[House Hearing, 115 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] A LEGISLATIVE PROPOSAL TO CREATE HOPE AND OPPORTUNITY FOR INVESTORS, CONSUMERS, AND ENTREPRENEURS ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ APRIL 26, 2017 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 115-17 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE 27-417 PDF WASHINGTON: 2018 _____________________________________________________________________________ For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Publishing Office, Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov. Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina, MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking Vice Chairman Member PETER T. KING, New York CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma BRAD SHERMAN, California STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York BILL POSEY, Florida MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin DAVID SCOTT, Georgia STEVE STIVERS, Ohio AL GREEN, Texas RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota ANN WAGNER, Missouri ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado ANDY BARR, Kentucky JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania BILL FOSTER, Illinois LUKE MESSER, Indiana DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona BRUCE POLIQUIN, Maine JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio MIA LOVE, Utah DENNY HECK, Washington FRENCH HILL, Arkansas JUAN VARGAS, California TOM EMMER, Minnesota JOSH GOTTHEIMER, New Jersey LEE M. ZELDIN, New York VICENTE GONZALEZ, Texas DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan CHARLIE CRIST, Florida BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia RUBEN KIHUEN, Nevada ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia THOMAS MacARTHUR, New Jersey WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio TED BUDD, North Carolina DAVID KUSTOFF, Tennessee CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana Kirsten Sutton Mork, Staff Director C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: April 26, 2017............................................... 1 Appendix: April 26, 2017............................................... 89 WITNESSES Wednesday, April 26, 2017 Allison, John A., former President and Chief Executive Officer, Cato Institute................................................. 15 Barr, Hon. Michael S., Professor of Law, University of Michigan Law School..................................................... 9 Cook, Lisa D., Associate Professor, Economics and International Relations, Michigan State University........................... 12 Michel, Norbert J., Senior Research Fellow, Financial Regulations and Monetary Policy, the Heritage Foundation................... 7 Peirce, Hester, Director, Financial Markets Working Group, and Senior Research Fellow, Mercatus Center, George Mason University..................................................... 14 Pollock, Alex J., Distinguished Senior Fellow, the R Street Institute...................................................... 10 Wallison, Peter J., Arthur F. Burns Fellow, Financial Policy Studies, American Enterprise Institute......................... 6 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Allison, John A.............................................. 90 Barr, Hon. Michael S......................................... 93 Cook, Lisa D................................................. 109 Michel, Norbert J............................................ 112 Peirce, Hester............................................... 130 Pollock, Alex J.............................................. 137 Wallison, Peter J............................................ 143 Additional Material Submitted for the Record Hensarling, Hon. Jeb: Coalition letter of suport for the CHOICE Act................ 182 Written statement of the Credit Union National Association... 185 Written statement of the National Association of Insurance Commissioners.............................................. 200 Written statement of the National Association of Mutual Insurance Companies........................................ 203 Written statement of the National Association of Professional Insurance Agents........................................... 208 Capuano, Hon. Michael: Written statement of William F. Galvin, Secretary of the Commonwealth, Commonwealth of Massachusetts................ 211 Clay, Hon. William Lacy: Written statement of Keith Mestrich, President and CEO, Amalgamated Bank........................................... 215 Duffy, Hon. Sean: Written statement of the Property Casualty Insurers Association of America..................................... 217 Ellison, Hon. Keith: Report of the Democratic staff of the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform entitled, ``An Examination of Attacks Against the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,'' dated July 13, 2011.......................... 225 Written responses to questions for the record submitted to John A. Allison............................................ 262 Written responses to questions for the record submitted to Peter J. Wallison.......................................... 264 Emmer, Hon. Tom: Written responses to questions for the record submitted to Hester Peirce.............................................. 272 Huizenga, Hon. Bill: Written statement of Duff & Phelps........................... 299 Love, Hon. Mia: Chart entitled, ``Average Value of Lending BEFORE Dodd- Frank''.................................................... 303 Chart entitled, ``Average Value of Lending AFTER Dodd-Frank'' 304 Luetkemeyer, Hon. Blaine: Written statement of the Electronic Payments Coalition....... 305 Written statement of the Independent Community Bankers of America.................................................... 310 McHenry, Hon. Patrick: Written statement of the Retail Industry Leaders Association. 312 Ross, Hon. Dennis: Written statement of the Food Marketing Institute............ 314 Written statement of the Merchant Payments Coalition......... 317 Written statement of the National Retail Federation and the National Council of Chain Restaurants...................... 319 Written statement of various undersigned national and state merchant trade associations................................ 323 Royce, Hon. Edward: Written statement of the National Association of Federally- Insured Credit Unions...................................... 331 Trott, Hon. David: Chart entitled, ``Rules Applicable to U.S. Financial Services Holding Companies Since July 2010''........................ 335 Waters, Hon. Maxine: Center for American Progress report entitled, ``President Trump's Dangerous CHOICE, Will He Embrace House Republicans' Plan to Gut Wall Street Reform?'' dated April 2017....................................................... 336 Letter to Chairman Jeb Hensarling stating that the Democrats will hold a separate hearing on the CHOICE Act............. 374 Letters of opposition to the CHOICE Act...................... 377 Written statement of the North American Securities Administrators Association Inc, and the Minnesota Commissioner of Commerce................................... 516 A LEGISLATIVE PROPOSAL TO CREATE HOPE AND OPPORTUNITY FOR INVESTORS, CONSUMERS, AND ENTREPRENEURS ---------- Wednesday, April 26, 2017 U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:09 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Jeb Hensarling [chairman of the committee] presiding. Members present: Representatives Hensarling, Royce, Pearce, Posey, Luetkemeyer, Huizenga, Duffy, Stivers, Hultgren, Ross, Pittenger, Wagner, Barr, Rothfus, Messer, Tipton, Williams, Poliquin, Love, Hill, Emmer, Zeldin, Trott, Loudermilk, MacArthur, Davidson, Budd, Kustoff, Tenney, Hollingsworth; Waters, Maloney, Velazquez, Sherman, Meeks, Capuano, Clay, Lynch, Scott, Green, Cleaver, Moore, Ellison, Perlmutter, Foster, Kildee, Delaney, Sinema, Beatty, Heck, Vargas, Gottheimer, Gonzalez, Crist, and Kihuen. Chairman Hensarling. The Financial Services Committee will come to order. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess of the committee at any time. Today's hearing is entitled, ``A Legislative Proposal to Create Hope and Opportunity for Investors, Consumers, and Entrepreneurs.'' I now recognize myself for 5 minutes to give an opening statement. It has been almost 7 years since the passage of the Dodd- Frank Act. We were told it would lift our economy, but instead we are stuck in the slowest, weakest, most tepid recovery in the history of the republic. The economy does not work for working people. They have seen their paychecks stagnate; they have seen their savings decimated. We have seen millions who remain unemployed and underemployed in an economy working at roughly half of its potential. Dodd-Frank has been a bigger burden to enterprise than all other Obama-era regulations combined. There is a better way, and it is the Financial CHOICE Act of 2017. This bill replaces onerous government fiat with market discipline, ends bailouts with bankruptcy, throws a deregulatory life preserver to our community financial institutions, replaces complexity with simplicity, holds both Washington and Wall Street accountable, and unleashes capital formation so the economy can move yet again for the betterment of all of our citizens. Under the Financial CHOICE Act there will be economic opportunity for all and bank bailouts for none--again, bank bailouts for none. Perhaps that is why press reports indicate that most Wall Street banks oppose the Financial CHOICE Act. The damage Dodd-Frank has done to consumers and business is well known to every Member, but let me remind you of just a few: 75 percent of banks used to offer free checking before Dodd-Frank became law; by 2016 only 38 percent did. Minimum balance requirements to qualify for free checking have almost quadrupled, and average monthly fees more than tripled. This helps explain why the number of households that are unbanked and underbanked is up by more than 3 million since the passage of Dodd-Frank. Data show that there are 50 million fewer credit cards available since 2008 and the remaining options cost more now, hurting small businesses and struggling families. The Federal Reserve reports that once Dodd-Frank's qualified mortgage rule is fully phased in, an estimated one-third of Black and Hispanic borrowers will be denied mortgages due to its rigid debt-to-income ratio. An overwhelming majority of community banks report that Dodd-Frank's regulatory burdens are preventing them from making more residential mortgage loans. And they have had to hire more staff just to deal with the legal compliance issues. The Dodd-Frank Act represents an even more dangerous prospect, namely, politicized lending. Washington elites are now allocating our capital to fulfill their agendas, devoid of any checks and balances or due process. And it is impossible to bring up the threat of politicized lending without bringing up the CFPB. The Financial CHOICE Act reestablishes this rogue agency as a civil enforcement agency patterned after the Federal Trade Commission, one that is responsible for actually enforcing the enumerated consumer protection laws written by Congress instead of making up its own law in an unfair, deceptive, and abusive manner. True consumer protection is only to be had in competitive, transparent, and innovative markets which are vigorously policed for fraud and deception. That is what the Financial CHOICE Act is all about. The bill releases financial institutions from regulations that create more burden than benefit in exchange for meeting high, yet simple capital requirements--that is, loss-absorbing capital, which is like an insurance policy against failure. Instead of government bureaucrats overseeing banks that plan their failures, the CHOICE Act will see banks plan for their expansions by helping grow the economy for every citizen. The Financial CHOICE Act repeals Washington's authority to designate too-big-to-fail firms--or SIFIs, as they are known going forward, and retroactively repeals previous nonbank SIFI designations. The bill recognizes that illegal activity by bad actors at financial institutions can harm the financial well-being of consumers and society and, therefore, imposes the toughest penalty in history for financial fraud, self-dealing, and deception. The bill repeals the misguided, complex, and unneeded Volcker Rule, as it has made capital markets less liquid, more fragile, and threatens financial stability. Even a Federal Reserve report now admits to this. The bill would unleash opportunities for economic growth, foster capital formation, and provide Main Street job creators with regulatory relief so more Americans can go back to work at good careers and give their families a better life. Ending the bureaucratic nightmare that is Dodd-Frank and replacing it with the simpler capital rules of the Financial CHOICE Act is imperative. America has struggled for far too long. It is time again to hold Washington accountable; it is time to hold Wall Street accountable. It is time for economic growth for all; it is time for bank bailouts for none. So I look forward today to our hearing, and to soon passing the Financial CHOICE Act. I now recognize the ranking member for 4 minutes. Ms. Waters. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, to the witnesses, for being here today. There is only one explanation for why we are here discussing yet another dead-on-arrival version of the wrong choice act. It must be that the foreclosure crisis and the Great Recession somehow weren't enough for the Majority, and so they irrationally want to clear the way for round two. I want to be very clear for anyone who is watching: That is exactly what this bill would result in. The wrong choice act thoroughly dismantles Wall Street reform, guts the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, and takes us back to the system that allowed risky and predatory Wall Street practices and products to crash our economy. During the Great Recession, because of the actions of reckless financial institutions, Americans lost $13 trillion in household wealth, 11 million Americans lost their homes, and the unemployment rate climbed to 10 percent. The impact was widespread and harmful to all. The wrong choice act paves the path back to that kind of economic ruin by rolling back the critical safeguards we put in place in the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act to protect American consumers, investors, and the economy. Today we have sensible Dodd-Frank rules and the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to prevent financial institutions from peddling toxic products or abusing hardworking American consumers. Since its creation the CFPB has returned nearly $12 billion to more than 29 million consumers who have been ripped off by financial institutions. With this financial cop on the block and with important rules of the road in place, Wall Street reform has worked. Since Dodd-Frank passage the economy has created 16 million jobs over 85 consecutive months, and business lending has increased 75 percent. Banks large and small are posting all- time record profits; community banks are out-performing larger banks; and credit unions are expanding their membership. But here we are. And even though Wall Street reform has made them safer and they are raking in profits, that is not enough for the banks. They want to go back to the bad old days of fewer protections, and they have shamelessly undertaken a full-court press to get a long wish list of giveaways, most of which have been compiled in this bill. Democrats are going to fight against it and stand up for Main Street. This bill must not become law. There is too much at stake for consumers and for our whole economy. And I will now yield to Mr. Kildee, the vice ranking member. Mr. Kildee. Thank you, Madam Ranking Member, for yielding. This so-called Financial CHOICE Act ends the most important aspects of Wall Street reform, which were designed and passed to prevent another financial crisis. Pushing this bill puts Wall Street ahead of Main Street once again. The wrong choice for hardworking Americans, it puts Wall Street back in charge and does away with those very protections that were enacted after the financial crisis, and puts the economy back at risk. And let me be clear: I and other Members on this side support improving some aspects of Dodd-Frank. But have we forgotten the lessons of the financial crisis? This takes us back to the days where Wall Street practices nearly crippled our economy, back to the days where millions of people lost their homes, lost their jobs, saw their retirement savings wiped out. The people that I represent have not forgotten these dark days, and the committee should not forget them either. Removing these important financial safeguards while at the same time eliminating the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, designed to protect consumers against those abuses, is the wrong choice and this committee ought to reject that. With that, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now yields 1 minute to the gentleman from California. Mr. Sherman. Mr. Chairman, this CHOICE Act takes some good bills that passed this committee with overwhelming and bipartisan majorities, puts them together with a lot more bad bills that do not have bipartisan support, and gives Members no choice. They are ultimately going to have to vote up or down. Mr. Chairman, please break up this bill. You say we don't have free checking anymore. You used to pay for checking because your checking account got about 4 percent less interest than the passbook account. In a zero interest rate environment or even a very low interest rate environment, obviously banks got rid of free checking in many cases, and in other cases they are trying to get it unfreezed. Finally, you say we don't have the economy we need. We need a better trade policy. You can't have a half-trillion-dollar trade deficit and then say, ``We are going to make up for that by deregulating the banks and reinstituting the disasters that we suffered in 2008.'' The idea that we can make up for bad trade policies and restore the economy by letting Wall Street do anything they want didn't work in 2008. It is not going to work now. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. We will now turn to our panel of witnesses. First, we welcome the testimony of Mr. Peter Wallison. He is the Arthur F. Burns fellow in financial policy studies at the American Enterprise Institute. He previously served as General Counsel of the U.S. Treasury Department and as White House Counsel to President Reagan. He received both his B.A. and J.D. from Harvard University. Second, Dr. Norbert Michel is a senior research fellow at the Heritage Foundation. He was previously a professor at Nicholls State University College of Business, where he taught finance, economics, and statistics. Dr. Michel holds his B.A. from Loyola University and a doctoral degree in financial economics from the University of New Orleans. Third, the Honorable Michael Barr is a professor of law at the University of Michigan Law School, where he teaches financial regulation, international finance, and financial derivatives. He previously served as Assistant Secretary for Financial Institutions at the Treasury Department. He received both his B.A. and J.D. from Yale University. Fourth, Mr. Alex Pollock is the distinguished senior fellow at the R Street Institute. Previously he served as a resident fellow at the American Enterprise Institute, and as the president and CEO of the Federal Home Loan Bank of Chicago. He received his B.A. from Williams College, a Master's in Philosophy from the University of Chicago, and a Master's of Public Administration from Princeton University. Fifth, Dr. Lisa Cook is an associate professor of economics and international relations at Michigan State University. Previously, she was a senior economist on the Council of Economic Advisors. As a Marshall scholar she received her B.A. from Spelman College and a second B.A. from Oxford University; she earned a Ph.D. in economics from the University of California Berkeley. Sixth, Ms. Hester Peirce is a senior research fellow at the Mercatus Center. She previously served as staff for the Senate Banking Committee, as well as the Securities and Exchange Commission. Ms. Peirce earned her B.A. in economics from Case Western Reserve University and her J.D. from Yale Law School. And last but not least, Mr. John Allison is the former president and chief executive officer of the Cato Institute. Prior to his time at Cato he was the longstanding chairman and CEO of BB&T Bank. Mr. Allison graduated from the University of North Carolina Chapel Hill and received his Master's Degree in management from Duke University. Each of you will be recognized for 5 minutes to give an oral presentation of your testimony. I think perhaps with one exception, you have all testified here before, but as a slight refresher course, green means go, yellow means you have 1 minute left, and red means you had best wrap it up. Without objection, each of your written statements will be made a part of the record. Mr. Wallison, you are now recognized for 5 minutes for your testimony. STATEMENT OF PETER J. WALLISON, ARTHUR F. BURNS FELLOW, FINANCIAL POLICY STUDIES, AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE Mr. Wallison. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Ranking Member Waters, and members of the committee. Thanks for the opportunity to comment on the Financial CHOICE Act. The act would repeal or substantially modify large portions of the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act. As outlined in my prepared testimony, there are two important things to know about Dodd- Frank: It is primarily responsible for the historically slow recovery of the U.S. economy since the 2008 financial crisis; and it was completely unnecessary. Enacted hurriedly, Dodd-Frank misdiagnosed the financial crisis. Without serious investigation, the Obama Administration and Congress assumed or wanted to believe that the crisis was caused by insufficient regulation of Wall Street and the financial system. In 2009, before any committee hearings, Chairman Barney Frank said that Congress would adopt a ``New New Deal.'' He was correct. The Dodd-Frank Act was by far the most restrictive financial regulatory law since the 1930s. If, instead of jumping to pass new regulations, Congress had stopped to consider why we had a financial crisis it would have found government housing policies were the cause. In 1992 Congress enacted the Affordable Housing Goals, which required Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to meet certain quotas when they bought mortgages from banks. First, the quota was 30 percent: In any year, 30 percent of the loans that Fannie and Freddie bought had to be made to borrowers who were at or below the median income where they lived. HUD was given authority to increase these quotas and did so aggressively through the Clinton and the Bush Administrations. By 2008 the quota was 56 percent, meaning that more than half of all mortgages they acquired in any year had to be made to borrowers at or below the median income. The purpose of the goals was to increase mortgage credit for these borrowers, but it had the effect of forcing Fannie and Freddie to reduce their underwriting standards. Although they had traditionally accepted only prime loans, which require 10 to 20 percent downpayments, they couldn't find enough of these loans among borrowers who met the quota. By the mid-1990s they were accepting loans with 3 percent downpayments; and by 2000, loans with zero downpayments. What Congress did not understand when it adopted the goals was that Fannie and Freddie, which were by far the largest buyers in the market, set the underwriting standards for everybody else. So their reduced underwriting standards spread to the wider market. Banks and others made these risky loans to compete with lenders who were also making risky loans and selling them to Fannie and Freddie. By 2008 more than half of all mortgages in the United States were subprime. And of these, 76 percent had been bought by Government agencies, primarily Fannie and Freddie. That shows without question that the government created the demand for these loans. Risky loans, in turn, created an unprecedented 10-year housing bubble between 1997 and 2007. When the bubble deflated, housing and mortgage values fell 30 to 40 percent nationwide, causing losses to many financial firms and banks that held mortgages or mortgage-backed securities. Fannie and Freddie themselves became insolvent and had to be bailed out with $180 billion in taxpayer funds. Because Congress did not know what really caused the crisis, it was led to adopt a series of unnecessary restrictions in the Dodd-Frank Act, detailed in my prepared testimony. Among them are: first, costly regulations on community banks, which prevented the growth of small business and the employment small business produces, causing 7 years of stunted economic and employment growth. Second, the creation of the FSOC, with the power to designate firms as SIFIs; among other things, this caused G.E. to close down G.E. Capital, which had been a successful lender to small business and other growth companies. Third, an unnecessary orderly liquidation authority that will make it likely to be difficult for very large financial firms to find financing in the future. Fourth, authority for the Fed to finance failing clearinghouses, which would pave the way for another financial crisis. And fifth, the Volcker Rule, which has drastically reduced liquidity in the financial markets, creating the potential for another financial crisis. The CHOICE Act can't be enacted too soon, Mr. Chairman. Thank you for your attention. [The prepared statement of Mr. Wallison can be found on page 143 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Thank you. Dr. Michel, you are now recognized for your testimony. STATEMENT OF NORBERT J. MICHEL, SENIOR RESEARCH FELLOW, FINANCIAL REGULATIONS AND MONETARY POLICY, THE HERITAGE FOUNDATION Mr. Michel. