a large organization and an international organization and you are a trader and you see the benefits to you in terms of your bonus of taking on certain kinds of risks, I think the notion of worrying about taxpayers or if the firm might actually go broke and have to be put in receivership with the FDIC or something, that may seem a little bit too remote. So the way in which I myself would go a bit further--and it is along the lines of the testimony that was given earlier--is that each company should work with its regulator, the Federal Reserve or the FDIC or the SEC, to describe what their compensation structure is, how it lines up with their own internal risk management structure, and that they are, in fact, providing the right holdbacks for traders and for other folks within the company to make sure that we don't go to the edge of the precipice; in other words, that we build in incentives for traders that might take big, risky bets but that wouldn't necessarily drive the company into bankruptcy but would pose additional risks on the system. But I do stress that not everyone at Squam Lake agrees with that. There was a good bit of concern among members of the Squam Lake group that we don't want to overregulate this. And I agree with that. We want to maintain incentives for performance, for innovation, all the things which help this be a dynamic sector. I will stop there. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Mr. Baily can be found on page 49 of the appendix.] The Chairman. Thank you. Next is Darla Stuckey, who is the senior vice president for policy & advocacy for the Society of Corporate Secretaries and Governance Professionals. Ms. Stuckey. STATEMENT OF DARLA C. STUCKEY, SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT, POLICY & ADVOCACY, SOCIETY OF CORPORATE SECRETARIES AND GOVERNANCE PROFESSIONALS Ms. Stuckey. Thank you, Chairman Frank, and Ranking Member Bachus. I am here today on behalf of the Society of Corporate Secretaries & Governance Professionals. Our members include corporate secretaries, securities lawyers, compliance officers, and even some executive compensation plan administrators. They work in companies of every size and every State and in every industry. I would love to talk more about us, but if you would like to know more, please go to governanceprofessionals.org. You have asked for our views on the effects of the implementation of the compensation-related provisions of Dodd- Frank, particularly as they affect risk taking and particularly in the financial services area. Without taking a position on the impact of the Act specific to financial services companies only, since all companies are covered by Dodd-Frank, we do believe that the governance changes under Dodd-Frank, along with the SEC rules implemented since the crisis of 2008, generally will help companies manage and oversee risk and further corporate accountability. Our members who are financial services companies simply request that the SEC, the Fed, and the FSA coordinate their compensation rulemaking and do so soon. You also asked for our views on what the Federal regulators should consider, so I now turn to three of the executive comp provisions, and I apologize if you have spoken about these in the first panel at length, but I will talk about say-on-pay, a little bit on pay ratio, and clawbacks, as well as I would like to talk-- The Chairman. No apology. We want your opinion. The fact that the other people talked about it makes your opinion even more important. So, please, go ahead. Ms. Stuckey. Okay. Thank you. I also would like your indulgence to talk a minute or two about the whistleblower provision in Dodd-Frank, which is not specifically executive comp related, but is very important. First, say-on-pay and say-when-on-pay. You know what say- on-pay is, the shareholder vote on executive comp. It is effective for meetings after January 21, 2011. Our only concern with this is that the SEC's schedule as submitted may be too late. We urge the SEC to propose these rules soon in October, so the rules will be out in early January so we can hit the January 2011 target. Given the short timeframe that we have, we suggest they implement rules similar to the TARP companies. They have had it for the last 2 years. Our members would use that as a model and get that done. The Act also requires companies to give shareholders a vote on how frequently--this is what we call--how frequently they should get say-on-pay, we call say-when-on-pay. I guess the SEC calls it say-on-pay frequency. With respect to say-when-on-pay, SEC rulemaking should provide boards a choice this year whether to offer a resolution with their own single recommendation, for example, 2 years; or to give a multiple choice resolution where the shareholders could pick: A, B or C; 1, 2 or 3 years. We believe that this has to be driven by boards and managements. They are in the best position to recommend the frequency to ensure that the timing of the vote is aligned with respect to compensation programs, many of which are driven in 3-year increments. The shareholders will be able to express their views. Finally, on this one, the SEC should clarify that a shareholder proposal seeking an alternative 1-, 2-, or 3-year scheme would be excluded from a proxy statement. This would avoid unnecessary uncertainty or a conflict with the company's resolution, and we don't think it was your intent to have say- when-on-pay votes every year in the 6-year period. Pay-ratio disclosure, I heard some of the colloquy. As you know, it does, by construction, apply to all employees. We would hope that all employees becomes all U.S. employees for U.S. companies and all U.S. full-time employees. We realize this rule won't be implemented until next summer or looked at until next summer, but we think that we need technical clarifications during this time, and we believe that the clarifications should be driven by intent and practical reality, which you have already heard. We don't believe that it was Congress' intent to include workers all over the globe to compare to U.S. CEO's, and in addition, it is quite, quite burdensome. One other thing that would help immensely with this and that we believe the statute should be clarified to provide is that total comp means total direct comp. That is cash: that is base salary, cash bonuses, equity comp, but not pension accruals, 401(k) matches, and other noncash items. Clawbacks: The Act also requires companies to implement policies to recapture incentive comp that would not otherwise have been received in the event of a restatement. This clawback provision is mandatory, provides no board discretion, covers all present and former executive officers, does not require misconduct, and has a 3-year look back; it goes well beyond existing law and practice today. Our biggest concern with this is that boards must have some discretion in this area to implement a clawback. At the least, it must be allowed to determine if recoupment would cost more than the expected recovery amount is worth; that is, whether you have to pursue litigation to get it back, the likelihood of recovery, whether it violates any employment contract, and there are also some State law concerns, that it would violate State law provisions. Surely Congress didn't intend to require clawbacks even where the recovery is less than the cost to recover it. For this reason alone, it is very simple: Boards must be given some discretion. So we urge the SEC to do that in its rulemaking, and at this point, I would recommend to you there is a letter from the Center on Executive Compensation attached to my testimony. The Chairman. Letter from whom? Ms. Stuckey. The Center on Executive Compensation. It is attached to my written testimony. The Chairman. Center for? Ms. Stuckey. Executive Compensation. Finally, I will turn now to the whistleblower bounty provision, and I appreciate your indulgence. It is in every company's best interest to have a robust compliance program, but the SEC and the U.S. Sentencing Commission strongly support effective in-house compliance programs that can prevent and detect criminal conduct or other wrongdoing. Section 922 of Dodd-Frank states that the SEC shall pay an award to whistleblowers in cash between 10 and 30 percent of any money they receive over $1 million that either they collect, the U.S. Attorney collects, any other SRO or any State Attorney General, as a result of the whistleblower's assistance. Importantly, the bounty depends on whether the informant provides original information to the SEC. That is, if an employee is aware of a potential violation and wants to report an issue, he now has to choose whether to raise it to the company or with the SEC. Employees have long been trained to raise issues first with their superior, alternatively with an ombuds or an ethics hotline or even to the chair of the company's audit committee. Under the new whistleblower provisions, an employee will now have a significant financial incentive to bypass raising the issue with the company at all for fear of losing the bounty, because if he raises to the company first, the company might beat him or her to the SEC. And if you believe the New York Post, the threat is real. Yesterday, the Post reported that when the new movie, ``Wall Street: Money Never Sleeps'' opens Friday, today, moviegoers will see an advertisement prior to the movie recruiting whistleblowers who know of misconduct at their companies. The ad will inform people of the potential riches that can come with being a whistleblower, letting them know that they can make money and also do a good thing. The ads also tell people that they can remain anonymous, and it also provides them with the address of the new whistleblower Web site, SECsnitch.com. We don't believe this was the intended result of this provision, having employees bypass their companies. It is contrary to long-established public policy, and it also undercuts the well-established internal compliance programs put in place after SOX that companies have spent so much money on. We suggest that the statute grant bounties but not on the condition that the whistleblower bypasses the company. Finally, we believe the SEC should refer to the defense and health care industries, which have long had to deal with false claims cases and have experience in this area. I encourage you to review my written testimony, and I think my time is up. I thank you. [The prepared statement of Ms. Stuckey can be found on page 86 of the appendix.] The Chairman. I thank both of the witnesses for their testimony. Let me say to Ms. Stuckey, as I did when the gentleman from North Carolina raised it, the provisions about all compensation, the comparisons, did originate in the Senate. We have some questions about it. I guess it would seem clearly there would be a consensus that it shouldn't be every single employee. Now, I don't know whether it was drafted with enough flexibility to allow that, but if necessary, we would have to step in. I think that is clearly the case, and that was not one of the issues that we thought most important. So that would be our general sense would be to--we will be urging the SEC to narrow that, if possible, and if not, then we would do it statutorily if we have to, which clearly is necessary in that regard. Mr. Baily, you did note that with regard to how deep into the company we get, you had your own views they were not universally shared by the Squam Lake group. One question, is the Squam Lake group a one-time group? Are you guys going to hang out some more, or what can we expect from Squam Lake? Mr. Baily. We are going to hang out more. There is some new stuff that is going on to look at, the GSEs, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and a couple of other things. One or two members of the group have made a graceful exit, but we are still in business. The Chairman. With regard to the GSEs, I would advise you not to waste your time to advise us on the post-GSE regime. There will be no more GSE's. I think that is fairly clear. We will obviously be open to what would be replacing them, and that will be very important. The gentleman from Alabama. Mr. Bachus. Thank you, and Mr. Chairman, I want to associate myself with Ms. Stuckey's remarks about the SEC getting their rules on say-on-pay out as soon as they can because businesses need to make decisions, and it would be very helpful. It would give certainty, which is always, I think, a good thing. Let me go back to the question of Ms. Stuckey, for purposes of the median pay ratio disclosure, you said that it ought to apply only with U.S.-based full-time employees, and I tend to agree with you on that, but because this covers all--I am not sure anybody said this. This is not just financial companies; 953 applies to all public companies, which in itself, we have talked about financial companies getting in trouble and the safety net. But would you go ahead and just explain for the record why you believe only U.S. employees. Ms. Stuckey. Sure, I would be happy to. I don't believe--it sort of caught our group by surprise and I understand that there is some appeal and there have been statistics quoted by the media in the past about average worker pay to CEO pay, and I am not sure how correct those are. So I can understand why someone would want to know what the average worker makes. We don't really think that institutional shareholders particularly care about this number, but companies are willing to implement Congress' intent, and it could be hugely burdensome. And without sounding like I am whining, if you are a multinational company and you have 100,00 employees in 20 or 30 or 40 countries, there are lots of pitfalls. There are cross-border issues, like exchange rates. There are privacy laws in France, for example, that might not even allow you to do this, all kinds of things. So if you are willing to work to make this only U.S. employees, a lot of corporate secretaries and human resource professionals will breathe easier. So this is a situation where we don't think the cost would outweigh the benefit of what the number is. And the reason why we don't think that the pension number should be included is the pension number certainly is known for the CEO and the top five folks, but in order to find the median employee, it is very different than finding an average. You have to do an actuarial pension calculation for each of your 8,000 people, say, in the pension plan, and that is for a medium-sized energy company in the Midwest that I spoke to. To do a pension calculation for 8,000 people and line them up in a row and pick the middle guy or gal, that is a huge burden. So we would urge you not to include that at all, but even if you wanted to include that, to allow the calculation to be done without that, find the middle person, then add the pension back in and then do the ratio, if you understand what I mean. Mr. Bachus. I do and let me say this. I agree with you that this would be a very burdensome problem. Mr. Baily, do you have any comment on it? Mr. Baily. I am quite concerned about the level of poverty in the United States. I am quite concerned about the fact that ordinary workers have not done very well in the last few years. I don't see how publishing that ratio helps anybody very much. So I am not a big fan of that. The Chairman. If the gentleman would yield, I would note again, that was a Senate provision, and I think our inclination is to see to what extent it can be lessened as a burden, and if not, we would be able to work to try and change that next year. Mr. Bachus. I think that is very helpful, and I think there is somewhat of a consensus building. Ms. Stuckey, what are some of the other potential hurdles or pitfalls to public companies complying with the Dodd-Frank compensation provision? Ms. Stuckey. I can mention one that I cut out in the interest of time, and that would be the pay versus performance disclosure. There is a new provision that the SEC provide rules on this, and I think companies are anxious about this because they want the rule to be written flexibly enough to explain, whether it be in draft form or not, how compensation actually paid is tied to performance. The current compensation structure of the current chart is not easy to understand. And they want to be able to tell-- boards and comp committees want to be able to tell their story, to explain which point in time relates to which compensation, and that some compensation may be granted in year one. It may be a reward for a past year's performance. It may be incentive for a future year's performance. Some compensation is based on just 3-year straight line performance pay based on net income. But they want to be able to show that at the bottom level, and you may not want to hear this, but at the bottom level, they want to be able to show that their executives are vested, just like the shareholders, and when the share price falls, they hurt, too. So their options become underwater, and the comp number that maybe the media reports isn't really what they got. So we want the SEC to write rules flexibly enough so that companies can tell that story. Mr. Bachus. Okay. Thank you. Mr. Baily, do you have any comment on that? Mr. Baily. No, I don't have any further comment on it. Mr. Bachus. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairman. I would note again that the provision just being discussed is another United States Senate provision. So we will be approaching with some--we will take a fresh look at it. The gentleman from Florida. Mr. Posey. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Baily, did I hear you correctly that before employing employees who should or could be subject to executive compensation requirements, that they should work with the FDIC, the SEC or whoever ahead of time before they make arrangements to employ these people, that they should work with them, they should go to a bureaucrat and get their plans approved or get some kind of warm and fuzzy from them? Mr. Baily. Maybe I misstated or maybe I am misunderstanding your question. I think there is a process going on now where the regulators that are approving the risk-management structures within companies so that they are meeting risk- management standards are asking them to explain what their policy is on compensation. It is not that I want them to say, this is the amount going to each employee and we are going to approve that going to each employee. No, I don't think that is a good idea at all, but what is their policy and does it meet the requirements for risk management, both in terms of their own desire to reduce risk within their institution and to make sure that they are not putting taxpayers in risk should something happen to the company? Mr. Posey. Did I understand correctly--and I will look at the transcript--but you suggested they should go to the FDIC, the SEC or someone beforehand to make sure that their plans are going to be compliant in advance, like there is some latitude given to the bureaucrat to make this judgment call, and they would have some type of influence on the committee who is setting the compensation outside of clear and unambiguous rules that apply to everyone that should be easily understood by the sector of this country that provides jobs and produces and gives us a GDP that we enjoy, that regulates a lifestyle that we had, that we are going to have those people go to a bureaucrat and get an opinion or try and get some kind of feel good signal in advance before they cut a deal? I hope that is not what you said and that is not what the transcript will say because I find that appalling. I find that is probably the quickest way to destroy the economic system we are trying to get to recover, but that would probably do more damage than anything else when you have that kind of intrusion, unclear, very ambiguous, could be arbitrary, could be capricious, affecting private companies', public companies', opportunity to do business. I would think that you would say, here are the rules, if you don't go outside that box, you are okay. If you go outside that box, you are in trouble. Or maybe that you will establish, instead of a zillion different rules, say here's the new fiduciary standard, you have this fiduciary standard to your stockholders, and it would be a jury in question whether or not you break that fiduciary standard, and if you do break it, the consequences are severe. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Baily. I certainly did not wish to create arbitrary and capricious rules or to create a system in which you have to have necessarily warm-and-fuzzy relationships with bureaucrats. So I, too, will look back at the transcript and make sure that I was saying something that I want to stand by. I do understand very much the need to have incentives and opportunities and that businesses be allowed to run their operations, as long as the policies they are following--and there should be clear rules about this, I agree with you again on that--so that within the rules, they are not imposing excessive risk on taxpayers. Mr. Posey. The biggest disincentive in the world is for you to have to clear your decisions with a government bureaucrat on any level. I just think the suggestion that you need some kind of government approval after you have made your decision, inside the box of the guidelines that are established, that should be clear, unambiguous is just staggering to the imagination. Mr. Baily. I take your point. The Chairman. The gentleman from North Carolina. Mr. McHenry. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I certainly appreciate the testimony. And Mr. Baily, your discussion began with, I think, a key point, which is income distribution deals with a lot larger set of issues like skills, education, training, the ramifications of the Tax Code, really the provisional incentives the Tax Code puts in place, and I appreciate you mentioning that at the beginning, because I think the one key thing that we can do as a matter of governmental policy is make sure that there is a skill base out there so that we can have a very diverse, very active economy, and appreciate you starting with that, and that is something that is of issue to me and my constituents at home. The question here today, the reason why we are even having this discussion is really at the heart, and I know the chairman has had this interest in executive comp for long before the financial meltdown. But the reason why we are talking about systemic risk and executive comp, well, compensation structures, is largely because of the Federal Government's actions to prevent a complete and utter meltdown of the financial marketplace. Is that basically your view, Mr. Baily? Mr. Baily. I am sorry, could you just repeat the last sentence? Mr. McHenry. Basically, the reason why systemic risk is the discussion is because the Federal Government had to bail out firms, right? Mr. Baily. Yes. Mr. McHenry. Then you look at the overall structure, and you said, of course, you got paid millions if you did ``X,'' if you failed, and you got paid billions if you succeeded, so of course, the incentive is to not worry about failure; somebody else will pay for it. My concern is this: We write a regulation, and to Ms. Stuckey's point, you have three or four different regulators, they write three or four similar regulations but just dissimilar enough, that you can't really please everyone, and then they stay on the books. And in the end, the marketplace figures out a way, with the force of money and the power of money and the power of ideas in order to make more money as individuals, and they get around it. So basically, it is great. Congress feels good. We have stuck it to these folks that were making all this money, and we feel good, and in the end, it nets out with nothing. Is that a concern that you have, Mr. Baily? Mr. Baily. Yes, it is a concern. Now, as we discussed a little bit in the earlier panel, one response to that is that many of these companies, and I think maybe that is a little also in answer to the earlier question, a lot of these companies are themselves reforming their own compensation structures, so they are not saying, oh, no, we don't want to do that. Some of them actually did it before the crisis. Some of the better companies and more enlightened companies had pretty good compensation structures, and they did withhold bonuses over several years, and in most cases, those companies fared better over this crisis than the ones that did not. So I don't think we are pushing this down the throats of most companies. We are trying to do things that, by and large, they are doing on their own. The only thing that we added I think in the Squam Lake Report was to make sure we don't just end up with systems that kind of align the employees with the shareholders, meanwhile forgetting that taxpayers could be on the hook. And so we want to make sure that at the level of incentive, particularly to the CEO, but to senior management, that they know that some of their pay is on the line if taxpayers have to get involved and so we can help avoid some of these bailouts that we had. Mr. McHenry. Would you agree that the best way for this to actually happen is not through a government regulation but through a corporation's reform within? Mr. Baily. I think there is an interest in--we do have supervision and regulation of our financial institutions. So I don't think we can just leave it to the companies themselves to do it. I think we have to make sure that it is being done in a way that protects us as taxpayers rather than just leaving it to-- Mr. McHenry. Beyond financial firms. Mr. Baily. Oh, beyond financial firms? Mr. McHenry. I think that is an answer. Mr. Baily. I can certainly come back with a response, but if these are not companies that are going to get bailed out or receive government interest, by and large, they should do their own thing without the interference of the government. Mr. McHenry. Okay. And certainly it would be in the shareholders' interests to ensure, such as say-on-pay, can have their say-so and take their capital away from firms that don't have the right incentive structure where the CEO and the executives aren't truly aligned with the interests of shareholders, and the marketplace can make that choice. And that is what many of us are saying. It is not that we certainly support certain compensation amounts. It is that we believe in the individual ownership of that company rather than government regulation. And finally, Mr. Chairman, I appreciate your indulgence, but to Ms. Stuckey's point about total direct compensation versus an individual who has worked for a company for 30 or 40 years and started at the retail, checking people out, has worked their way up and is number two in line to the CEO and, after 40 years, has a lot of deferred compensation, and it appears that he has a lot more direct compensation from the firm than he truly does. And I appreciate your interest, and I have folks in my district who have that very issue that it certainly overstates what they believe is really worthwhile to disclose. Ms. Stuckey. I would agree, and I just, if you have 1 minute, I can give you a couple of other things, questions that have actually been raised by people attempting to gather the information: What do we do with 401(k) matches? What about mid- year employees or part-timers? People who have come on with an acquisition? What about severance? What about people who are downsizing, given their huge severance package because they have been there 30 years and maybe you have accelerated their vesting, what do we do about that? What do you do about overtime and shift differential payments of hourly workers? And then, of course, there is the overseas currency, nonmonetary components, like apparently in overseas countries, many people get cars. Sometimes they even get food. There are a lot of things that might have to be valued. So that is the sort of nuts and bolts stuff that we are concerned about. Mr. McHenry. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairman. I thank the witnesses. This will be an ongoing process, and this has been useful, and we will continue to work on it. The hearing is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 11:55 a.m., the hearing was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X September 24, 2010
![]()