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling, Ranking Member Waters, members of the committee, thank you for the opportunity to testify today. I am a senior research fellow in financial regulations at the Heritage Foundation, but the views that I express in this testimony are my own and they should not be construed as representing any official position of the Heritage Foundation. My testimony argues that Dodd-Frank needlessly increased borrowing costs and that removing this excess burden will markedly increase sustainable economic growth. Dodd-Frank worsened the too-big-to-fail problem, expanded the command-and- control type of financial regulations that have harmed people for decades, and pointlessly addressed issues that had nothing to do with the 2008 financial crisis. My remarks will provide one example of each of these three Dodd-Frank failures. The first is the new Dodd-Frank resolution process that keeps large failing financial firms out of bankruptcy after Federal regulators certify that no viable private alternatives exist. This is unequivocally the wrong approach. The very theory behind a legal bankruptcy process is that it provides for orderly resolution of a distressed firm. It offers a financial timeout so that the company can remain a viable business while staving off a mad rush of creditors trying to get their claims settled first. Bankruptcy provides protection to debtors, which is why creditors don't like bankruptcy. So it is no surprise that over time these protections have been whittled down. The main problem with the Bankruptcy Code after 2005 was that it provided nearly all derivative and repo agreement counterparties safe harbors from key bankruptcy protections, such as the automatic stay. These safe harbors were justified on the grounds that they would prevent counterparties from running, thus worsening a systemic crisis, but that theory has now been proven wrong. The Financial CHOICE Act implements an improved process-- bankruptcy process--for large financial firms by adopting the Financial Institution Bankruptcy Act of 2016, legislation that subjects derivatives and repos to an automatic 48-hour stay. The temporary stay is a welcome improvement, and the elimination of the safe harbor and all other bankruptcy safe harbors or derivatives and repos would be optimal. The second major policy mistake is that Dodd-Frank created an unaccountable Federal agency based on a flawed concept of consumer protection. I am referring, of course, to the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau and so-called abusive acts and practices. The United States did not need and does not need either. The CFPB is unaccountable to the public in any meaningful way and raises serious due process and separation-of-powers concerns. Most importantly, there was no shortage of consumer protection prior to the Dodd-Frank Act. Title X of Dodd-Frank created the CFPB by transferring enforcement authority for 22 specific Federal statutes to the new agency. These Federal statutes were already layered on top of State laws and local ordinances, and this framework has for decades outlawed deceptive and unfair practices even in financial products and services. The CHOICE Act greatly improves the status quo by making the CFPB Director removable at will, putting the agency through the regular appropriations process, eliminating the abusive behavior concept, and relegating the CFPB to an enforcement- only agency. These changes would provide an enormous benefit to U.S. citizens, but Congress can do even better by eliminating the CFPB and consolidating its enforcement authority at the Federal Trade Commission. The third major policy mistake that I will discuss is the Durbin Amendment. Section 1075 of Dodd-Frank implemented price controls on the interchange fees charged in debit card transactions, and it did so based on the premise that banks and card networks had colluded to fix prices. If, in fact, banks and card networks are guilty of these actions then merchants and any other aggrieved parties have a remedy in Federal court. The issue is actually quite simple. Long before 2010 Congress had done its job by creating anti-trust law. It should never have jumped into the middle of a legal dispute as if it were the Judicial Branch. Congress should repeal the Durbin Amendment and restore the rule of law, letting the courts decide if, in fact, there was collusion and price-fixing. Thank you for your consideration, and I am happy to answer any questions that you may have. [The prepared statement of Dr. Michel can be found on page 112 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Mr. Barr, you are now recognized for 5 minutes for your testimony. STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE MICHAEL S. BARR, PROFESSOR OF LAW, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN LAW SCHOOL Mr. Barr. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Ranking Member Waters, and distinguished members of the committee. It is my pleasure to appear before you today. The Dodd-Frank Act was passed in response to the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. In 2008 the United States plunged into a severe financial crisis that shuttered American businesses and cost millions of families their jobs, homes, and livelihoods. While American families have not forgotten the pain of the financial crisis, a kind of collective amnesia appears to be now descending on Washington. Many seem to have forgotten the causes of the crisis and the brutal consequences for American families. Instead of offering hope and opportunity to American families, the legislation being considered by this committee would needlessly expose taxpayers, workers, businesses, and the American economy to fresh risks of financial abuse and financial collapse. That is not a risk we can or should take. While the draft legislation has many serious flaws, I want to focus here on three key problems: first, weakening oversight of the financial system; second, eliminating orderly liquidation; and third, undermining consumer and investor protection. First, weakening oversight of the financial system. The proposed legislation would weaken oversight of the financial system by eliminating the ability of the Federal Reserve to supervise systemically important nonbank financial companies, undermining the Financial Stability Oversight Council, abolishing the Office of Financial Research, and fundamentally weakening oversight of banks. The designation of systemically important nonbank financial institutions is one of the cornerstones of the Dodd-Frank Act, and a key goal of reform was to create a system of supervision that ensured that if an institution posed a sizeable risk to the financial system it would be regulated, supervised, and have capital requirements that reflected its risk, regardless of its corporate form, whether a bank holding company, investment bank, insurance conglomerate, finance company, or whatever. Shadow banking gets a free pass today. The bill would also weaken Fed oversight of the biggest banks. The Fed provides for a graduated, tailored system of enhanced prudential measures that increases in stringency with the size of the firm. None of these enhanced measures apply to about 95 percent of banks, the category commonly described as community banks, those with under $10 billion in assets. Exempt are more than 6,000 banks in communities all across the country. Yet, to benefit huge Wall Street titans the proposed legislation offers up a simple option to be exercised at the discretion of Wall Street firms. A 10 percent leverage ratio gets big firms like Goldman Sachs and Wells Fargo out of heightened supervision by the Fed. That is a big mistake. It lets Wall Street choose whatever approach is the least constraining even if it means bigger risk for the rest of us. That is choice for Wall Street, pain for American families. None of these changes will help hometown banks. Instead, small banks could benefit from safe harbor rules and plain- language versions of regulations that do apply to them, as well as longer exam cycles and streamlined reporting requirements. Second, eliminating orderly liquidation. At the height of the crisis Lehman collapsed in bankruptcy, AIG was bailed out, and President Bush and Congress stepped in to pass the Troubled Asset Relief Program. In response, Dodd-Frank authorized an orderly liquidation authority so that our economy would never again be exposed to those horrible choices. Whatever the merits of bankruptcy reform, the bill would foolishly rely solely on the hope that bankruptcy judges could manage the failure of a firm like Lehman. Orderly liquidation has three essential features not replicable in bankruptcy: first, it is part of an ongoing system of supervision; second, the FDIC can provide liquidity; and third, the FDIC can coordinate globally to deal with the failing financial firms. Bankruptcy just can't match that. Last, undermining consumer and investor protection. Congress created the consumer agency to protect people from harmful and abusive financial practices. In just 6 years the agency secured $12 billion in relief for more than 29 million consumers. Yet, the bill would cripple the agency, needlessly harming American families. In sum, the proposed legislation crushes investor hope, it mocks investor opportunity, and it undermines the transparency, honesty, and trust essential for capital formation. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Mr. Barr can be found on page 93 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Mr. Pollock, you are now recognized for 5 minutes for your testimony. STATEMENT OF ALEX J. POLLOCK, DISTINGUISHED SENIOR FELLOW, THE R STREET INSTITUTE Mr. Pollock. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Ranking Member Waters, and distinguished members of the committee. Of the many provisions in the CHOICE Act, my discussion will focus on three key areas: accountability; capital; and congressional governance of the administrative state. Mr. Barr mentioned community banks. We should hear from them. A good summary of the results of the Dodd-Frank Act is supplied by the Independent Community Bankers who say, ``Community banks need relief from suffocating regulatory mandates. The exponential growth of these mandates affects nearly every aspect of community banking. The very nature of the industry is shifting away from community investment and community-building to paperwork, compliance, and examination.'' Now, that is certainly not what we want, but it is what we have because when Dodd-Frank was enacted the urge to overreact was strong and Dodd-Frank expanded regulatory bureaucracy in every way. This was in spite of the remarkably poor record of the government agencies as they helped inflate the housing bubble--a vivid lesson of crisis so well pointed out by Peter Wallison--and in spite of the obvious fact that the regulatory agencies have no superior knowledge of the financial future, as all of us know, because nobody does. Accountability is a central concept to every part of the government. To whom are financial regulatory agencies accountable? Who is their boss? The answer to both these questions is, of course, the Congress. All of these agencies of the government, populated by unelected employees with their own ideologies, agendas, and ambitions--and the CFPB is the best example of that--must be accountable to the elected representatives of the people who created them, can dissolve them, and have to govern them in the meantime. All must be part of the separation of powers and the system of checks and balances, and this includes the Federal Reserve, as appears in the CHOICE Act. As the president of the New York Federal Reserve Bank testified on the 50th anniversary of the Fed, ``Obviously the Congress which set us up has the authority and should review our actions at any time they want to and in any way they want to.'' And that seems to me entirely correct. Under the CHOICE Act such reviews would happen at least quarterly. The chairman mentioned in his opening statement that people have seen their savings decimated. I would like to suggest that for the Federal Reserve reviews with Congress, the Congress should also require the Fed to produce a savers' impact statement quantifying and discussing the effects of its monetary policies on savers and saving. The most classic and most important power of the legislature is, of course, the power of the purse. The CHOICE Act, accordingly, puts all the financial regulatory agencies under the democratic discipline of congressional appropriations. This notably would end the anti-constitutional direct grab of public funds which was granted to the CFPB and which was designed precisely to evade the democratic power of the purse. I believe the CHOICE Act is an excellent example of the Congress asserting itself at last to clarify that regulatory agencies are derivative bodies accountable to the Congress. They cannot be sovereign fiefdoms--not even the dictatorship of the CFPB and not even the money-printing activities of the Federal Reserve. Turning to banking, the best-known provision of the CHOICE Act is to allow banks the very sensible choice of having substantial equity capital--to be specific, a 10 percent or more tangible leverage capital ratio--in exchange for the reduction in onerous and intrusive regulation. Such regulation becomes less and less justifiable and less and less sensible as capital rises, and more capital for less intrusive regulation is a rational and fundamental tradeoff. It seems to me the 10 percent leverage capital ratio, conservatively calculated, as proposed in the CHOICE Act, is a fair and workable level. As a final comment, the CHOICE Act makes positive changes to the FSOC, but FSOC or anybody's forecasts of the unknown financial future are hard to get right and are unreliable. So higher capital is a better protection than another 10,000 pages of regulations. I hope the committee will promptly advance the CHOICE Act, and thank you for the chance to be here. [The prepared statement of Mr. Pollock can be found on page 137 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Dr. Cook, you are now recognized for your testimony. STATEMENT OF LISA D. COOK, ASSOCIATE PROFESSOR, ECONOMICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS, MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY Ms. Cook. Chairman Hensarling, Ranking Member Waters, and members of the committee, thank you for the opportunity to testify today about the Financial CHOICE Act of 2017. In the winter of 2008, when I was teaching macroeconomics at Michigan State University, I looked out my window one evening and saw a line of students snaking around the corner and down the street from the building across the way. It was not a typical line of boisterous students waiting to purchase something like football tickets. The mood was somber and no one was talking. I approached a colleague to ask what was happening. He said it was a line for the food bank. Students who lost their jobs and funding were going hungry. No wonder the scene was so jarring. It was straight out of Dorothea Lange's iconic photos of the Great Depression. Many of these students had to drop out of MSU to support their families. And this was happening in my lifetime, on my campus, to my students and their families. It was also happening to many students and families across the country. Recall that the recession began in December 2007. This is the time when the auto industry was bleeding jobs. It lost 31 percent of its workforce between 2008 and 2009. In Michigan the number of foreclosures nearly doubled between 2008 and 2009, and that was after having quadrupled between 2005 and 2008. With one in seven jobs tied to the auto industry, the country was more broadly losing more than 700,000 jobs per month. Ultimately, the economy would shrink by 8.9 percent that quarter--the last quarter of 2008. Anyone witnessing this would have said ``never again'' to the job losses, ``never again'' to the disruption in families and communities, and ``never again'' to the irresponsible lending and financial practices accompanying these undesirable outcomes. Among those irresponsible financial practices was that banks were placing bets with public money. If they won, bank profits would soar and bank managers and owners would be paid; if they lost, American taxpayers would pay through deposit insurance or direct government bailouts. The banking system, the banking business model, and their impact on people and the economy all required the examination. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act was one legislative response intended to reassure taxpayers and to signal to regulators and financial institutions that this would never happen again. As a law constraining lending and therefore economic growth, my calculations suggest that this is not the case. If higher capital requirements constrain lending and, therefore, economic growth, we should see a fall in both since the passage of Dodd-Frank in 2010. Instead, we see both increasing. According to the latest data available, commercial and consumer loans grew between 0.5 percent and 12 percent annually since 2012. Household debt at the end of 2016 stood at $12.6 trillion, which is only 0.8 percent shy of its $12.6 trillion peak in the third quarter of 2008. The economy has expanded 0.2 percent and 6.7 percent each quarter since the first quarter of 2011. Does the Federal Reserve require more oversight? No. The kinds of provisions being proposed in the Financial CHOICE Act resemble financial reforms implemented in many of the emerging markets in developing countries I have advised or researched to disastrous effect and would undermine the credibility of the Federal Reserve. This would be okay if we were a small island nation with no financial transactions and no interaction with the outside world. But we are the largest economy with extensive financial ties to the rest of the world, and this would not be appropriate for us. In conclusion, this body should say ``never again'' to the wild, bleak days of unfettered consumer and bank finance. It should say ``never again'' to the losses in houses, firms, communities, hope, and opportunity that the recent financial and economic crisis brought. It should declare ``never again'' by engaging in thoughtful financial reform and rejecting many provisions of the Financial CHOICE Act. [The prepared statement of Dr. Cook can be found on page 109 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Ms. Peirce, you are now recognized for your testimony. STATEMENT OF HESTER PEIRCE, DIRECTOR, FINANCIAL MARKETS WORKING GROUP, AND SENIOR RESEARCH FELLOW, MERCATUS CENTER, GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY Ms. Peirce. Chairman Hensarling, Ranking Member Waters, and members of the committee, thank you for the opportunity to be part of today's hearing. As Dr. Cook's poignant description of the financial crisis illustrates, what the financial system does and how it is regulated really matters for the rest of the economy. And so it makes sense periodically to look at the financial system and look at how it is regulated and take another look to see whether it is working as it should. I think that improvements can be made and the CHOICE Act offers a number of improvements that will make the financial system work better for the rest of the economy. I will talk about some of the improvements today. First of all, good rules require good process. Without good process and without accountability you don't get good rules. The CHOICE Act makes a number of improvements to make sure that rules that are imposed on our economy are done through notice and comment rulemaking. It also takes an important step of requiring that the financial regulators conduct economic analysis. This exercise is designed to ask, ``What problem are we trying to solve,'' to look at different potential solutions to solve those problems, and then to look at the costs and benefits associated with each of those potential solutions; and to build into a rulemaking metrics so that you can go back 5 years later and say, ``Is this working as we intended it to work? Is it achieving the goals that we intended it to achieve?'' And the Financial CHOICE Act also builds on the economic analysis requirement by then requiring that Congress take a look at rules when they are final and consider again whether they want those rules to go into effect. The value of doing this, especially with an economic analysis in hand that might alert Congress to unintended consequences, is huge. This gives an important measure of accountability. Another important measure of accountability is the new requirement that financial regulators be appropriated as other agencies are. It is very important to have this level of accountability. Another important piece of the Financial CHOICE Act is the attempt to shut off avenues for bailouts. One such example is the elimination of Title VIII of Dodd- Frank. Title VIII was the companion to Title VII, which deals with over-the-counter derivatives. Title VII moved a lot of over-the-counter derivatives into central clearinghouses, and as the drafters of Dodd-Frank realized, doing this might just create the next too-big-to-fail entity. And so the solution to that concern was to create the Federal Reserve as backstop for these clearinghouses. That creates terrible incentives. So eliminating the backstop will force regulators and market participants to concentrate on risk management and to also think about the important questions of recovery and resolution. What happens when there is a problem at a clearinghouse? There are some discussions of this issue already, but taking away Title VIII would focus the mind on these discussions further. And then another important part of financial regulation, which the CHOICE Act recognizes, is the need to allow the capital markets to work. We need to allow investors and companies to meet in the capital markets in ways that are mutually beneficial, and the CHOICE Act opens up new avenues for investors and companies to come together. It also addresses another important problem, which is that many companies don't go public anymore, which means that investors can't participate in the growth unless they are accredited. The CHOICE Act makes a change in this by allowing more investors to qualify as accredited, but it also looks at the problem of why companies aren't going public, and it seeks to reduce some of the burdens associated with being public. These burdens are not associated with a benefit to investors, and so the CHOICE Act pulls them back. The bottom line is that regulatory reform needs to work for consumers, investors, and Main Street companies. That is the objective of financial regulatory reform. And I believe the CHOICE Act has many elements that further these objectives. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Ms. Peirce can be found on page 130 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Mr. Allison, you are now recognized for your testimony. STATEMENT OF JOHN A. ALLISON, FORMER PRESIDENT AND CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER, CATO INSTITUTE Mr. Allison. Thank you, and good morning. I appreciate being asked to testify. At the time of the most recent financial crisis I was the longest-serving CEO of a major financial institution in the United States: BB&T. My company went through the financial crisis without a single quarterly loss. I had the unique experience of being in a key decision-making position in a bank during the last three financial crises: the early 1980s; the early 1990s; and the most recent crisis. Unfortunately, in my view government policy unquestionably was the cause of the financial crisis. Two primary components of the government action created the crisis. First was housing policy, which Peter Wallison described well. Second were errors by the Federal Reserve--two categories: one, monetary policy; and two, regulatory policy. In terms of monetary policy, in the early 2000s we were having a minor correction that we needed. Unfortunately, in response, the Federal Reserve created negative real interest rates. You could borrow less than the rate of inflation which was a huge incentive for people to borrow. It created bubbles in housing, but it also created bubbles in the commodities market, in the stock market, and in car finance that led to the failure of the car industry. You can't have all those bubbles without the Federal Reserve making mistakes on monetary policy. On regulatory policy the Fed incented risk-taking. You could have half as much capital for a loan to a subprime lender as you could for Exxon. Nothing could incent risk-taking more than that. In addition, the Federal Reserve and other regulatory agencies did a terrible job handling this crisis in comparison to the other two. They made two meta-mistakes. First, they created a huge amount of ambiguity. In the past they had strategies. This time was totally arbitrary. They saved Bear Stearns, failed Lehman Brothers; they failed Wachovia, they saved Citigroup. When Washington Mutual failed they covered the uninsured depositors and they took it out of the hide of the bond-holders instead of out of the FDIC insurance fund. Markets can't deal with ambiguity. Secondly--and this is huge and under-discussed--how they handled the credit issue was big during this crisis. In the past what they did was cause small banks that were in trouble or big banks that were in trouble to fail. They let the bad banks fail but they let healthy banks like BB&T keep doing their lending. This time they saved the unhealthy banks and forced the healthy banks to stop making loans. It was bizarre. What happened? BB&T was forced to put thousands of borrowers out of business that we would not have put out of business, that would be creating jobs today. But unfortunately, tragically, they have continued with this pattern after the correction. It has particularly been destructive in what I call venture capital small business lending, because they are obsessed with mathematical modeling. In venture capital small business lending, a lender makes a judgment of the individual's character, not just the numbers. That is what I started out doing in the banking business. And fortunately, I helped a number of companies get started that have created hundreds of thousands of jobs. We can't make those kind of loans today. That doesn't start out as a big loan because it doesn't get to a big loan until the company gets big. So these loan growth numbers are very distorted because what is happening--you can study the numbers--is there has been a massive increase in assets going to large companies and the government at the expense of small companies and lower-income and moderate-income consumers. Dodd-Frank has caused consolidation in the industry--it has deprived startups of capital; it has destroyed innovation; it has led to less competition; deterred small business, low- income, and average consumers; and slowed economic growth. For those of you who are concerned about safety and soundness, why would you believe regulators know how much risk we ought to take? They just caused this last crisis. In my career, regulators always overreact. They encourage too much risk in good times, and too little risk in bad times, which is what they are doing today. They don't have any magic wand. Markets do a much better job of risk management. I think it is ironic that the regulators have actually increased systems risk by trying to reduce risk at individual institutions. Some banks should be failing. Businesses are failing all the time. They are forcing everybody to take the same risk, which increases systems risk. Capital is a far better protector of risk. Highly capitalized banks very seldom fail, primarily because it puts some real skin in the game. You know, I had a lot of BB&T stock. I cared how BB&T did. When people put capital in the game, they care. And if you allow institutions to have little capital, like Citigroup basically had no capital when they effectively failed, they are going to take a lot of risk. I think it is ironic that the institution that caused the biggest trouble, the Federal Reserve, has more power out of this crisis. And I also think it is ironic that a lot of people who are concerned about consumers are on the same side as Wall Street banks. Listen, the Wall Street banks love Dodd-Frank because they have achieved regulatory capture. In my career they always capture the regulators, and that is exactly what they have done in this case. Thank you for listening. [The prepared statement of Mr. Allison can be found on page 90 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Thank you, Mr. Allison. And thank you all, members of the panel. The Chair now yields himself-- Mr. Cleaver. Mr. Chairman? Chairman Hensarling. --5 minutes for questions. Mr. Cleaver. Mr. Chairman, a parliamentary-- Chairman Hensarling. Who seeks recognition? For what purpose does the gentleman from Missouri seek recognition? Mr. Cleaver. A parliamentary-- Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman will state his inquiry. Mr. Cleaver. Mr. Chairman, because a lot of people are coming in and out trying to go to other committee hearings, I am just--well, first of all, let me thank you for having the hearing. We have had other major pieces of legislation, that have gone through didn't go through regular order, so I appreciate this. But this is a huge piece of legislation, and I am just hoping that we could have more than just one hearing-- Chairman Hensarling. If the gentleman would state his point of order? Mr. Cleaver. The point of order is-- Chairman Hensarling. Parliamentary inquiry. Mr. Cleaver. Yes. I'm sorry. It was a parliamentary inquiry. And my inquiry is will there be additional hearings due to the significant nature of this legislation and how huge the bill is? We had--I can't remember--40-something, I think, hearings on Dodd-Frank and--41--and I would hope that we could have--we probably don't need 41, but I hope we can have more than just this hearing. Chairman Hensarling. I am not sure the gentleman has stated a proper parliamentary inquiry. Nonetheless, by the chairman's count, over the last 3 Congresses we have now had 145 different hearings on the Dodd-Frank Act and aspects of the CHOICE Act. Having been here during Dodd-Frank, I don't remember a single hearing on the combined Dodd-Frank Act, but I assure the gentleman from Missouri that we expect to have even further hearings in this Congress to monitor all aspects of banking, of financial capital, the Dodd-Frank Act, and the CHOICE Act. So, yielding to-- Ms. Waters. Will the gentleman yield? Will the gentleman-- Chairman Hensarling. For what purpose does the ranking member seek recognition? Ms. Waters. To seek a clarification of whether the gentleman asked about Dodd-Frank or the CHOICE Act. Are you saying you have had 145 hearings on CHOICE? Are you combining the two? What are you referring to? Chairman Hensarling. Again, the gentlelady doesn't pose a parliamentary inquiry. So if the gentlelady wishes to pose a parliamentary inquiry, the Chair will entertain it. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I shall continue with the gentleman's question about whether or not there will be additional hearings based on the complexity of the wrong choice act? Chairman Hensarling. Okay. Well, again, by our count, we have had a 145th hearing on the problems of the Dodd-Frank Act, and I plan to have dozens more hearings on the negative impact of Dodd-Frank on the American people and the economy, and the Minority will certainly be noticed on these hearings. The Chair now yields himself 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Wallison, since the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act, the big banks have become bigger and the small banks have become fewer, as I think you well know. Something I am particularly concerned about is a Federal Reserve report entitled, ``Bailout Barometer,'' which indicates that since the financial crisis and the passage of Dodd-Frank, a whopping 62 percent of total liabilities of the financial system are now backstopped by the Federal taxpayer, either implicitly or explicitly. If I recall right, that is up about a third since the crisis. I am thinking specifically of Title I and Title II, the OLA and SIFI designation process of Dodd-Frank. Has the designation of too-big-fail-to firms made the economy more stable or less stable, in your opinion? Mr. Wallison. In my view, it has made the economy less stable. There are so many reasons why a firm that is declared to be a SIFI is going to cause difficulties for our economy, one of which, of course, is that it gives the impression that the government has declared this firm to be too-big-to-fail, which means that the firm will then be treated by the market as though lending to that firm is without possible adverse consequences, just like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, which were, many of us said for many years, treated as backed by the government even though formally they were not. Because these firms are seen as too-big-to-fail, they will be able to get credit for their activities without having to take the kinds of steps that the market would normally require them to take under market discipline to reduce their risks. So simply designating firms as SIFIs does increase the potential risk in the economy and in the financial system, and that is one of the reasons why I oppose the designation process. There are several others, but that is one. Chairman Hensarling. Dr. Michel, under Title II of Dodd- Frank, the orderly liquidation authority gives the FDIC new broad, sweeping discretionary powers in bailing out financial institutions. It is my understanding that under Dodd-Frank we could look at another AIG-like bailout, where foreign banks could receive 100 cents on the dollar. Is that your understanding, and did you have any concerns on this regarding the orderly liquidation authority? Mr. Michel. That is my understanding. That is a big concern. I think from a broader perspective, if you want to end bailouts you don't formalize a process where the government can say, ``There is no other private alternative so the FDIC is going to handle this.'' And somehow that is supposedly not a government bailout, not government-funding. It just doesn't make any sense if you want to end that process, so I have major concerns with that. Chairman Hensarling. Mr. Allison, you have the most banking experience on this panel. You mentioned earlier that you were speaking of the role that capital really played in financial stability. Basel III sets up a risk-weighted asset regime, versus the simple leverage ratio of the CHOICE Act. In your decades of experience as a banker and living through three different financial panics, can you kind of contrast and compare the two different models? And I believe I have seen FDIC data that indicates that 98 percent of all banks at at least a 10 percent simple leverage ratio survived the second-worst financial crisis in America's history, which I suppose would suggest some level of financial stability. But could you expound on your views here, please? Mr. Allison. Yes, sir. First, I think Basel can be gamed. Before the financial crisis these banks were doing all the risk modeling, the banks that got in trouble, and they gamed the system. And you could easily game the system by how you use the mathematics, what probabilities you put on certain kinds of losses. Second, it is self-defeating because it puts more capital in certain kind of assets, which means banks are getting more of those assets which drives the risk up in the assets. And the classic example is subprime lending. Banks were required to have half as much capital in subprime loans so you had a lot of subprime lending. In Europe no capital was required for loans to Greece so Greece got a lot of money. So when you try to risk-weight the assets you defeat the outcome. For example, up to a few months ago energy lending had less capital and now it has more capital after the fact. The regulators always figure it out after the fact. Chairman Hensarling. My time has expired. The Chair now yields to the ranking member for 5 minutes. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pollock, in his statement, said that the community banks and States need relief from suffocating regulatory mandates. And I am concerned about whether or not Mr. Pollock and others who talk about community banks are as concerned about community banks as they are about the too-big-to-fail banks. Mr. Barr, let me ask you, the wrong choice act 2.0 would eliminate restrictions on mergers, acquisitions, and consolidations of banking organizations that choose the off- ramp to regulation as long as the banking organization maintains a quarterly leverage ratio of at least 10 percent. Would this provision, in addition to the other de- regulatory efforts under the wrong choice act 2.0, potentially allow the largest banks to grow exponentially larger and even more interconnected, which would leave the banking system open to greater vulnerabilities that would trigger another financial crisis? Mr. Barr. Yes. I believe that provision will further increase concentration at the very top of the financial sector. It will permit the very largest firms to grow significantly bigger. It may stifle competition both in the mid-sized market and the smaller market, and I believe it will increase systemic risk. Ms. Waters. So this is not about protecting community banks. This is about allowing the biggest banks in this country to have that kind of off-ramp. Ms. Cook, the wrong choice act 2.0 would provide a so- called off-ramp for banks of all sizes, including the trillion- dollar banks on Wall Street, to opt out of all enhanced prudential standards under Dodd-Frank for stronger capital, liquidity, and risk management, as well as Basel III capital and liquidity requirements if they meet a 10 percent leverage ratio requirement. Because regulators recently noticed that they are working--regulators have already said that they are working on simplifying capital requirements for community banks. Is it appropriate to roll back these important rules for Wall Street at this time? What are we doing here? Ms. Cook. I didn't quite hear the end of your question but I think I got the gist of it. Certainly giving the supervisors and the regulatory authorities less power, having them collect less data, I think would be detrimental to our financial system not just in the United States but to avert the next global financial crisis. Again, I was saying that the provisions of the CHOICE Act would be appropriate if we were a small island nation that didn't interact financially with other nations, but for the largest financial system for the largest economy in the world this would be inappropriate. Ms. Waters. Mr. Barr, getting back again to this discussion about community banks, we hear a lot about wanting to protect community banks, wanting to get rid of the regulations that are causing them so much pain. But we find they are doing quite well. Their profits are up, et cetera, et cetera, et cetera. Would it be reasonable to conclude that this is really about the big banks in America and providing them the opportunity to not have the oversight and regulation that we have put together in Dodd-Frank reform that would avoid another recession, almost depression, that we went through? Mr. Barr. Yes, I completely agree with that. I think if the issue were a focus on community banks we would be debating in front of us a bill on community banking. But that is not the bill we are debating. We are debating a bill that takes on really all the post- financial crisis reforms, that weakens oversight of the biggest banks, it weakens oversight of the shadow banking system, it makes it much more difficult for consumers to get their day in court, it blocks consumer protection that helps families across the country. So this is not a community banking bill that we are discussing today. Ms. Waters. And does this open up the door for more acquisitions and reduces the big banking community to instead of five or six banks maybe three in this country? Mr. Barr. I wouldn't want to guess about the exact structure, but it certainly eases restrictions at the very largest firms to engage in merger and acquisition activity irrespective of concerns about financial stability. And the other measures that are undertaken in the bill suggest significantly less oversight of those firms with respect to stress testing and the process for resolution planning. So I do think that the very largest firms are going to benefit a great deal under this legislation. Ms. Waters. You were around when we went through the meltdown in 2008 and you know how scary it was. And we did not know what to do. We ended up with this bailout. Should we go through that again? Do we have to go through that again with-- Mr. Barr. Mr. Chairman, I see I am out of time. May I respond? Chairman Hensarling. Quickly. Mr. Barr. I don't think we can afford to go through that kind of crisis again, and the orderly liquidation authority and the prudential measures put in place were designed to prevent the kind of problems of bailouts in the future. I think it would be a mistake to repeal them. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentlelady yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New Mexico, Mr. Pearce, chairman of our Terrorism and Illicit Finance Subcommittee, for 5 minutes. Mr. Pearce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thanks to each one of you for your presentations today. Mr. Allison, you appeared to be in the eye of the hurricane while the hurricane was going on. I am going to refer a question. There are two different narratives that always pop up when we are in these kinds of hearings. One is well-stated by Mr. Wallison, where he describes in his text that the enactment in 1992 of the Affordable Housing Goals caused the underwriting that Fannie and Freddie were compelled to take those on. If that underwriting had not been available then the implication is that banks would have stayed in their lane, but since they could get rid of the loans then the system just got out of control. The other narrative is that the big banks were somehow evil and then without any support at all just went out and did these things on their own. You were in the eye of the hurricane. Can you give a perspective on how this actually developed--a brief perspective, please? Mr. Allison. Yes, sir. There is no question that government policy caused it. Freddie and Fannie were the giant providers of credit in the marketplace; they dominated the market because they had government implicit guarantees so they had the lowest cost of capital. BB&T had been a mortgage portfolio lender requiring a 20 percent downpayment. We were driven out of that business, as were most other banks. The regulators wanted banks, they wanted Wall Street, to do subprime lending. But a lot of people who blame the banks were the people who actually forced banks to do subprime lending because we didn't want to do that, most of us, because we were lending other people's monies and banks really shouldn't be doing subprime lending. Mr. Pearce. And then the big banks, seeing the opening, said in order to get more of these loans in this area we will give bonuses. But if the banks could not have gotten rid of those loans then how many of the big banks would have had incentives for--where they were going to eat the loan if they couldn't resell them to a government-backed enterprise? Mr. Allison. They wouldn't have. Mr. Pearce. Yes. Okay. Thank you. I appreciate it. Mr. Wallison, you say that Fannie and Freddie were--you hint that they were compelled. Were they actually compelled through legislation, or pressure, or how, that Fannie and Freddie changed their underwriting standards? How did that compulsion look and feel? Was it legislation? Mr. Wallison. The Affordable Housing Goals was legislation. The Department of Housing and Urban Development was given authority to raise the goals. The original goals were 30 percent of all mortgages they bought in, in any year, had to be made to people who were at or below median income where they lived. HUD raised those goals to 56 percent. Now, you can say Fannie and Freddie could have ignored that, but they couldn't. These regulations from HUD were binding on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, so they had to find those mortgages. Mr. Pearce. Okay, so-- Mr. Wallison. You can't find prime mortgages if more than half of all mortgages you are allowed to buy are made to people who are below median income. Mr. Pearce. Okay, so of the two narratives, that the evil institutions caused it and greed caused it, versus the government regulators and congressional law, that is clear. Now, we also hear, Mr. Allison, that the community banks have exceptions. There are exceptions to the rule. Mr. Barr said that in his testimony. Why don't those exceptions work out? Because my bankers, the community bankers in rural New Mexico with 4,000 and 5,000 people in a town, are livid about Dodd-Frank and livid about the CFPB. Why aren't those exceptions in place? I know they are written into the law, but how does that work out? Mr. Allison. Community bankers are adamantly opposed to Dodd-Frank, and I know many of them, and the reason is it is nice to say the regulators can make an exception, but if you are a regulator and you make an exception and your bank gets in trouble, you will get blamed. So in fact, most of the Dodd- Frank provisions are hurting community banks. And you can raise the level and all that, but the community banks are not going to really be exempt because the regulators are just human beings. They don't want to get in trouble if their bank gets in trouble, so they go and apply basically the same rules to community banks they provide to big banks. Mr. Pearce. One of the witnesses, and I forget which one, talked about having firefighters put out fires, and it made me think about the forest in New Mexico. The Forest Service regulating the forest began to quit cutting trees. They stopped cutting trees about 60 years ago or whenever. And so typically trees in New Mexico are about 50 trees per acre; now we have 5,000 stems per acre, and the fires break out and they are catastrophic fires, and so the Forest Service now says we need more firefighting money. What we needed is to stop letting the trees grow to start with. And so it looks like a very close parallel to what should have been done here. I yield back, Mr. Chairman. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Mrs. Maloney, ranking member of our Capital Markets Subcommittee. Mrs. Maloney. Thank you. I think it is important that we remember why we passed Dodd-Frank in the first place. We did it because our country experienced the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression: 8 million people lost their jobs; 6 million people lost their homes. The crisis destroyed over $5 trillion in wealth for the middle class--their savings, their pensions, they just evaporated. And overall, over $13 trillion in household wealth in this country was lost. But with better regulation and with the tools that we put in place in Dodd-Frank, we can prevent this type of devastating financial crisis from happening again. So it is important not to go backwards, which the wrong choice act does. So my first question is to Professor Barr. One of the main ways this bill, in my opinion, goes backwards is by repealing Dodd-Frank's orderly liquidation authority. I find this provision deeply, deeply, deeply troubling. The creation of the resolution authority for large nonbank financial companies like AIG and Lehman was one of the most bipartisan ideas in Dodd-Frank. In fact, it was originally proposed by the Republican-appointed Treasury Secretary, Hank Paulson, and it was supported by the Republican-appointed Fed Chair, Ben Bernanke, and the Republican-appointed FDIC Chair, Sheila Bair. It is important to remember that the FDIC has long had the authority to resolve commercial banks outside of the bankruptcy process. And all Dodd-Frank did was give the FDIC the authority to do the same thing for large nonbank financial institutions. This was very important because when many of the big nonbank financial institutions were on the verge of collapse, we had only two choices: chaotic, disorderly bankruptcy, like Lehman, which went under; or a bailout, like AIG. Neither was a good choice. Dodd-Frank gave the regulators a third option: an orderly wind-down that prevents a government bailout but does not harm the overall broader markets. But now the Majority has somehow convinced themselves that this longstanding FDIC authority is some type of evil new taxpayer bailout. In their minds, allowing the FDIC to take away a failing financial firm, fire the management, wipe out the firm's shareholders, impose losses on the firm's creditors, and completely liquidate the firm, that, in the Majority's mind, somehow constitutes a bailout. So my question is, Professor Barr, is the orderly liquidation authority in any way, shape, or form a bailout? Mr. Barr. No, it is not. The orderly liquidation authority actually is the opposite. It provides a realistic chance of winding down a firm or a set of firms in a financial crisis to avoid the kind of bailouts and also chaos we had in the fall of 2008. And so if you look overall at the legislation we are considering now, the Financial CHOICE Act, in my judgment, would move toward bailouts, move us away from the system of orderly liquidation that was put in place in Dodd-Frank. I think that is quite dangerous both for taxpayers and to the financial system. Mrs. Maloney. I agree. So I want to ask you again, what would happen if the Majority is successful in erasing the orderly liquidation authority? Mr. Barr. I think that it would make it more likely that in the next financial crisis Congress and the President would be faced with the same horrible choices they faced in 2008, and I think it will mean that we will see more bailouts and more chaos in financial markets. So it will be the worst of both worlds. We are going to get more taxpayer bailouts and more harm to the economy, and that is why I think it would be a serious mistake to repeal orderly liquidation. Mrs. Maloney. And the living wills. If the orderly liquidation authority is repealed, making a traditional bankruptcy the only option for a failing financial institution like AIG and Lehman, would that make living wills more important--would it make them more important or less important? Mr. Barr. I think it would make it even more important to have a very robust resolution planning process with living wills, with simplification of holding company structures, and with the other sets of supervision undertaken. Mrs. Maloney. So why in the world would the Majority want to make bankruptcy the only option? Chairman Hensarling. Brief answer. Mr. Barr. I believe that it would be a serious mistake to rely only on the bankruptcy courts. I think it should be an option, but not the sole option for dealing with a failing firm. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Luetkemeyer, chairman of our Financial Institutions Subcommittee. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I ask unanimous consent to enter into the record statements from the Electronic Payments Coalition and the Independent Community Bankers of America, and I have a statement, as well. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mr. Luetkemeyer. And it is kind of interesting that the Community Bankers--they represent 6,000 community banks-- support the CHOICE Act, which, if Professor Barr is really interested in the big banks going through and supporting something, they do not support the CHOICE Act, and I haven't spoken to a single one that supports this. And you wonder why they would want to give up their implicit guarantee from the Federal Government. So I don't know where that statement came from, but it defies the facts. With that, Mr. Allison, you have testified with regards to the capital ratio here a couple of times already this morning, and I want to just follow up with regards to something that Mr. Barr said again. He said that the CHOICE Act offers a simple option to be exercised at the discretion of Wall Street firms at a 10 percent leverage ratio, that it takes big firms like Goldman Sachs and Wells Fargo, out of the heightened supervision of the Fed. If you actually look at what happens if they get to that point, you are looking at $430 billion that is added to the capital structure of these big banks. Do you think that is a giveaway to Wall Street? Mr. Allison. I do not. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Do you think that this improved capital leverage ratio would be detrimental to financial stability and economic growth? Mr. Allison. I think it would substantially reduce financial risk far more than more regulations, and I think it would be good for growth because banks would be more rational when allocating capital to the most productive ends because they would be lending more of their own money. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you. Mr. Pollock, you also mentioned some things with regards to this. It would seem to me that it would--any time you put the private sector dollars on--or at risk versus the taxpayers' dollars at risk, that would seem to me to be a preferential situation than what the capital leverage ratio, this 10 percent ratio, actually does because suddenly if the owners of the institution have their own money at risk they are going to be a little bit more, I would think, discretionary about how they run that institution, versus if they know that the taxpayers are going to bail them out regardless of what decision they make it would, I would think, enhance risky behavior. Can you comment on that? Mr. Pollock. Congressman, I completely agree. I talked about that as accountability, putting up more capital. There is also the issue, as Mr. Allison said, of ``skin in the game'' in your own business, being actually at risk in the business you do. There are provisions in the act which give relief to the small lenders who actually operate on a skin-in-the-game basis in their mortgage lending, which I think is a very good idea. Mr. Luetkemeyer. I know that Mr. Allison also made a comment with regards to the community banks and regulations, and on your testimony you also made that comment that it would be very beneficial to help them be able to survive. I assume that is what you think? Mr. Pollock. I think that without question, intrusive and extensive regulation falls disproportionately heavily on smaller organizations. That is true every place, but it is also true with banking. The bigger banks can create bureaucracies to face off against the government bureaucracies; the smaller banks are strangled by that same bureaucracy, and that is in their own words, as you point out, Congressman. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Mr. Michel, one of the things that Dodd- Frank did was give the authority of the unfair, deceptive, and abusive acts and practices situation to--authority, anyway--to the CFPB. The key word there is ``abusive.'' Has anybody ever defined what ``abusive'' is? Has the CFPB ever defined what ``abusive'' is? Mr. Michel. No. And Director Cordray has actually said that it would be a bad idea for them to define abusive practices and said that we should just look at these things on a case-by-case basis. So we know that they are not unfair, we know that they are not undeceptive, but they are something else and we will figure that out as it happens. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Wow. That is like putting police in charge and then saying, ``Well, they can decide what is a crime and what is not a crime.'' Is that basically a good analogy? Mr. Michel. Yes. That is hardly the rule of law, yes. Mr. Luetkemeyer. I know we have a bill to do just that very same thing. And in this CHOICE Act is something to basically do that, as well. Mr. Wallison, before I go away here, you make a couple of comments with regards to the slow economy and part of it being done as a result of Dodd-Frank. Former Fed Chair Alan Greenspan last week made the comment that if we did away with Dodd-Frank it would spur the economy. Would you like to just--a quick 10- second comment on that? Mr. Wallison. I didn't hear his comment, but I would say that the problem is that Dodd-Frank has caused such a decline in the number of small banks that it is very hard for small businesses that rely on small banks to get the kind of financing that would keep our economy going. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Okay. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman. Mr. Sherman. Mr. Chairman, I reiterate my plea that we vote on these bills separately so that members of this committee have a choice. There are 12 bills that the CHOICE Act has swallowed up that have the support of half or more of the Democrats and half or more of the Republicans of this committee, and we ought to be moving those bills separately. Of particular importance are the Preserving Access to Manufactured Housing Act and the Mortgage Choice Act. These bills will pass this committee overwhelmingly if we bring them up separately. We are told that it is the government's fault, overregulation. But you cannot say that overregulation caused the panic of 1814, the panic of 1819, the panic of 1837, the panic of 1839, the panic of 1857, the panic of 1861, the panic of 1873, the one of 1893, or October 2000--rather 1907. And overregulation did not cause the Great Depression, nor did it cause the 2008 Great Recession. We are told that Fannie and Freddie were making loans that the private sector, at least those not subject to HUD regulations, would never make. But it was the credit rating agencies that gave AA and AAA ratings to Alt-A loans that Freddie and Fannie wouldn't touch, and to loans that did not meet Fannie and Freddie's standards. And, Mr. Chairman, your bill eliminates the last vestiges of already unenforced Franken-Sherman to regulate the credit rating agencies. As long as they have a high rating to bad bonds, whether they are mortgage or otherwise, portfolio managers almost have to buy them. How does a portfolio manager say, ``Well, the guy across the street is getting a 7 percent return on AA-rated bonds but I prefer a 6 percent return because I don't trust the credit rating agencies?'' How am I supposed to invest in Vanguard if T. Rowe Price is giving me half a percent more and their bond portfolio is AA-rated, just as the Vanguard one is? The problem we have, the problem that this committee has not fixed, is that the credit rating agency is the only game where the umpire is elected and paid by one of the teams, namely the issuer of the bonds. As long as that happens, you can blame Fannie and Freddie for bonds they never touched that got AA rated, that portfolio managers on pain of being fired had to buy to match other portfolio managers, and we didn't do anything about it. Mr. Barr, this discussion of a 10 percent capital rate, meaning basically no regulation--do you think it makes sense to allow a business model in which you get a lot of capital or money through FDIC-insured deposits and you are free, as long as you have 10 percent capital, to buy Zimbabwe bonds, high- risk bonds, super high-yield bonds? Would we be opening things up to a business model of 10 percent capital and extreme high- risk debt instruments? Mr. Barr. I do think it is a mistake to rely on only one form of capital rule. There is not any perfect capital rule. The 10 percent leverage requirement has a positive attribute for firms where it raises their equity position, but it has lots of downsides as a sole tool, and one of those downsides is that without a measure of the riskiness of assets you are incentivizing the firm both to move items off the balance sheet and also to engage in riskier lending activity, and I think both of those are a problem. And it would also remove the full set of heightened supervision that is enhancing the safety of the firms. Mr. Sherman. All right. Thank you. And I want to focus on this issue of bailouts. I opposed the first five drafts of Dodd-Frank because they provided permanent unlimited bailout authority. We got rid of those provisions. We do have orderly workout authority. But, Mr. Chairman, we will have another bailout if we have another 2008 as long as there is an institution big enough to call the White House and say, ``We are going down and we are taking the whole economy with us.'' You know. You were there. You opposed it. I opposed it. But this Congress will pass a bailout bill under those circumstances. The way to deal with this is the Sanders-Sherman approach: Break up every institution that is over 2 percent of GDP. Otherwise it is just bandaids, trying to pretend we won't have a bailout when we allow too-big-to-fail to exist. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Huizenga, chairman of our Capital Markets Subcommittee. Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I would like to start by asking unanimous consent to enter into the record a letter of support from Duff and Phelps, one of the leading firms in mergers and acquisitions and valuations, specifically on Section 822. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mr. Huizenga. Thank you. And I want to get to Ms. Peirce here on couple of things. I was intrigued as you were talking about sort of the Title VII and Title VIII, but we may need to revisit that at another time. What I liked is you used a phrase, I think, where we need to have people meet in the marketplace, is I think the phrase that you used, or something like that. And what we have seen is, I believe, less access to the financial opportunities that are out there that have occurred. And on March 22nd the Capital Markets Subcommittee held a hearing where we had a witness testify that 2016 was one of the slowest IPO years since 2008, and I am curious if you could comment on that. Ms. Peirce. Sure. I think it is a big problem that companies--it is understandable that companies are waiting longer to go public. It is very expensive to be public and so many are choosing not to. And when you become public you subject yourself to litigation risk, and many worry about that. I think efforts that will lower the cost of being a public company while still ensuring that investors are protected are very important. There are a number of these included in the bill-- Mr. Huizenga. Wait a minute. Do you think we can do both? Ms. Peirce. I think it is possible to do both, and I think-- Mr. Huizenga. Because if you listen to the rhetoric from the other side it is one or the other. Ms. Peirce. And I think that is what has led us to the place we are in, which is we think of protecting investors in a very specific way, which is just making sure that investors never get harmed. But we never think about the opportunities that we shut them out from participating in. So as a company is growing we want to let investors be part of that growth. Mr. Huizenga. And we are not talking necessarily accredited investors. What happens after an IPO is our retirement funds, us as individuals, no matter what your income or net worth is, are able to go in and take advantage of an opportunity. Isn't that right? Ms. Peirce. Yes. That is why we really need to preserve--it is fine for companies to raise money privately, but we really need to preserve and protect our public markets, as well. Mr. Huizenga. I am concerned that we are not doing that. We have half the number of public companies that we did 20 years ago, and we have only slightly more public companies than we did in 1982 right now. And we have a number of folks who have given testimony in front of this committee at different times about income disparity, and I wholeheartedly agree that that is a problem. Having a less-than-robust--that may be the polite D.C. way of putting it--economy out there I believe is part of that, and it was not long ago, less than a month ago, that I asked Chair Yellen about the effects and influences on regulation, on our recovery and how shallow it has been, how long it has been, how weak it has been. She literally--look it up on YouTube-- stammered and hemmed and hawed for about 3 or 4 seconds and then said she disagreed with that. We saw just this week former Chairman Greenspan came out and precisely hit the nail on the head by saying we have gone and had this over-regulatory burden, and I see Dr. Cook's reaction is not exactly in favor of that. But this sort of this rosy outlook of where the economy is can't be a straight-faced analysis if you look at the income disparity. And it only seems that when it is in defense of the past Administration that you have people talking about what a great economy we have going on. In my last minute here I have the Securities and Exchange Commission I believe is the police officer, the cop on the beat that is out there making sure that investors are protected. What we have them doing now under Dodd-Frank and under other so many provisions, though, is we frankly have them being road maintenance. They are filling in the potholes and checking the streetlights when we have them going out and doing things like figuring out rules for CEO pay ratio, rules for having conflict minerals. Can you explain to me how in the world that is advantageous to protecting an investor when we are out there doing that, when the SEC is required to protect investors; maintain orderly, fair, and efficient markets; and facilitate capital formation? Ms. Peirce. Yes. I think with any requirement that you place on public companies it not only places a requirement on public companies but, as you point out, it requires the SEC to engage in areas in which it doesn't have particular expertise in, is very difficult. The pay ratio rule is one example of a rule that is very difficult to implement in a way that will be meaningful for investors. Mr. Huizenga. And, Mr. Chairman, I think that shows it just pulls their focus away from what they really need to be concentrating on. With that, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New York, Mr. Meeks. Mr. Meeks. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And first I want to associate myself with some remarks from the gentlewoman from New York, Carolyn Maloney, because I think what she said was exactly right. Often, people forget where we have come from and what took place in 2007 and 2008, the number of jobs that were lost, how people were devastated, and why that--and that it was, in fact, a Republican Administration that then, on a transition, worked with a Democratic Administration to try to help fix this problem, which is why we came up with Dodd-Frank as opposed to doing nothing at all, so that we can make sure that we protect our system. In fact, if we are serious about doing this, that is a matter in and of itself because that showed a Republican Administration during a transition making recommendations to a Democratic Administration also on how we can resolve some issues to make sure that we don't get in this--in the worst recession and get out of the worst recession since the Great Depression. And when we talk about the--in the Obama Administration the economy, as my colleague just talked about, the reason why we did talk about it is because we talked about where we have come from. You just don't change things overnight, and it took hard work to make sure that we got out of losing 700,000 jobs a month to the place where we were at least gaining jobs again, gaining 200,000 to 300,000 jobs a month. Surely all of us would like it if the past Administration would have said, ``We want to gain more jobs,'' and we would need to do that over time. But yes, I would be rejoicing also as I did as we started beginning to reverse the depths of the recession that we were in. Now, the other issue that I want to bring up quickly in the time that I have left, Mr. Barr, is this world is interconnected like never before. And I believe in your testimony you talked about how the United States led internationally in regards to Dodd-Frank so that we could make sure that we have some uniformity, et cetera, and therefore there were some agreements internationally. So my question to you is, can you tell us whether or not the wrong choice act would cause the U.S. to go back on its word on international agreements and how that will affect us, if you will? Mr. Barr. You are absolutely right. The U.S. really led the effort globally for financial reform really from the start-- beginning in the end of the Bush Administration and continuing into the Obama Administration, shaped a global financial structure that made sense for reducing risk in the system. And I do believe that moving backwards, as the CHOICE Act would do, on orderly liquidation, on designation of nonbank firms in particular, would be a retreat from the global system that has developed in the wake of the crisis to deal with this problem. Mr. Meeks. Let me just ask you this because we have folks who are looking at this and screaming, et cetera: Just break that down for me. Break it down in layman's terms so that the average person who is listening--so if we get out of these international agreements, what kind of impact would that have on the average American citizen? That is who I am focused on, what kind of impact would that have on them? Can you, so that they could understand what you are talking about? Mr. Barr. I think it exposes families to enormous risk of financial abuse in the marketplace. It exposes them to the risk and harm of another financial crisis that was, as Dr. Cook suggested, so brutal for American families in terms of lost incomes, lost jobs, even the ability to have enough food to eat. So if you get these things wrong it can have a brutal impact on how people try and live their daily lives every day. Mr. Meeks. Let me go to Dr. Cook quickly because on that same part, Dr. Cook, knowing that you have reviewed the CHOICE Act, what parts of the CHOICE Act--and I know there are a lot that you can choose from, et cetera, but maybe there are one or two in the time that I have left that you might be able to single out--what parts of the CHOICE Act will go directly to the heart of hurting the average American citizen, the middle- class and the low-income households? What do you think will most be going directly to them? Because that is who I am focused on. I don't care what party you are from, the middle class of America, the low-income who needs the most help. How would this hurt them? Ms. Cook. I think all of the provisions that weaken the CFPB and weaken the authority of the Federal Reserve to monitor and have oversight and make sure that we don't have the Wild West that we had before the financial crisis, I think this is the most onerous part. We aren't even collecting the information or not allowing--these provisions wouldn't allow collecting the information we need critically to input into our models or even know, understand what is happening in the economy. We need this information in a timely way, and I think anything that undermines that authority is not a good thing. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Wisconsin, Mr. Duffy, chairman of our Housing and Insurance Subcommittee. Mr. Duffy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think this has been a fascinating debate today and I appreciate the witnesses being here. But it is the conversation that I am hearing some on the Democrat side say, ``Well, Dodd- Frank is looking out for the little guy, and the previous system we used to have was to the benefit of the big guy.'' And maybe to quote Mr. Barr, he said the CHOICE Act now is going to help the Wall Street titans. I don't know if the panel can see this, but to your left and to your right there are quotes that come up--and behind you are quotes that come up--from Wall Street CEOs. Articles have been written about the CHOICE Act and Dodd-Frank. And I think it is interesting that the Wall Street titans, Mr. Barr, are in opposition to the CHOICE Act and they are in support of Dodd-Frank. And if I was also to talk to my community bankers, my little credit unions that serve rural Wisconsin, that like to have money from their community go to bankers in their community to then make decisions that benefit their community--those shops, those banks, those credit unions, they are closing up or they are consolidating and the decisions aren't made in that community anymore but they are made in Chicago, or Minneapolis, or Milwaukee, or Green Bay, but no longer in that community. So I would look at Dodd-Frank and think: The big titans, the big guys, they like it. The little guys, they are getting crushed by Dodd-Frank, which is the exact opposite of what my friends say was supposed to happen. I would also argue the Democrats, my friends, say that the bigger the bank, the riskier it is to the economy, the more systemic the risk. Does anybody have an opinion whether big banks have gotten bigger since Dodd-Frank or smaller during Dodd-Frank? Mr. Wallison, do you have an opinion on that? Mr. Wallison. Well, the numbers speak for themselves. Yes, the big banks are much bigger-- Mr. Duffy. Have gotten bigger. Mr. Wallison. Much bigger, of course. Mr. Duffy. Because they are more--do sometimes complex rules and regulations help big guys, the big titans, and hurt the little guys? Is that a philosophy that you believe in? Mr. Wallison. Jamie Dimon, who is the chairman of JPMorgan Chase, the biggest bank in the United States, called regulation a moat, and he is correct about that, because it keeps competition from challenging his bank. Mr. Duffy. So Dodd-Frank protects him? Mr. Wallison. It weakens the smaller institutions. Mr. Duffy. Are you saying that Dodd-Frank actually protects them from competition? Mr. Wallison. Yes, it protects them from competition. Mr. Duffy. Helping the big titans on Wall Street. Mr. Wallison. Yes. It is easy to see, Congressman, because they have all kinds of lawyers and compliance officials and so forth to handle-- Mr. Duffy. Economies of scale. Mr. Wallison. --regulation and spread it over a $2 trillion bank, and the small banks do not, so they are harmed by Dodd- Frank. Mr. Duffy. I think one of the most interesting factors when you look at the breakdown of where does the--where do the big titans believe Mr. Barr on Dodd-Frank versus reform in the CHOICE Act there is--look at the Presidential election. Where did big banks and Wall Street give their money? Did they give it to Hillary Clinton, who supported Dodd-Frank, or did they give it to Donald Trump, who wanted to do away with Dodd-Frank? They voted with their money, and they gave most of their money, Mr. Wallison, to whom? Do you know? Mr. Wallison. I think the statistics show that they gave most of it their money by far to Hillary Clinton. Mr. Duffy. To Hillary Clinton, yes. So this argument that Dodd-Frank helps the little guy and hurts the big guy is absolutely false. It is a great narrative, but it doesn't work. You would think that when you have a financial crisis you might actually wait for the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, which I think you served on, Mr. Wallison, to come out with its report before you decide, what do we do to fix what caused the crisis, because we now know and now we are going to legislate. Dodd-Frank passed before the commission even came out with its report. So now the opposition to the CHOICE Act is astonishing to me. I just want to--Mr. Wallison, I keep asking you questions here, but was it your testimony that government policy created the crisis in housing finance? Mr. Wallison. That is exactly right, and it is almost incontrovertible because if you look at the data you can see very clearly that as the Department of Housing and Urban Development required Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to buy more and more mortgages that were subprime mortgages, that spread to the entire housing finance system. This weakened the system substantially, and when the housing bubble--created by these low underwriting standards--collapsed, we had the financial crisis. Mr. Duffy. One more quick question: So if government policy helped created the crisis, is it fair to say that Dodd-Frank doubled down on more government policy? Yes or no? Mr. Wallison. That is what we are seeing. Mr. Duffy. Absolutely. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Ms. Velazquez. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Barr, I agree with you. There seems to be a case of policymaking amnesia going around this room. I was here in 2008 as our Nation stood on the edge of financial calamity and ruin. Try telling the victims of the Wells Fargo account scandal that we need less financial oversight, not more. Try telling hardworking families who were preyed upon with deceptive mortgages or cascading overdraft fees that this bill is the right choice for them. My position is that this legislation before us is the wrong choice for consumers, for small businesses, and our entire community. Mr. Barr, I am deeply concerned about the impact the CHOICE Act will have on consumers in my district. According to a report from the New York City Comptroller, since 2011 the CFPB has helped more than 23,000 New Yorkers. For example, in October 2016 a Brooklyn resident filed a complaint against Navient with the CFPB regarding student loan repayment. Because of the Bureau, Navient was compelled to respond and the individual was granted relief. Further, using its enforcement authority, the CFPB sued Navient partially on the basis of complaints just like this to seek relief for other impacted borrowers. If the CHOICE Act is enacted it will make it harder for the CFPB to work with a company to help resolve a specific issue and severely restrict its ability to take enforcement actions on a person's behalf. So, Mr. Barr, how will consumers like the one I just mentioned continue to be protected in situations like this? Mr. Barr. I think that the CHOICE Act would bring us back to a situation that we had before the financial crisis where there were insufficient ways to protect American families. In fact, in many ways it would make it worse than what we had before. I think the act would cripple the new Consumer Bureau and there wouldn't really be anybody standing up for American families on issues like the Wells Fargo scandal, or payday lending, or other abuses in the marketplace. So I think it would be quite a tragedy to see that happen. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you. Mr. Barr, the CHOICE Act repeals the Department of Labor's fiduciary duty rule and makes it extremely difficult for the SEC to ever move forward with its own conflict-of-interest rule. Can you explain how these changes will continue to put Americans at the mercy of unscrupulous financial advisors? Mr. Barr. I think that if you are offering investment advice you ought to have the same high standard of care of fiduciary duty, where if you are offering individual investment advice to a consumer the consumer can rely on the fact that you are looking out solely for their best interest. That is what the fiduciary duty rule would do, and repealing it would be a horrible mistake. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you. Dr. Cook, the CHOICE Act repeals the Volcker Rule, Dodd- Frank's ban on speculative trading and certain investments in hedge funds and private equity funds at banking entities with access to the Federal safety net. Doesn't this repeal expose taxpayers to losses associated with banks' proprietary trading, which amplifies the costs associated with the crisis? Ms. Cook. That is exactly right. And as I was saying earlier, with respect to the guarantee that is given any bank, especially if it has depositors, if it is playing with public money then certainly it gets all of the upside and doesn't feel the pain on the downside. So certainly this repeal, I think, would not be appropriate for American consumers. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you. Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentlelady yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Missouri, Mrs. Wagner, chairwoman of our Oversight and Investigations Subcommittee. Mrs. Wagner. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you all for appearing here today to discuss the merits of the CHOICE Act and the ways that it will help bring accountability to Washington while opening up the economy for Main Street back home. Something that I specifically want to discuss is the level that the U.S. has outsourced its decision-making and regulation-setting to the international level since the financial crisis. Mr. Pollock, you reference in your written testimony a September 2014 letter from Mark Carney, Chairman of the FSB, to then-Treasury Secretary Lew regarding whether Berkshire Hathaway should be designated as systemically important. Now, I understand that letter has been made classified by Treasury, but I agree with you, sir, that your statement that the letter should be made available to Congress as well as documents about any possible agreements and decisions made at the FSB level. Mr. Pollock, going forward should Congress demand the same level of disclosures and transparency regarding these decisions made at FSB as we would in the case of other international economic and trade negotiations in which the U.S. engages? Mr. Pollock. Congresswoman, I think that is a very important provision in the CHOICE Act, just as you say, and that the issue of whether American government agencies like the Fed and the Treasury make deals in international settings, which they then feel compelled to follow when they get back into the American process, is a very important issue. We don't want the International Financial Stability Board telling the United States what to do, in my opinion. So I fully support the transparency and reporting required in the CHOICE Act of the financial regulators, and of course that includes the Fed and the Treasury. Mrs. Wagner. Besides the CHOICE Act and the provisions that we have regarding that kind of transparency and accountability, what can Congress do to prevent further outsourcing of U.S. regulatory priorities in international bodies do you think? Mr. Pollock. Congresswoman, I think in general the accountability of regulatory bodies called for in the CHOICE Act, where Congress carries out its duty as the elected representatives of the people to oversee what the bureaucratic agencies are doing, fits in with understanding what may be going on internationally and guiding it. Mrs. Wagner. Thank you very much. I couldn't agree more. It is important that the best interests of the U.S. are being represented at the international level with full accountability, full transparency, and disclosure. Moving on, last week the President signed an Executive Order halting the FSOC's ability to designate nonbank SIFIs while they review the designation process. Through the Oversight and Investigations Subcommittee, which I Chair, we have published a staff report and held a hearing that has shown this process has been both arbitrary and inconsistent in the past. Mr. Pollock, could you please comment on the prudence of last week's Executive Order? Mr. Pollock. Congresswoman, I remember the hearing very well, which you chaired, and at which I had the honor to speak. I think what the staff study found is quite true, that the FSOC's decisions were inconsistent, arbitrary, and capricious, as the judge said. And it is because the decisions are fundamentally political, judgmental decisions that they shouldn't be delegated to a committee. FSOC is not even a committee of agencies--although it would be under the CHOICE Act--but a committee of individuals who happen to head agencies. So I think what the Executive Order said, and what the CHOICE Act would provide here, and what your hearing showed, are all correct. Mrs. Wagner. Political and judgmental. Sir, should FSOC even have authority to designate these firms? And how does the CHOICE Act help curtail this power that seems to enshrine this status of too-big-to-fail for certain firms? Mr. Pollock. Congresswoman, I concur with the idea they should not have such authority and that we would be better off moving in the direction of the CHOICE Act where they would not have it. Mrs. Wagner. Mr. Wallison, should FSOC have this designation authority for nonbank SIFIs? Mr. Wallison. Certainly not. FSOC should not have that authority. It has abused that authority so far and it will continue to do so if it is left with that authority. Unfortunately, they have been implementing in the United States decisions of the Financial Stability Board in Europe. Mrs. Wagner. Absolutely correct. Thank you very much for your testimony. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Clay, ranking member of our Financial Institutions Subcommittee. Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for conducting this hearing. Let me thank all of the witnesses for being here. We have heard a lot of bank-and-forth from my friends on the other side as well as from the witnesses here, but let me see if I can inject some of the facts before we move forward. And I have a letter here from the CEO of an American bank, a community bank, who said that, ``The lending and credit markets are on a hot streak. Credit card lending is higher than it has been in 6 years and just hit a record high of $996 billion at the end of last year. ``Auto loans peaked at over $1 trillion in the fourth quarter of 2016, up from $634 million in the same quarter of 2010. Mortgage rates fell to 3.65 percent by the end of 2016, down from 4.69 percent in 2010. ``The recession caused by 2008's financial collapse tore apart these industries, left millions of Americans out of work, and obliterated any and all trust in the country's largest financial institutions. We are finally seeing true recovery and growth again under the watchful eye of careful regulatory oversight and in the wake of years of careful policymaking designed to encourage recovery while preventing the country from ever experiencing a crisis of that scale again. ``Yet, even as we watch this progress continue, some Federal lawmakers insist that regulations formed in the wake of the crisis are holding markets back--claims which fly in the face of reality. These lawmakers are demanding a rollback of the Dodd-Frank Reform Act despite the protections it offers to both consumers and our national economy. ``The opponents of oversight and regulation insist the red tape of Dodd-Frank's reforms are driving up mortgage and credit costs for consumers even though the costs are consistently hitting record lows. ``An American Banker piece published recently used the figures above to dispel these falsehoods about the lending industry, proving Dodd-Frank is not holding back opportunities for consumers. In reality, interest rates on mortgages are at a long-term low point; mortgages are being given more freely than at any point since the crisis. Auto lending is already well above pre-recession levels, and auto loan rates are lower than they were in 2010.'' And then he goes on to say, ``It is difficult to argue with the point that scrapping Dodd-Frank would make it easier for banks to issue credit and loans. However, the protections offered under this law are the only thing standing between consumers and the predatory lending practices which fomented the greatest economic crisis in 70 years. ``Dodd-Frank helps prevent any small handful of banking institutions from holding the keys to the country's economy by limiting investments by banks and forcing accountability to Federal regulators. We are preventing the rebirth of too-big- to-fail institutions.'' And this is from the CEO of Amalgamated Bank, which I would like to submit and have it included in the record. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mr. Clay. Thank you. Mr. Barr, do you agree with the writer of this letter? Mr. Barr. I don't know all the details in the letter itself, but in the biggest-picture sense, yes. I think the lending markets are quite healthy in the United States today, and one of the reasons for that, in comparison to, say, Europe, is that we took swift action in the wake of the crisis to reform and build capital. And I think all of our panelists are saying that more capital is good. We have differences beyond that. Mr. Clay. Thank you so much for your-- Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Kentucky, Mr. Barr, chairman of our Monetary Policy and Trade Subcommittee. Mr. Barr of Kentucky. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thanks to all our witnesses for your testimony. I would note that a number of our witnesses are either lawyers or law professors, and I want to ask you a little bit about Article 1 powers in the Constitution as it applies to the Dodd-Frank law. As you all well know, Article 1 Section 1 of the Constitution provides that all legislative power shall be vested in the Congress, and we know in law school that they teach us in constitutional law that is known as the non- delegation doctrine, which has been interpreted creatively by the judiciary to allow for delegation to unelected, unaccountable Executive Branch officials over time. That practice has exploded under the Dodd-Frank law. And in fact, most law is now written by unelected bureaucrats, as opposed to elected representatives of the people here in Congress. My question to Mr. Pollock and Mr. Wallison: Does the massive delegation of authority to Federal bureaucrats concern you? Mr. Wallison. I will go first. Yes, quite a bit, actually. Take, for example, what the FSOC is supposed to do. The FSOC is supposed to determine whether a particular company at some time in the future, in a time unknown--that could not possibly be known--could, if it collapsed or had material financial distress, cause a financial crisis. In other words, they are being asked to make a decision about something that no one can possibly know. So of course they struggled with all of this, and when they finally designated MetLife, MetLife went to court and the judge--a district judge here in the city--looked at it and said, ``This is not possible. This is arbitrary and capricious.'' That is the kind of decision that the Dodd-Frank Act has given to the Executive Branch--and that, to me, is a delegation of legislative authority. Congress should have made those decisions. Mr. Barr of Kentucky. And, Mr. Pollock, in answering that question, why is it important that key policy judgments be made by those who define legal rules and not by those who enforce the rules? Mr. Pollock. It is the most fundamental constitutional idea, as you suggested in your comments, Congressman, that it is the elected representatives of the people who make law. As I said in my testimony, the regulatory agencies are derivative bodies--derived from the Congress, responsible to the Congress. I am delighted to see the CHOICE Act having the Congress step up to carry out its governance responsibility of these agencies. Mr. Barr of Kentucky. Ms. Peirce, I appreciate your testimony that good rules require good process. And in reference to the structure of the CFPB under Dodd-Frank, and in reference to the D.C. Circuit decision in PHH, can you tell us a little bit about why the structure of the Bureau and insulating that Bureau from political accountability, why that is a bad idea and how that may produce anti-consumer policies? And in answering that question could you respond to the refrain we hear from the apologists of Dodd-Frank, the defenders of Dodd-Frank, that, ``Oh, we need to insulate the Bureau and the Director from political accountability; it needs to be an independent agency.'' Ms. Peirce. Yes. The notion that independent of accountability will produce better regulation is false. The PHH case is actually a great example because the underlying facts of that case are fairly stark, so even if you take away the constitutional concerns and look at what was actually done in the case, changing the law midstream, essentially, and applying a retrospective penalty that increased dramatically when it got to the Director's level shows the kind of due process concerns that you can have. So the idea that one man is going to be able to make consumer decisions for all the consumers in the country is troubling, especially when that person doesn't experience the circumstances that a lot of people experience and doesn't have the limited options that people have. And so from his perspective he may not understand that constraining the options even further is making life even more difficult for people. Mr. Barr of Kentucky. Let me ask the question this way: Is the public interest--is the interest of the consumers best served by the people's representatives or by those who are fundamentally unaccountable to the people? Ms. Peirce. I think that is what you need to have. You need to have appropriations and you need to have other powers so that Congress can monitor what the agency is doing and bring in the public interest. Mr. Barr of Kentucky. Thank you for your testimony. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Georgia, Mr. Scott. Mr. Scott. Thank you very much. Mr. Chairman, I was an original cosponsor of Dodd-Frank, and I remember that we had exactly 41 hearings before the House passed its version of Dodd-Frank. But today it seems to me, unless I can be corrected, we have only a single hearing on this issue, and I assume this is it. I happen to believe that the American people deserve much better than this. This CHOICE Act goes underneath all of the elements of our complex, complicated financial system, and to give it only one day, one hearing, is not fair to the American people. It doesn't take a historian to remember the amount of jobs we lost. Sometimes we lost as much as 600, 700 jobs a month. Retirement savings of American citizens, millions went down the drain. And the amount of foreclosures was devastating. And the thing that disturbs me is that this should be a very definitive Republican and Democratic partnership working together. And let me remind the committee and the people of this Nation who might be listening, every major piece of public policy that has been sent forth has had both Democrats and Republicans working on it together. Social Security started way back, but we had people working on it together. Even our highway system, the interstate highway system, by a Republican President, Dwight David Eisenhower, but they were Democrats and Republicans working together. I could go on to cite even the Civil Rights Act. It was Democrats and Republicans. And need I say, if it weren't for Everett Dirksen we would never have been able to pass some of this legislation. So I just wanted to set the stage on that because I don't think there has been any Democrat on this side of the aisle who has reached over to that side of the aisle and worked together. And I want to appeal to the chairman that before we move this bill out, to have some additional hearings, and I think the American people certainly deserve that. But I do have some very, very pressing concerns. One is the capital requirements, Title I under this act, to bring about this area of accountability and to simply base it upon certain data that has been collected that might not be the case--the off-ramp, audits deemed the Fed, which would handcuff the Fed. So in my last minute, Dr. Cook and Mr. Barr, you all touched upon this. Am I right about what I am saying? Dr. Cook, and then Mr. Barr? Ms. Cook. You are absolutely right about what you are saying. There is a lot of forgetfulness about the effort that went into fighting this financial crisis. And I am not sure I understand from the conversation. There is a lot of disparagement of economists and expertise and people who have been working on these tools for a long time. I guess I am the only macroeconomist here. Maybe I feel under siege. We work very hard. These people who are being described as bureaucrats who are undemocratically making these decisions, they are just Ph.D. economists who want to do a good job, who think about the spirit of public service. So I think that they would be interested in making sure that the system was safe and sound and stayed that way. Mr. Scott. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Posey, for 5 minutes. Mr. Posey. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Wallison, an important yet perhaps overlooked provision of the CHOICE Act would limit donations made pursuant to settlement agreements to which certain departments or agencies are a party. Section 393 of the Financial CHOICE Act would prohibit Federal financial regulators from using settlement proceeds to make payments to third parties who are not harmed by the wrongdoing that led to the settlement. That seems like a no-brainer, and I think the vast majority of American people believe that when the government enters into these settlement agreements, those funds are reserved solely to compensate the actual victims. But as we learned from the previous Administration, that is not always the case. Over $3 billion--``billion'' with a ``B''--in settlements has been pilfered from victims and sent to special interest groups since 2014. For example, the National Council of La Raza, the controversial left-wing advocacy group, received $1 million in grants under a mortgage lending settlement despite not being harmed by the activity in question. Community development groups and other political allies of the previous Administration have also benefitted from these settlements, receiving de facto Federal funding without the approval of Congress. Because enforcement agencies cannot unilaterally disperse settlement proceeds to third parties, they have instead directed the banks to donate funds to various groups as terms of their settlement agreements. And even worse, the previous Administration actually incentivized companies to donate to unharmed third-party groups by doubling the credit such donations would have toward paying down their settlement obligations. In these situations the consumers, the victims of the alleged wrongdoing, end up losing because funds would have otherwise gone to them. Mr. Wallison, beyond the moral and ethical questions of this practice, can you discuss the constitutionality of these settlement slush funds and whether or not this practice violates, at least in principle or spirit, the appropriations power reserved for Congress and, therefore, the separation of powers? And finally, do you believe this provision in the CHOICE Act is an appropriate step toward correcting this problem? Mr. Wallison. Yes, Congressman, I do. I think this is something that this committee should be quite concerned about. There was an investigation by The Wall Street Journal last year--a very thorough investigation--to find out what happened to over $100 billion in settlements that the government had made with the large financial institutions, and they found that $45 billion of that went to the victims but they could not determine and did not determine how it went to the victims, because I suspect that there weren't lawyers from the Justice Department standing on street corners taking applications. I suspect that what happened is that most of this money went to people who said they represented the victims and would make sure that the victims were suitably reimbursed. I think this is a serious problem because that money should have belonged to the American people and should have been appropriated by Congress. And I am quite unhappy with the way that whole process was looked at by the previous Administration. Mr. Posey. Yes. I know I tried to get copies of some consent decrees to try and follow the money and the Justice Department refused to provide me the information. To this day I am still unable to get it. I am glad The Wall Street Journal at least could get some of it. Dr. Michel, in keeping with the important check that the power of the purse provides Congress, the CHOICE Act would subject the CFPB to regular appropriations. As you know, currently the CFPB requisitions money from the Federal Reserve to fund its operations. Congress cannot review or direct how the CFPB uses that money. What inherent problems are there with allowing an agency to avoid Congress' power of the purse? And conversely, what are the benefits of ensuring agencies must justify their spending to the people's representatives in Congress during the appropriations process? Mr. Michel. I think it is important to know that any and all Federal agencies should be directly accountable to the people through their elected representatives. So any process that keeps them--or that puts anything in between that and that slows that process down or makes that process more difficult is bad. The FTC is a good example historically of an agency that was reined in by Congress through the appropriation process when they were doing what they were not supposed to be doing, and I could envision how that could happen again with something like the CFPB, were it the case that those protections were in place. And it is very important. It is the only mechanism that the people have. Mr. Posey. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Massachusetts, Mr. Lynch. Mr. Lynch. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman, and to the ranking member, as well. And thank you, to our witnesses, for your willingness to help the committee with its work. I have to admit, I am very concerned with this bill that we are discussing today. I have to say that the Financial CHOICE Act of 2017 is probably the worst bill that I have seen in my time in Congress. And I am not new. But it is a compendium of just bad, bad ideas. It is actually breathtaking in the naked purpose of this bill, to benefit the big banks in this country at the expense of the American taxpayer. I have to give you credit, Mr. Chairman and my colleagues on the other side of the aisle. I have never seen so many bad ideas jammed into one bill. This is really an accomplishment. I am not sure you should be proud of it, but the bill is what it is. This essentially repeals Wall Street reform, okay? And I was here when the market went in the toilet, and I am familiar with the reasons why it did so. I am a Democrat who voted against the bailout because there were folks in my district who didn't even have a bank account and we had to give the people who caused the problem billions and billions of dollars at their expense. And now we are going to go back and do the same thing again. And we are just about out of the--there are some towns in my district that haven't yet climbed out of the last recession and we are paving the way to the next one. It is just a very, very bad idea. So this bill repeals the Volcker Rule, which stops banks from gambling with taxpayer money and depositors' money. It repeals the orderly liquidation authority, which was a mechanism that we adopted to prevent future bailouts and which would allow any mega financial company to fail in a way that didn't damage the wider economy. Mr. Barr, I appreciate you being here and your thoughtfulness, as well as Dr. Cook. Mr. Barr, as you know, Section 901 of this legislation repeals the Volcker Rule. And there is a study that was authored by the International Monetary Fund which disclosed that 73 banks identified currently as systemically important by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision account for nearly two-thirds of global assets, according to this study. These institutions pose management challenges and are very, very difficult to regulate, supervise, and resolve in an orderly manner in the event of a failure. And I ask you, what would the repeal of the Volcker Rule do to the ability of regulators to manage the risks in the financial system due to the proprietary trading, and sponsoring hedge funds, and other risky activities? What would that do? Mr. Barr. I think it would make it much harder to manage those firms, harder to supervise them, and harder to resolve them if they got into trouble. So I think these kind of structural barriers that slow down the transmission of risk from one institution to the other can be effective as long as you are sure to regulate the shadow banking system and not say, ``Well, as long as it is going on over there we don't care about it.'' So if you have a system that really regulates both banks and shadow banks, I think those kinds of structural separations can be quite useful, including the Volcker Rule. Mr. Lynch. Thank you. Dr. Cook, do you have any thoughts on that? Ms. Cook. No more than what my colleague has said. Mr. Lynch. Okay. The same people who tried to kill the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau want to put the funding necessary for that agency subject to the appropriations process. So they have already tried to kill it; now they want the ability to defund it. Any idea what the ramifications of that might be if that were to come to pass, as this bill suggests, Mr. Barr? Mr. Barr. I think it would be a mistake to put the CFPB under appropriations. I think the system we have for the OCC and the Fed and the FDIC insulating it from the appropriations process is appropriate, and I think the CFPB should be treated the same. Mr. Lynch. Dr. Cook, do you have any feelings on that? Ms. Cook. I just agree. Mr. Lynch. Okay. Very good. All right. I have 20 seconds left. I just want to say what a horrible bill this actually is. It is amazing. I hope that people are paying attention in their home and they understand what is going on in this committee. It affects every home and business in America today, and you should pay attention to this stuff. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Royce, chairman of the House Foreign Affairs Committee. Mr. Royce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Allison and Dr. Michel, I just want to follow up on the questioning from my colleague, Mr. Duffy. And my primary concern, I will just explain here, has to do with the regulatory weight that we have placed on community banks, on smaller financial institutions, on the credit unions, and so forth. And simply due to economies of scale we have put them at a significant disadvantage so that the smaller the institution, the larger the disadvantage, which is a backwards equation. And I think any of us who have talked to our local community banks understand this. And my question for you is, what is the real-life impact thereby on a borrower seeking a loan? We were all onboard, of course, with increased underwriting standards, no more low-doc or no-doc loans. But it seems that we have moved closer to what we would all consider a utility model here. We are not letting bankers be bankers. We have moved to sort of a utility model that puts increased regulatory burden on local banks and credit unions--they are not the ones that created the crisis--while at the same time taking away the one advantage that they had over their competition because they knew their own customers. So if they were going to be allowed to be bankers they could work out the loans. Not when you have this kind of regulatory environment. So let me ask that question: How does the current regulatory environment created by the current version of Dodd- Frank affect constituents in Southern California who are seeking a loan? Mr. Allison. There is no question that it makes it more difficult for banks to do their traditional what I call small business venture capital lending, which was the core of their business. That is where they--you look at the financial information, but you judge an individual, the market, and the idea. The Federal Reserve has put intense pressure on mathematical modeling, which a lot of these loans don't make it, and a lot of loans that I made that have turned out very successful wouldn't have happened. In addition to the direct cost, I grew up in a small bank and the CEO has to do a lot of this regulatory stuff himself. And the CEO provides a disproportionate amount of the intellectual talent in a small bank, and if he or she is spending her time--their time doing regulation instead of out in the community looking for opportunities to make the community grow then you have a really serious misallocation of resources, and you see that in a lot of small communities today. Mr. Royce. Or if you have performing assets. Mr. Allison. Yes. Mr. Royce. And the regulatory approach here says, ``Write them off.'' Mr. Allison. Definitely. And it hurts the growth in those communities. I think it is a big problem for small communities. Mr. Royce. There is another aspect to this that I have worried a lot about, and that is because of the economies of scale they are going to be ripe for being bought by the larger financial institutions. Wouldn't that over time--and I think this was Mr. Waller's argument some years ago; I heard him lay out this case that if we are worried about over-leverage, why would we create a situation where the burden on the smaller institutions is such that they are going to be bought out by larger institutions who then will be in a position without the competition to further over-leverage? And that is the kind of over-leverage we were really worried about in the first place. Let me ask you about that. Mr. Allison. Yes, sir. I think that definitely happens. And one of the ironies, we have made it so hard for banks to start because ultimately what has been happening in the community banking industry is some community banks are getting-- Mr. Royce. So that is why we are not seeing any new banks or credit unions. Mr. Allison. They can't get started. Mr. Royce. Yes, yes. Well, a quick follow up. My colleague, Mr. Williams, has introduced a bill that would encourage greater use of CFPB 1022 exemption authority. Do you believe that Director Cordray has correctly interpreted the Bureau's authority and used it appropriately to prevent over-burdening small community banks, smaller credit unions? Mr. Allison. No. In theory community banks are supposed to be exempt, but in practice they are not, and that is just the way regulators act. They are not going to exempt community organizations. Mr. Royce. I was going to ask Ms. Peirce, I was hoping you could also put to rest the idea that the AIG was a failure only of Federal regulation of the financial products unit. You have researched the role AIG securities lending program and the failure of State regulation on this front had, and maybe you could opine on that for just a second? Ms. Peirce. Yes. AIG was about much more than just derivatives, which people like to portray it as. There was a failure of the State insurance regulators, as well. And so the solution in Dodd-Frank was not appropriately tailored for the actual problem at AIG. Mr. Royce. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The gentleman from Minnesota, Mr. Ellison, is recognized for 5 minutes. Mr. Ellison. All right. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you, to the ranking member. Mr. Wallison, I have a question to you. On your role as a member of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission you continually claimed that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were responsible for the financial crisis. My question to you is--I would like to ask you about a July 13, 2011, report published by the Committee on Oversight and Government Reform. The report was entitled, ``An Examination of Attacks Against the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,'' and I ask unanimous consent to submit the report for the record. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mr. Ellison. On page 11 of the report it says that you used your position on the commission to promote a theory supported by Representative Issa and put forth by Edward Pinto, a resident fellow at the American Enterprise Institute, that was ultimately rejected as flawed by every other member of the commission--namely, that government housing policy was the primary cause of the government's economic crisis. The report also notes that your fellow Republican commissioners thought you were really just a ``parrot for Pinto.'' I guess my question is, you are offering your testimony here so that, I guess it could be believed, but how do you react to your fellow members of the commission making the observations that they made about your work? Mr. Wallison. I don't want to really refer to my work, but I can refer to the commission and I think my work will stand up over time. You can also look at my book on the subject, ``Hidden in Plain Sight''-- Mr. Ellison. Okay. Thank you for your answer. Mr. Wallison. --which-- Mr. Ellison. I think that is-- Mr. Wallison. Wait a minute. Wait a minute. I do think-- Mr. Ellison. No, it is my time, and you have sufficiently answered. Thank you. Mr. Wallison. Am I not entitled to answer what you just-- Mr. Ellison. You have answered. Chairman Hensarling. The time belongs to the gentleman from Minnesota. Mr. Ellison. Thank you. Also, Mr. Wallison, was your compensation at the time you served on the commission or after your service tied in any way to you magnifying the beliefs of Mr. Pinto? Mr. Wallison. No. Mr. Ellison. Okay. Also, did you receive a warning from the General Counsel that you violated the confidentiality requirements to serve on the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission? Mr. Wallison. I received a statement by the members of the commission that I had not observed the confidentiality requirements of the commission at one point. Mr. Ellison. Okay. And how do you respond to the observation that you had confidentiality expectations that you didn't meet? Mr. Wallison. I don't think they were applicable to me. Mr. Ellison. Okay. Dr. Cook, could you talk about the--there has been a lot of discussion around the role that Fannie and Freddie played in the financial crisis of 2008. And as I look at the CHOICE Act-- or the wrong choice act--I couldn't find anything that addresses Fannie and Freddie directly. Did you see anything? Ms. Cook. I have seen something. Bostic and coauthors, in I think it was 2012, had a paper--an extensive paper, so this is Raphael Bostic, who is now the president of the Atlanta Fed, but a colleague from the University of Southern California, who looked into this in depth to see what the role was, and it didn't--it said that it didn't have an outsized role in forcing this financial crisis. So I think that I would agree with what you are intimating by your question. Mr. Ellison. Okay. But in the bill that is before us--and I would encourage Mr. Barr to offer his views--I was looking through the bill. I try to read all the bills. I didn't see any provisions directly bearing on Fannie and Freddie. If it is such an enormous problem and it caused so much damage, you would think that it would focus on--the CHOICE Act--the wrong choice act would focus on it, and yet I did not see where the CHOICE Act addresses fixing the problems of Fannie and Freddie. Mr. Barr, would you like to comment on this? Mr. Barr. I am not aware of any provision of the act that takes on the question about the future of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. There are-- Mr. Ellison. Well, wait a minute. Mr. Barr. --things around the edges. Mr. Ellison. It is a huge problem and it caused all the catastrophe. Shouldn't they be the central focus of this legislation? Mr. Barr. I was surprised that it was not a central part of any approach here. Mr. Ellison. That is all the time I have and I want to thank the entire panel, including you, Mr. Wallison. Thank you very much. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Hultgren. Mr. Hultgren. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I just want to say thank you for all of your work, Mr. Chairman, in getting us to this point. And I want to thank everyone on the panel for being here, as well. Before I get into my questions, Mr. Wallison, I wanted to see if you wanted a minute to respond to anything from the previous question. I wanted to offer that first, if there is anything that you want to respond; you weren't given much of a chance to answer. Mr. Wallison. I wasn't. Unfortunately, the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission was a poorly run operation and all of us, the members, did not see all the data that the staff of the commission had. We did not get a copy of the report until--the final report, until 9 days before it was supposed to be published. After the commission ended I was able to go back and look at some of the files that they had, and I found that much of the material they had in their files and the material that they ignored supported the position I had been taking all along, which was that the financial crisis was caused by government housing policy. I have since written a paper that is available on the AEI website, and anyone could have a look at that to see how the commission distorted the facts in order to achieve something that they wanted the--they wanted Congress to follow up. Mr. Hultgren. Thanks. I do want to direct my first question to Ms. Peirce, if I may. I understand there is some consternation regarding Section 844 of the CHOICE Act. I would like to use this opportunity to clear up some of those concerns. One purpose of this provision is to update the resubmission thresholds and holding requirements for shareholder proposals to prevent only those proposals with very little or no support from continuing as a nuisance every year after they have already been denied by the vast majority of other shareholders. For example, I can't believe investors need for Boeing to adopt health care reform proposals, for Mondelez to report on gender equality through the entire supply chain, for McDonald's to educate the American public on the benefits of genetically modified products, or for Archer Daniels Midland to adopt and implement a comprehensive sustainable palm oil policy. These social objectives, for which I agree there could be some merit in addressing, have nothing to do with investor protection or capital formation. The resubmission thresholds in the CHOICE Act I think are reasonable. They were actually proposed by SEC staff in 1997 under the leadership of a Democratic appointee, Arthur Levitt. The Association for Corporate Secretaries testified in the Capital Markets Subcommittee last year that, ``The so-called failure rate under the 3-6-10 threshold of 1997 would compare to current voting patterns under 5, 15, 25 percent.'' So all of that, am I missing something here? Is there--the purpose of our securities law is for job creators to constantly respond to proposals with almost no support? Shouldn't the SEC be focused on capital formation and real investor protection, not social issues? And furthermore, from an investor protection standpoint, if people feel very strongly about these social issues don't they have the choice to invest in other companies that they feel are addressing these concerns? Ms. Peirce. Yes. Shareholder proposals have become a big consumer of resources, both of SEC staff and of company resources. And ultimately shareholders pay the cost, and so putting in--revisiting the resubmission thresholds is one way to make sure that investors are not paying for companies to respond to these each year. Mr. Hultgren. Ms. Peirce, on page two of your written testimony regarding administrative procedure you highlight some of the reforms the CHOICE Act proposes for the SEC. In general, can you discuss the importance of the rule of law for accountability in the investigation and enforcement process of this agency? Furthermore, wouldn't it be logical to also make identical reforms to the CFTC? Ms. Peirce. Yes. I think due process is not only valuable for the target of an enforcement proceeding, but also for our country as a whole to know that when an agency pursues an individual for a violation that it is following all the proper procedures and affording all the proper protections. And so I think that some of the changes that the CHOICE Act makes do this and could be extended to other agencies, as well. Mr. Hultgren. Mr. Wallison, there has been some concern about the lack of clarity between proprietary trading and permitted activities such as market-making and hedging. How do you draw the distinction between proprietary trading and market-making and hedging, and what are the consequences of not having the clear distinction between the banned proprietary trading and permissible market-making? Have any of the regulators addressed these concerns? Mr. Wallison. The problem is that you cannot draw a line effectively between proprietary trading and market-making. That caused many years of dispute among the regulators who were supposed to draft the appropriate regulation. They finally put one out, but it still hasn't solved that problem. The two look very much alike when you consider what they are. And as a result, banks, in an excess of caution, have stopped doing what they should do to make markets. Mr. Hultgren. My time has expired. I yield back. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Maryland, Mr. Delaney, for 5 minutes. Mr. Delaney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My questions are for Mr. Wallison, but before I start I want to comment on Mr. Allison's testimony, which I thought was very thoughtful. I have long thought that in the rating of banks the ``C'' in CAMELS and the ``M'' in CAMELS should be way over-weighted relative to the other categories because capital does solve many problems. I am not sure I agree with your conclusions. I don't think the reason we have had such tepid economic growth is because of banking regulations. Recognizing, however, that we should be doing things to provide relief to community banks, and parts of FSOC I think are overreaching, and there are clear things we should be doing to this regulation to get more at the spirit of what you laid out in your comments. But I thought they were very thoughtful. And, Mr. Wallison, I think my question to you kind of ties into my colleague from Minnesota's question, which is the reason we are not fixing Dodd-Frank, which is what in my judgment we should be doing, any time we do a transformative piece of legislation, whether it be health care or financial regulation, the Congress should sign up for 10 years of fixes, right, because we shouldn't presume we got it right on the day we drop the bill, and we haven't been able to do that with Dodd-Frank. And I think the CHOICE Act is also a step backwards in that direction. I would much rather this committee be focused on fixes to Dodd-Frank as opposed to repealing it. But the repeal seems to be based on two premises: first, that Dodd-Frank has caused us to have reduced economic growth since it was put in inception. I don't buy that argument. I think U.S. banks have generally done pretty well. They have gained market share relative to their foreign competitors; liquidity in U.S. markets is quite strong. However, small community banks have clearly been, in my opinion, hurt by the law and they are not providing credit at the levels they could in the market. But if you look at the percentage of the market small community banks have, and even if you were to assume they were to be providing 50 percent more credit, it wouldn't move the needle that much, in my judgment. But the other premise is that somehow the government caused the financial crisis and, therefore, if that is true then the government shouldn't be responding to it. And that is where I have issues with your testimony because you seem to believe that the reason the financial crisis occurred was because of the U.S. Government. And you said that in your testimony. And so my question to you is, 19 of the 20 largest financial institutions that existed in the United States right before the financial crisis either failed or required a massive injection of government capital--19 of 20. It is hard to trace what actually caused the financial crisis, but it is clear that one thing was a main contributor to it, and that is that the market--the private market, whether it be the credit rating agencies, risk managers in private financial institutions--and the government, whether they be regulators or these quasi- government institutions, Fannie and Freddie, had a view that mortgage securities were as safe as U.S. Treasuries because they were treated almost interchangeably on the balance sheets of these financial institutions, which caused excess leverage in the system. How is that the fault of the U.S. Government? Mr. Wallison. This is a very complicated question, but-- Mr. Delaney. No, it is a simple question: How did the government somehow kind of put the private market in a trance that mortgage securities were as safe as U.S. Treasuries? How is the government responsible? Because clearly the market thought that because they leveraged them accordingly, they repackaged them accordingly, and they treated them accordingly. How was that the government's fault? Mr. Wallison. The underwriting standards of Fannie and Freddie were forced down by the Affordable Housing Goals. When you reduce underwriting standards you cause a bubble to start growing. Let me give you an example of that. Mr. Delaney. So you think the private market doesn't have any responsibility for determining whether underwriting standards have been reduced and whether, in fact, mortgages are riskier? You think that is the government's problem? Mr. Wallison. Fannie and Freddie set the underwriting standards for the housing finance market because they were by far the largest buyers of mortgages. So if you wanted to compete in that market you had to make the kinds of mortgages that Fannie and Freddie wanted. That is why the underwriting standards of the entire market declined. Mr. Delaney. So it is the government's fault that market participants engaged in irrational business practices for competitive gains? Mr. Wallison. It wasn't irrational because Fannie and Freddie were buying these mortgages. They were happy to buy them. And you could profit from making these mortgages and selling them to Fannie and Freddie and also FHA-- Mr. Delaney. But a lot of mortgages were bought by things other than Fannie and Freddie. They were bought by securitized instruments. Mr. Wallison. Yes, that is-- Mr. Delaney. At the peak of the financial crisis 18,000 securitizations had received a AAA rating. Only eight corporations in the world had a AAA rating. So it took the history of the world and all the corporations in the world and eight of them made it to a AAA, yet 18,000 mortgage securitizations had a AAA rating. Mr. Wallison. Well, now you are talking about the rating agencies. That is a whole other story. But the fact is that the--they used a model-- Mr. Delaney. But you are assuming the government made the rating agencies misunderstand-- Ms. Waters. Mr. Chairman, unanimous consent for the gentleman to have 1 more minute? Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Ross. Mr. Ross. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank you very much for holding this important hearing. I firmly believe that we must enact many of the important reforms contained in the CHOICE Act. We need to unlock financial growth and opportunity once again in this country. I support the provisions of this bill that increase accountability of both Washington and Wall Street. For example, I support repealing the Department of Labor's flawed and misguided fiduciary rule. I support the provisions of this bill that would help financial institutions, especially smaller institutions that have had too many burdens placed on them over the years. I support the provisions that require the restructuring and accountability of the CFPB. Yet, there is a provision of this bill that I must express my concerns about, and that is the provision that would repeal debit reform. I have heard directly from a broad spectrum of the retail community in my district, and even from my manager at Publix Supermarket in my hometown where I shop, about the need to maintain debit reform. Just last night I had the opportunity to sit down with an old friend, Wogie Badcock, III, who is the executive vice president of public affairs for Badcock Home Furniture and More. Wogie is in the room today and he is here because of the importance of this debit reform to his family furniture business, which was started in 1904 by his grandfather. The savings that they have realized from debit reform has allowed them to hire more employees, open more new stores and distribution centers, and even pass along some of the savings to consumers, benefiting consumers. In fact, since the enactment of debit reform Badcock Home Furnishing and More has used those savings to open up more than 30 stores in the last 5 years across the Southeast. This is significant. With that in mind, Mr. Chairman, I would like to take a moment to enter the attached letters from the Food Marketing Institute, the National Retail Federation, the Merchants Payments Coalition, and a joint trade letter into the record that represents 170 national, State, and local trade associations and 900-- Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mr. Ross. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I now would like to move on. For you, Mr. Wallison, I find it really interesting that here we have on FSOC one member--a voting member who has insurance expertise and yet is ignored, is so much ignored that we create this idea that somehow or another in the nonbank financial institutions, such as an insurance company, that they are going to be the subject of a run on an insurance company that is going to lead to the demise. Would you not agree, then, that we should allow for the best system that we have, which is our State system of regulation, to continue to be that which not only protects our consumers but also allows for solvency and capital requirements to make sure the best products are available for our consumers and not have FSOC being that faux umpire? Mr. Wallison. The State system of insurance regulation has been very successful over time. I don't see any reason we would have to change that. Mr. Ross. I agree. Well, go ahead. Mr. Wallison. As I said earlier, I think the FSOC was simply implementing the decisions of the Financial Stability Board in Europe, which declared AIG, Prudential, and MetLife to be GSIIs. Mr. Ross. Yes. Mr. Wallison. As a result, they simply put those into effect-- Mr. Ross. They just rubber-stamped them. Mr. Wallison. They were rubber-stamping what the FSB was-- Mr. Ross. Yes. And we know what the courts have said. And that is good, and I think that is what is very good about this bill is it does away with that. But let me get back to something that my colleague from Maryland, Mr. Delaney, was just talking about, and that is rating agencies. When we look at too-big-to-fail, when we look at organizations that are so large that they are going to be subject to bailouts from the government, would not a rating agency consider that in terms of them giving them their rating, so much so that they would consider it to the detriment of one that was too small and allowed to fail, that the bigger one, the too-big-to-fail, would have an unfair competitive advantage? Mr. Wallison. Yes. That is exactly what happened with Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac-- Mr. Ross. Exactly. Mr. Wallison. --which were not supposed to be. Mr. Ross. --mortgage-backed securities and they knew they were backed by the Federal--full faith in the credit of the Federal Government, so why not give them a AAA rating? Why not give them what they want because the Federal Government stands behind it? And if that doesn't create a disincentive for a strong economy, I don't know what does. It creates the moral hazard that we are here today trying to correct with the CHOICE Act. Mr. Wallison. You are completely right. Mr. Ross. Thank you. You should tell my wife that sometime. [laughter] Mr. Allison, you mentioned earlier in your testimony--and I appreciate your experience in the banking industry, I really do, because I think you did something that was tremendous with regard to the financial meltdown: You withstood it. You withstood it strongly. You didn't have any damage because you did it right. You had capital requirements. You knew what to do. But you also mention in your testimony that the regulatory burden imposed by the Dodd-Frank Act has a negative impact on lower-income Americans. Can you expand on this in 10 seconds? Mr. Allison. To the degree that consumer banks are focused on regulations instead of taking care of their customers--or big banks are focused on regulations instead of their customers--the customers get worse service and pay higher prices. At the end of the day, all cost gets passed to the customer. Mr. Ross. Thank you. My time is up. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green. Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Friends, if you like kickbacks you will love the CHOICE Act because it will allow hardworking Americans to go into a lending institution to acquire a loan and receive an indication that he or she has qualified for a loan at 8 percent when they actually qualified for a loan at 5 percent. Dodd-Frank ended what was called the yield spread premium, which allowed hardworking people to qualify for loans at a lower rate and be put in a loan at a higher rate, and the person doing it suffered no consequences at all because it was lawful. So if you like that kind of kickback scheme you will love the wrong choice act. It allowed people to find themselves in a circumstance where they were paying more for a loan than they should have been, there were more defaults than we should have had. It was a bad circumstance that Dodd-Frank eliminated, the so-called yield spread premium, but it really was just another kickback. If you want to see a real setback then choose the CHOICE Act because the CHOICE Act would allow investment bankers to take your money that you have deposited in a bank, go out to Wall Street and gamble with it, and if they make a profit they get to keep it. They will call it proprietary trading. They will get to keep that profit. And if they lose then the FDIC bails out the bank. It is a bad bill. It allows hardworking Americans to be ripped off with impunity. Ms. Cook, would you kindly give your explanation in terms of how the so-called yield spread premium, the kickback, had an impact on hardworking Americans? Ms. Cook. One manifestation of that was when this was used to put especially African-Americans and Hispanics into mortgages that were actually lower--in lower-quality mortgages than they deserved from their credit score and other information that would have gone into a mortgage decision. So this was absolutely rampant. We are still finding more cases of that from this period, but yes, it was used in a widespread way. Mr. Green. And actually there is no way to really measure how much damage it did. There is no way to adequately determine the suffering. I see a person of the cloth here. You have no way of knowing how much suffering took place because of this so-called yield spread premium that the CHOICE Act will again allow. Mr. Barr, explain if you would for us as tersely as possible how allowing investment bankers to take money that hardworking Americans have deposited and use that money on Wall Street, make a profit and keep it--would you explain, please? Mr. Barr. The Volcker Rule is really designed to try and separate out different kinds of risk in the financial system, so prop trading, short-term trading contributed to some of the problems that the largest firms had, and therefore, when they failed the American people were the ones who ended up suffering from that failure. So that reform, along with other structural reforms, is designed to make it less likely that families will get crushed. Mr. Green. And less likely that deposits that hardworking people place in banks will end up in the hands of an investment banker on Wall Street with a gamble that may or may not succeed, true? Mr. Barr. I think that it is a bigger reform than that. That is, it is designed to really push that risk all the way outside the bank holding company to really try and separate out the risk so families aren't crushed in the future if we have a huge crisis. Mr. Green. And that is what the Volcker Rule did with-- Mr. Barr. Correct. Mr. Green. --Dodd-Frank. But that is being eliminated, true? Mr. Barr. Correct. Mr. Green. Okay. Quickly, I remember how bad it was when we were going through the crisis in 2008. It was such that banks would not lend to each other. The banks refused to lend to each other. We had to pass Dodd-Frank and we still need it. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Pittenger. Mr. Pittenger. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you so much for hosting this very important hearing of one of many scores of hearings we have had with multiple individuals who have come to testify from the private sector as well as from the academic world, those who have had vast experience. And I thank each of you for joining us today. Mr. Allison, I would make special note of my friend from North Carolina, a graduate of North Carolina. Mr. Allison. Thank you. Mr. Pittenger. If I recall, you graduated with high honors and the notoriety of the academic institution is only matched by the prowess on the basketball field, so-- Mr. Allison. Well, I agree. [laughter] Mr. Pittenger. As well as your education at Duke. But more important to me of that is 38 years that you have had in the banking business right there at BB&T, and to serve 20 years as the CEO for that institution. And as I have watched you from a close distance, from Charlotte, a major financial center, those of us in Charlotte have the utmost respect for you as the quintessential banker, one who really understood the business, the one who understood the customer, one who valued the importance of good banking. I was a banker, served on a board of a community bank for 10 years, from the time we chartered until the time we sold the bank. Like you, we were favored with a disciplined approach. We knew our customer and we had very low losses. You, of course, suffered through the 1980s and the 1990s with great success. You went through this last decade without a loss quarter. That is remarkable. And so what you bring to the table, to me, really far surpasses all the regulators, the bureaucrats, people, frankly, I think who have good intentions, who come with the right spirit of wanting to address a real problem. But we get down to the bottom line. We get down to the real world of banking. And for us it was knowing your customer. And you knew your customer. I went in to see you on several occasions just to talk and learn from you during that period of time. But what I want to ask you today is, what is the impact of what has happened as a result of Dodd-Frank on the broader context. What has happened to that entrepreneur? What has happened to that small business guy who is trying to get started? What is the impact of that in terms of our economy in the future? Here we are tepidly moving along at 1.5 percent. This is the only period of time since World War II that we never could reach 3 percent. We have had an average of 3.5 percent for the last 100 years in this country of economic growth, and we are just barely moving along. Look at the future, where we are with our country and where that growth is going to come from, and what is impeding that growth, and how this plays a role into that. Kindly speak to that, if you would. Mr. Allison. Well, unquestionably, healthy banking systems lead to healthy economies. And community banking, even when it is done in a larger organization, is what spurs entrepreneurial activity, because we are basically small business venture capital lenders. And I saw this--to concretize it--that at BB&T our board, once Dodd-Frank passed, we spent 9 or 10 hours a day on regulation and none on running our business. The regulators forced us to get rid of our community banking model. We were a very decentralized organization, which is one reason we went through the financial crisis without any losses. We had local decision-making with people who understood the markets. The regulators forced us to centralize our lending authorities just like the banks that failed. So they absolutely forced the model that hadn't worked because they were all academics and they knew all about mathematics; they just never made a loan, and they didn't understand what banks do, and even larger banks that serve their communities. And the irony is that a handful of Wall Street banks have been the big winner. Mr. Pittenger. While I have a few seconds left, give us a forecast for the future. What is going to happen if we don't fix this problem right now? Mr. Allison. You are going to have a lot more consolidation in the industry and basically community banking as a successful business is not going to continue. But I keep hearing people here say community banks are doing so well. Look at their low stock prices-- Mr. Pittenger. What is going to be the impact on the economy if we don't help this entrepreneur? Mr. Allison. I think it is going to be stuck in slow growth. I think if you don't have entrepreneurship you don't have growth. Mr. Pittenger. Thank you, sir. My time is-- Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Wisconsin, Ms. Moore, ranking member of our Monetary Policy and Trade Subcommittee. Ms. Moore. Thank you so much, Mr. Chairman, and Ranking Member Waters. And I want to thank this distinguished panel. I am the last Member on our side here so I apologize in advance for having you suffer through some of the inquiries along the same lines. But I do appreciate getting some clarification on some things. Mr. Wallison, you and I have talked before about your perspectives and about your views on--your minority views with regard to the financial crisis and its causes. One of the comments that you have made, not only that the fault of this was Freddie and Fannie and CRA, but then you double down today to say that you had done research afterwards and found that your book, which I will be happy to look at, bore all these things out. And you essentially blamed it on predatory borrowers. Now, I don't know about other people in this room but I have only--I am 66 as of last Tuesday and I have only bought 2 homes in my entire life. And the only reason I have a second house is because I was a State Senator and I didn't live in the district and I had to move when I won the State Senate seat. I sold that house to my daughter. People don't go and sit down and buy a house every day. So it is amazing to me that you don't think credit default swaps or lax underwriting or CRA rating agencies are at fault, that you think it was predatory borrowers. But having said that, let me move on and just say that for one thing I--Mr. Chairman, without objection, I would like to enter into the record a letter from former Representative Barney Frank, the former chairman of this committee, his letter to his constituents on the economic crisis. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Ms. Moore. Thank you. One of the things that Barney Frank points out in his letter is that from 1991 until 2006, when Democrats took over the Majority, they were trying desperately to stop predatory lending. And that is what we have found is that there is a lot of predatory lending that was involved. It was not predatory borrowers; it was predatory lending. I also heard you say that Freddie and Fannie underwrote bad loans. Freddie and Fannie do not underwrite loans. They were scammed, as well. Mr. Barr, let me ask you something. This CHOICE bill proposes to repeal Title I of Dodd-Frank, which governs the role of the clearinghouses. Can you talk to us about the systemic risk that may be involved if we were to pass this bill and to undo Title I, which deals with the clearinghouses? Mr. Barr. The legislation would dismantle, basically, the process for overseeing and designating financial market utilities, including derivatives clearinghouses, payments and settlement systems, basically the essential backbone of our economy. So it would remove the ability to impose heightened standards; it would remove the ability to provide liquidity in events of distress. And I think that would be a horrible mistake. It is consistent with the mistake that is made in the other part of the bill that repeals the authority to designate shadow banking firms like Lehman Brothers and AIG-- Ms. Moore. And what--the impact. I have 1 minute left, so-- Mr. Barr. It will crush the economy. Ms. Moore. It will be like when Henry Paulson showed up that day and said, ``Give me $700 billion.'' I don't want to go through that again. All right. So Title I will be eliminated under this legislation. Also, if we don't have the Volcker Rule, this will allow federally-backed funds to trade, and it would create some sort of moral hazard. Do you agree with that, if we were to eliminate the Volcker Rule? There has been discussion of that earlier. Some clarification about what is proprietary trading and what is market-making. I agree we need to hone in on that distinction. But do you think eliminating the Volcker Rule is a good idea? Mr. Barr. I think that would be a mistake. I agree with you that clarification of the lines, what is clearly in, what is clearly out--gray areas might be handled with capital rules. So I think there are ways of implementing the Volcker Rule more efficiently, but I would not eliminate it by any stretch. Ms. Moore. And by the way, 85 percent of all these nonperforming loans were done by non-CRA and non-FDIC-insured banks. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. For what purpose does the ranking member seek recognition? Ms. Waters. Mr. Chairman, I seek unanimous consent to enter into the record 108 letters from groups opposing all or part of the CHOICE Act. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr. Rothfus, for 5 minutes. Mr. Rothfus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank the panel for helping us today understand these various issues. My first questions are going to go to Mr. Wallison and Mr. Pollock. As you know, under Section 165 of the Dodd-Frank Act, firms that are subject to the Fed's heightened prudential supervisions or provisions are required to prepare and submit resolution plans or living wills that demonstrate how they can be resolved under the Bankruptcy Code without posing a risk to U.S. financial stability. Dodd-Frank authorizes the Fed and the FDIC to restrict the business activities of a firm submitting a living will if the firm cannot demonstrate that it can be resolved in a safe and orderly manner under the Bankruptcy Code. If necessary, the Fed and the FDIC, after consulting with the FSOC, may even order a firm to divest assets or operations. Mr. Wallison, your colleague, Paul Kupiec, has pointed out that the living will process outlined in Section 165 of the Dodd-Frank Act is a recipe for government command and control of private enterprise. He writes, ``Living wills are a gateway for regulators to change the company itself. If companies' living wills are not to regulators' liking, regulators can require the institutions to restructure, raise capital, reduce leverage, divest, or downsize. Thus, rejecting a living will gives regulators an opening to restructure the companies themselves. ``This type of regulatory discretion is not uncommon in the world, but it is usually found in banana republics and countries where the government runs the banking system. Such unconstrained authority opens up all sorts of avenues for partiality and government intrusion into a financial institution's operations.'' Mr. Wallison, do you share Mr. Kupiec's concern that the vast discretion granted to Federal regulators under Dodd- Frank's living will regime is essentially a license for those regulators to decide the proper size, scale, and business model of private sector enterprises? Mr. Wallison. Yes. It seems pretty clear that the legislation allows the regulators to permit or to stop certain kinds of activities by companies that would otherwise be helpful to the market and perfectly legal. So yes, this is a major impairment of the freedom of companies to try to develop markets and serve those markets. Mr. Rothfus. Is this setup consistent with your view of how our free-market economy should operate? Mr. Wallison. It is completely inconsistent with how the market should operate, and that is one of the reasons why I oppose it. Mr. Rothfus. Mr. Pollock, do you agree with Mr. Wallison's assessment? If so, will the Financial CHOICE Act provide benefits to firms and the market? Mr. Pollock. Yes, I do agree with him and with Mr. Kupiec. A theme of the Dodd-Frank Act is granting wide, unfettered discretion to regulatory agencies outside of notice and comment rulemaking to impose judgment and subjective views. The living wills are a great example of that. The stress tests, if I may say so, are another example where you can regulate through regulatory proceeding without rules and without laws. Mr. Rothfus. Mr. Pollock, previously Senator Phil Gramm testified before this committee that the Fed and the FDIC have almost total discretion in deciding whether a plan is acceptable. Are you aware of any other industry in the Nation that is subject to such requirements and micromanagement by the Federal Government? Mr. Pollock. I am not. Mr. Rothfus. I am glad my colleague from Wisconsin mentioned the former chairman, Mr. Frank. Mr. Wallison, do you recall a time in maybe 2003 when Barney Frank said he wanted to roll the dice on the housing market? Mr. Wallison. Yes, I do very well. Mr. Rothfus. Do you know if he was ever held accountable? Did anything in Dodd-Frank ever hold him accountable or anybody who wanted to roll the dice in the housing market? Mr. Wallison. No, I am afraid that was not done. Mr. Rothfus. Okay. Dr. Michel, I was at a Women in Business lunch last week in Pittsburgh where most of the attendees were small-business owners, executives, and entrepreneurs. Much of the discussion centered on the difficulties that many women face in pursuing their goals, and we had a great discussion about regulations in Washington. At one point one of the attendees stood up and suggested that regulations were not a problem and challenged those in attendance to identify specific regulations that hurt their business. Immediately--immediately--a woman jumped on that opportunity and she said there--she was an executive with a community bank in the area. She told us that regulatory burdens for her firm were over the top in every respect. Thanks to the CFPB and its mortgage disclosure rules it now took her customers twice as long to close on a home--6 weeks to 12 weeks. Disclosure documents had also nearly tripled in length, leading to increased cost and customer confusion. How do the reforms in the Financial CHOICE Act provide consumers relative to the CFPB with the protections they deserve while supporting the growth of a vibrant financial sector? Chairman Hensarling. Very brief answer, please. Mr. Michel. Okay. Well, very brief, I-- Chairman Hensarling. If a brief answer is not possible-- Mr. Michel. No, I-- Mr. Rothfus. We will follow up-- Mr. Michel. I'm sorry, yes. Mr. Rothfus. We will follow up. Mr. Michel. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair wishes to advise all members and our panel that we expect Floor votes somewhere in the next 15 minutes. Shortly thereafter we will recess. I believe two votes will be pending on the Floor at that time so we will recess for approximately 30 to 40 minutes, at which time our panel can take a needed break. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Washington, Mr. Heck, for 5 minutes. Mr. Heck. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, very much. So from where I sit I thought that the Great Recession, the global financial crisis, was the worst financial crash or panic certainly of my lifetime, not having lived through the Great Depression. It obviously came, I think we would all acknowledge, as a surprise to a lot of bankers and regulators. And as a consequence, it caused a lot of people to do some serious introspection and reevaluation of their thinking, most notably including in 2008 the former Chair of the Federal Reserve, Alan Greenspan, who testified before the House and made the following statement: ``I made a mistake. I made a mistake in presuming that the self-interest of organizations, specifically banks and others, were such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders and their equity in their firms.'' More recently than 2008 he said, ``I have come around to the view that there is something more systematic about the way people behave irrationally, especially during periods of extreme economic distress, than I had previously contemplated.'' Those are obviously big statements and big changes from the vantage point of Chairman Greenspan, who had previously believed, as we all know, that regulators should absolutely defer to markets, which were made up, he thought at the time, of rational, self-interested actors. So I have read all your testimony today and, frankly, I wish there was more discussion of the lessons learned from the financial crisis and the Great Recession, because I think it is really important that we not go through that again, not have all that net worth wiped out, not have all that unemployment created. So I am going to ask each of you, beginning with Mr. Allison, very, very briefly, if I may, to follow the model of Chairman Greenspan very succinctly and tell me what you learned from the financial crisis that conflicted with your earlier beliefs. Mr. Allison. I learned that government policy, even well- intended, can be incredibly destructive. Affordable housing, which was really subprime lending, had very positive thoughts behind it and it was incredibly destructive and driven by government policy, including by Alan Greenspan, by the way. Mr. Heck. Thank you, Mr. Allison. Banks played no role in lending money to people who shouldn't have been-- Mr. Allison. Banks made mistakes too. Mr. Heck. They are not government. The banks weren't government. They loaned money to people that they shouldn't have. Mr. Allison. They were regulated. Mr. Heck. I call it the fog-of-mirror test. Mr. Allison. They were regulated. Mr. Heck. Ms. Peirce? Ms. Peirce. I learned that when you put institutions into a system where a lot of their decisions are being driven by regulation they often behave differently than you would expect a self-interested institution to behave. Mr. Heck. ``They made me do it.'' Dr. Cook? Ms. Cook. I believe that the monetary authorities should have as much flexibility and as many tools as they can to fight the next financial crisis, and they don't need to be micromanaged. Mr. Heck. Mr. Pollock? Mr. Pollock. Having for decades studied financial cycles, Congressman, I learned that this cycle was like the others-- severe, but there have been other severe cycles. And I agree that mistakes are key. Mr. Greenspan made an incredible mistake in deciding to set off a housing boom in the early 2000s. That is part of the government's responsibility. Mr. Heck. And the private sector played no role in it. I am always amazed--I have to interrupt and say I am always amazed that there are ideological points of view that seek to attribute and allocate 100 percent of the culpability to the three parties to this. It amazes me. Did the government not catch this, not intervene? Yes. Did the private sector, in the form of the banks, loan money to people that they should not have? Yes. Did people seek loans that they could not support? Yes. There is plenty of blame to go around, and I just have to say that when we refuse to acknowledge that there is lots of culpability to go around here, it frankly impedes our progress in preventing it again. Mr. Barr? Mr. Barr. I agree with the last statement you just made. What I was going to say is that I think all the gatekeepers and safeguards in the system broke. So all of our private sector safeguards broke down: the capital provision broke down; lawyers didn't do their jobs; credit rating agencies didn't do their jobs; supervisors didn't do their jobs; bankers didn't do their jobs; and borrowers didn't do their jobs. We had just a disastrous consequence when all of that broke down. Mr. Heck. Thank you. I don't have enough time left for the two of you, and I apologize. But I am going to ask one quick question, ask you to raise your hands. Raise your hand if you think that the problem of the last 10 years is too much investigation of financial crimes and abuses? Who thinks there is too much investigation of financial crimes and abuses? [No hands were raised.] Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back the balance of my time. Mr. Rothfus [presiding]. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Colorado, Mr. Tipton, for 5 minutes. Mr. Tipton. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I thank the panel for taking the time to be here. Mr. Allison, listening to you, I thought it was really interesting--you were talking about CEOs of banks now being compliance officers, not being able to actually do the business that they want to be able to do to be able to loan to the communities. And you are in North Carolina, is that correct? Mr. Allison. Yes, sir. Mr. Tipton. I have a couple of comments out of Colorado, small community banks out of Colorado. One stated to me, ``We have shut down the majority of our mortgage group from 15 to 4 people because the business model no longer made sense. People lost jobs because the cost of the regulatory burden was too much.'' Another gentleman, a banker in Durango, Colorado, stated, ``We want to be able to have the ability to be flexible with products in dealing with customers, but because of Dodd-Frank it is not, `How can we help the customer;' it is now a matter of, `How can we not get in trouble with compliance?''' In terms of dealing with our small community banks, do you think it would be important for us to be able to actually tailor rules and regulations to be able to meet those needs of the small community banks rather than the one-size-fits-all mentality of Dodd-Frank? Mr. Allison. I absolutely do, and I think you have to take away the structure that is there or the community banks are going to get stuck with the big bank regulations. Mr. Tipton. When we are going down that road of actually sculpting it we had had Chair Yellen, and she kept talking about the trickle-down effect. So there seems to be unanimous opinion that our small community banks are really being bound by Dodd-Frank's action. Under Section 546 of the CHOICE Act, it includes my bill, the TAILOR Act, and this legislation would require that financial regulators examine the unintended effect of unnecessarily burdensome compliance requirements. Do you believe that this would achieve a more balanced approach to right-size regulatory framework? Mr. Allison. I think it would be very helpful. Mr. Tipton. Good. Mr. Pollock, I thought it was interesting listening to some of the comments that we have had in regards to the impact of regulators in terms of policy that is going through. Is there anything that was required in Dodd-Frank when it came to actually doing a cost-benefit analysis, in terms of how rules and regulations were put into place and how it would impact? Mr. Pollock. I don't believe so, Congressman, and it is certainly not a theme of Dodd-Frank, but it is a theme of the CHOICE Act, I think a very good one. It is fundamentally important that things be looked at in terms of benefits and costs. Even if there is quite a bit of uncertainty, confronting the uncertainty is extremely important. Mr. Tipton. Right. We often hear from some of our friends that really being able to have a cost-benefit analysis is just a tactic to be able to put the brakes on regulators. Do you see it that way? Mr. Pollock. I see it as a logical requirement for rational action, Congressman. Mr. Tipton. Mr. Wallison, do you have any comments on that? Mr. Wallison. No. I think that is exactly--I agree completely, as usual, with Mr. Pollock's position on these things. Mr. Tipton. Okay. Mr. Pollock, then, I will go to you again. In the absence of an explicit statutory requirement, having financial regulators conduct an economic analysis and a retrospective review of their regulations, would that be an important thing to do? Mr. Pollock. I think it is a great idea, which is in the CHOICE Act, Congressman. We all ought to be doing that. We were talking a minute ago about reviewing our mistakes, and we should review our past actions for what was right and what was wrong. And if it was wrong that gives us a chance to fix it. Mr. Tipton. All right. And just to go back to you, Mr. Allison, a little bit more on the community banks, listening to some of the questions from our Democratic colleagues, regulatorily were banks put in a position if they did not make a loan they were going to be in violation and if they did not make the loan they were going to be in violation? Did you find experiences like that? Mr. Allison. Absolutely. There was tremendous pressure to do subprime lending. Yes, some banks got greedy and made mistakes. Ironically, those were the banks that were saved, like Citigroup, in my view. And they were big banks. And that was a mistake because what that does is encourage those banks to continue. They should be allowed to fail. I think the CHOICE Act would be much more effective at dealing with bank failures. And I do not agree with the systematic risk. Citigroup could have gone broke and BB&T would have been happy; it would have been a good day. So Citigroup has been saved 3 times during my banking career. That is how we got too-big-to-fail banks. The community banks always get hit with penalties because the really big banks do bad things and get bailed out. Mr. Tipton. All right. Thank you. My time has expired, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Rothfus. The Chair would like to advise the committee that votes have been called. We intend to go through two more sets of questions. Right now, we have Mr. Williams and Mr. Poliquin on deck. We will be taking a brief recess then to finish up the votes. And I recognize the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Williams. Mr. Williams. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And one could argue-- Mr. Rothfus. Will the gentleman suspend? For what purpose does the ranking member seek recognition? Ms. Waters. Mr. Chairman, pursuant to clause 2(j)(1) of rule 11 and clause d(5) of rule three of the rules of this committee I am submitting for your consideration a letter signed by all of the Democrats of the Financial Services Committee notifying you of our intent to hold a Democratic hearing, also known as a minority day hearing, on the Financial CHOICE Act before a committee vote on this measure. I look forward to working with you to determine the date, time, and location of such a hearing. Mr. Rothfus. The demand being properly supported, the continued hearing day will be scheduled with the concurrence of the ranking member and members will receive notice once the day is scheduled. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Williams, for 5 minutes. Mr. Williams. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I guess with what we have heard today with this testimony is that the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau is one of the most unacceptable and most unaccountable agencies in the history of the United States. So what happens when you create an agency that is not only unaccountable to Congress but unaccountable to the American taxpayer? Let me give you a few examples. First, you get an agency that uses strong-arm tactics to encourage payments or settlements, often using faulty studies to justify enforcement. That is what happened to Ally and others who found themselves in the crosshairs of the CFPB. Second, you have an agency that is growing by leaps and bounds with no end in sight. According to the CFPB's own strategic plan, the fiscal year budget estimate for 2017 is $636 million, a 5 percent increase from last year. Third, you get rules that are thousands of pages. The proposed rule on payday lending is 1,341 pages, not to be outdone by the rule on prepaid accounts, totaling 1,689 pages long. And finally, you have an agency that hides behind their consumer complaint database. Although the CFPB received just 0.06 percent of their overall complaints on the above-mentioned prepaid cards, the Bureau ignored more than 5,000 public comments--in this book right here, okay, they ignored that-- expressing support for these products and issued the rule anyways, all at the expense of the consumer. So this is what Dodd-Frank gave us, Mr. Chairman, and that is why it is so important to fix this disastrous law. Now, Dr. Michel, let me begin with you. As we have talked about, the very structure of the CFPB rule was unconstitutional late last year. The court rules in order to bring the agency within constitutional bounds the President must be able to remove the Director at will. Do you agree with the D.C. Circuit opinion that the lack of accountability Dodd-Frank provided the CFPB was so great that it violated the separation of powers embedded in the Constitution? Mr. Michel. Yes, I agree, and the PHH case is a great example. You have a Director who can't be removed, who decided on which case he wanted to enforce, which company he wanted to go after, decided which statutes did and didn't apply, decided that it would be an ALJ proceeding, decided that he didn't like the ruling, decided he could double the fine. Mr. Williams. Okay. Mr. Michel. All of these things. Mr. Williams. All right. Another question: Would making the agency's Director removable at will by the President provide accountability to the agency? Mr. Michel. That would be an improvement, yes. Mr. Williams. All right. Again, Dr. Michel, the FTC has been enforcing consumer protection for decades before the CFPB existed without ever conducting supervision. Isn't that right? Mr. Michel. Correct. Mr. Williams. Okay. Do you believe that the FTC has been effective in protecting consumers through enforcement actions without supervision power? Mr. Michel. Yes. Mr. Williams. Okay. And do you believe the CFPB would be effective at protecting consumers as a civil enforcement agency that has investigative and enforcement authority rather than supervisory authority? Mr. Michel. Yes, especially when it comes to the banking industry. They don't need any more supervisors. Mr. Williams. Thank you. Would you comment on that, Mr. Wallison? Mr. Wallison. Yes. I agree that they don't need any more supervisors. Every agency of the Executive Branch ought to be accountable to the President. Otherwise, our elections mean nothing. You elect a President, and if Congress has the power to say, ``This person cannot be removed from office,'' they are saying the election of the President had no meaning. It did not make that person accountable in any way. So this is what is at stake in the CFPB case. Mr. Williams. And just in closing, Mr. Allison, when the public hears people in your industry and even in my industry--I am a car dealer--say that since this legislation you have literally had to hire more compliance officers and loan officers, that is a true statement, isn't it? Mr. Allison. Absolutely. Mr. Williams. And who is affected by that? Mr. Allison. The consumer. The consumer always pays. Mr. Williams. Right. I yield my time back, Mr. Chairman. Thank you very much. Mr. Rothfus. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Maine, Mr. Poliquin, for 5 minutes. Mr. Poliquin. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate it. Thank you, everyone, for being here today. I represent some of the hardest-working, most honest people in America up in Maine's 2nd District. Maine is vacation land. Now, if you folks have not planned your vacation to Maine, it is a good time to consider that because we are booking up quickly and we have staff here to help anybody out if they need that help. Mr. Allison, we have about 500 small towns in our State. And in these small towns you often have a community bank, a credit union, maybe a local insurance agency or a retirement fund manager. And these folks, these little institutions are the pillars of our community. I love to travel around our district. I am a business professional. Like you folks, this is not my profession in politics. I am here to help, but I love to talk to folks who grow our economy and create jobs. I love to do it. And without exception, Mr. Allison, they tell me what Mr. Williams and Mr. Tipton have already talked about, which is their major problem is this compliance and this paperwork. They are spending more time filling out paperwork than they are selling money. Mr. Allison. Absolutely. Mr. Poliquin. I remember a conversation I had with a loan officer up in the Machias Savings Bank way down east in Maine when you--right before you hit Canada you take a left, right down there. And they are saying this is just driving up the cost of the business that we have and they can't get this--the money out they need to families that want to grow and businesses that want to grow and hire. So my question, Mr. Allison, is in your opinion--you have 30 years' experience in the banking business--does this CHOICE Act help with that problem such that small community banks and credit unions, and what have you, are going to be relieved of some of this burden of compliance and instead get in the business of lending money to our families? Mr. Allison. Absolutely. I think the CHOICE Act would be very beneficial in that regard. Mr. Poliquin. We have roughly 26 small community banks in Maine. And they are traditional: they take in deposits, Mr. Allison, and they provide checking accounts and savings accounts and lend out money. They do not package these mortgages and sell them in the secondary market. Bangor Savings Bank and the Community Credit Union in Lewiston, they did not cause this recession. Don't you think it is a good idea to make sure to back up what Mr. Tipton said, that the regulations, the rules that these bureaucrats in Washington come up are tailored to specifically the size and the type of institution and the complexity of an institution instead of otherwise? Mr. Allison. Absolutely. And it is ironic that Dodd-Frank was supposed to penalize the very large banks, the Wall Street banks, and it has actually helped them and it has actually hurt the community banks, which did not cause this crisis. Mr. Poliquin. Great. We are batting a thousand. Let me ask you another question, sir. FSOC currently continues to deliberate on whether or not nonbank financial institutions should be designated as too-big-to-fail and therefore come under a whole other set of regulations and rules that drive up cost, reduce product offering, and so forth and so on. Now, if you or I are in the investment management business--we run pension mans, retirement assets--and your--I hate to say this--your performance is lackluster and mine is good. Your client is going to leave you and come to me. But guess what? The assets are held by Roger down the street in a custodial bank, so if you get into trouble or I get into trouble but the assets are held here, does that represent a systemic risk to our economy? Mr. Allison. Absolutely not. Mr. Poliquin. Of course it doesn't. What advice would you give this committee when it comes to FSOC's ability to designate those nonbank financial institutions that represent no systemic risk to our economy-- what advice would you give them with respect to the CHOICE Act? Mr. Allison. I absolutely don't think that they ought to be able to designate them. And I think also those companies ought to be allowed to fail if they get in trouble. That is good. Mr. Poliquin. Which brings me to my next point and my last point: The CHOICE Act ends the requirement for taxpayers to bail out big Wall Street banks if they take too much risk and get into trouble. I happen to think that is a great thing. Now, we have a Bankruptcy Code that deals with this. Do you think that Code, the existing laws we have now, could handle this problem? Mr. Allison. I think we need some modification to the Bankruptcy Code, but I think the Bankruptcy Code would be much better than what has been proposed in the Dodd-Frank law. Mr. Poliquin. Okay. And does the CHOICE Act accommodate that end? Mr. Allison. Yes. Mr. Poliquin. Thank you, Mr. Allison, very much. Mr. Chairman, I yield back my time. Don't forget the trip to Maine this summer. Mr. Rothfus. The gentleman yields back. Votes have been called. This is a two-vote series. The committee will reconvene immediately after this vote series. The committee stands in recess. [recess] Chairman Hensarling. The committee will come to order. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Utah, Mrs. Love, for 5 minutes. Mrs. Love. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for all of our Members who are here, and our witnesses who are here for this hearing. I really appreciate it. I want to start off with Mr. Wallison. You may have noticed a slide being displayed over the course of this hearing that cites the Federal Reserve data indicating that commercial and industrial loans are up 75 percent since Dodd-Frank became law. The graph represents trends for loans and leases and bank credits for all commercial banks through December 2016. So in your opinion, in your experience do you think that that figure is entirely accurate? Mr. Wallison. No. Actually I don't understand that. Mrs. Love. Okay. So in what ways do you think that there is room for nuances in explaining that trend? Mr. Wallison. For one thing, all of the data that we have seen shows that banks have not yet reached the point where they were in 2008--the banking system as a whole--except for the very largest banks, which are doing quite well. But in terms of return on equity and return on assets, banks in general are still below where they were in 2008. In addition, and this is the most devastating fact about this whole situation: There were 25 new banks in 2009; there were 9 in 2010; there were 3 in 2011; and since then there have been either zero or one in all the subsequent years. Now what does that say? That says that the banks cannot make a profit. Otherwise people would be forming new banks. So we have a serious problem here with this legislation. We have to get this out, and we have to start relieving the pressure on our community banks. Mrs. Love. Do you have that graph that we can pull up? Does staff have that other graph that we pulled up, where we separated large banks and small banks? There we go, right there. Can you look at the one before Dodd-Frank, please. When we took the data and we separated between large banks and small banks, the data before showed that small banks, you can see the difference between small banks and large banks. Now look at the data after. Which tells me that large banks are doing okay and small banks are the ones that are providing less access to credit for those who need it in their communities. Mr. Wallison. That is right. In my prepared statement I have a couple of charts that show exactly that--that the loans from the large banks have been going up and the loans from the small banks have been going down. Large loans have been going up and small loans have been going down, all consistent completely with the idea that the small banks are gradually going out of business because of the regulation, and the large banks are taking up whatever new business there is. Mrs. Love. I am being as fair as I possibly can here. Who are the people that small banks lend to versus the people that large banks lend to? Mr. Wallison. The large banks are not lending to the very smallest businesses. They are lending to the larger small businesses. But the really troublesome part is the startups, because in our economy, fortunately, and this has always been true, everything starts from the bottom. And the little companies that develop over time are the ones that eventually become the big companies and displace in many cases the big companies. The startups are in the most trouble now because the smaller banks lend to the startups, but they make what would be called character loans. They are making it to people whom they know in the community, and those loans are not being made anymore because bank the examiners are stopping them from doing it. Mrs. Love. Let me tell you, the people that I represent are actually getting less access to credit because of the burdensome regulations that are being imposed on our small bank communities. Now people may say that this is not really about small banks and large banks, and we are not really here to help small banks. But I am telling you right now, when you get Jennifer Jones, who can't get a loan from her small bank in her community to expand her school, that affects middle- to lower- income families. When you get Brett Madson in Sanpete County, who has a turkey farm, and can't get access to the credit that he needs in order to get the tools that he needs to farm his turkeys, that affects the people in his community. Goldman Sachs is not in Sanpete County. JPMorgan Chase is not in Saratoga Springs. And all of the banks that give them access to credit are closing their doors every day. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Arkansas, Mr. Hill. Mr. Hill. I thank the chairman. Thank you for holding this hearing. I was particularly pleased about the CHOICE Act, because it really has one of the first innovative proposals that we have seen in the regulatory in terms of ideas in some time. And I want to thank Mr. Allison and certainly my friend Tom Hoenig at the FDIC for being the inspiration behind it, and that is this off-ramp provision for banks that hold tier 1 capital at 10 percent, tier 1 leverage ratio of 10 percent. I was looking at all of the banks at the end of the year in Arkansas, and three quarters of our community banks--we have 103 community banks in Arkansas--meet that 10 percent leverage ratio. There are several others that are quite close. The median ratio for the State was 11.16 in tier 1 leverage ratios. So I really do think that this is an important step to reward high capital with a more modest footprint of complexity in how we do prudential regulation. Mr. Allison, have you been able to identify sort of in your own thinking about this, because you have done a lot of thinking on this point, do you like the 10 percent leverage ratio number that we have selected? Do you think that sort of represents a sweet spot between capitalization and financial stability, while at the same time facilitating bank continued growth and profitability? Mr. Allison. I do. I think it is a reasonable number. Defining that number is part art and part science, but the important thing is you have to have a fair trade-off. What Dodd-Frank asks is for banks to have a lot of capital and a lot of regulation. They can't stay in business, and the regulators have chosen more regulation because they like to regulate, right? It is their job. I think we would be much better off with more capital and less regulation, so that is what makes it work economically. Mr. Hill. I am really reminded, knowing of your past CEO- ship of BB&T, I am really reminded of Jim Grant's quote last year in his newsletter, where he said that because of Chair Yellen's desire to have macro-prudential regulation, Grant postulated there is just no rule for micro-prudentialism. That is, what CEOs and boards of directors are supposed to do. And he said, do you think there would be any difference in outcome if all management at the bank didn't show up one day and just the regulators were there? Mr. Allison. I think all the banks would fail fairly quickly, in my opinion. Mr. Hill. Thank you for that. If I could turn to Ms. Peirce because I want to switch gears from capital formation to the ideas of capital formation for another challenge that we have tried to address in this bill, which is a loss of our public companies. About 50 percent of our public companies we have lost. This means there are fewer opportunities for people's 401(k) plans, fewer opportunities for individual investors to participate in economic growth. And one of those barriers is this regulatory cost of being public, and one of those issues is the burden of the governance process and access to the proxy. Do you think the current $2,000 ownership threshold for submitting a shareholder proposal is still in today's age a reasonable threshold? And also, in the holding period, is a one-year holding period requirement for submitting that proposal reasonable? Ms. Peirce. Yes, I think it is time to revisit those thresholds because shareholder proposals have become very costly to companies and to the SEC in processing them. So it seems to make sense to take a look. Shareholders obviously pay every time a company has to respond, so we need to look again and see what reasonable thresholds would be. Mr. Hill. Thank you. Mr. Wallison, one thing I have heard from regulators off the record, and from bankers of all sizes, community banks and then large, complex institutions, is the issue that the Volcker Rule, no matter how well-intended, just isn't working. What are your thoughts about the burdens to institutions of all sizes, and is that rule, you think, misdirected? Mr. Wallison. The Volcker Rule is a really serious problem. And first of all, it applies to much more than just insured banks. It applies to all firms affiliated with banks in any way. So they are all covered by these restrictions. The trouble is that it not only affects their ability to buy and sell securities as market makers, it also affects hedging. The banks have to do hedging in order to protect themselves against losses on the various things that they are invested in. Unless they can show that the hedge is actually related to something they have invested in, they are in danger of being charged with proprietary trading. In order to put on a hedge, the hedge must be related to something, some kind of security bought for their own accounts, which sounds like proprietary trading. So the banks are likely to become much more risk averse, even the largest banks as well as the medium-sized and small ones, when they have to comply with the rule. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Minnesota, Mr. Emmer. Mr. Emmer. I thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I want to thank you for holding this hearing. Earlier today it was suggested that it is wonderful that this is regular order but we hope we are going to have more than one hearing on this. It ignores the fact that many of the concepts that are in the CHOICE proposal have been debated and discussed now for years. And to Representative Love's point, when she had those graphs put back up on the screen, if we think back to 2008, there were roughly 8,000 community banks in this country and roughly 8,000 credit unions. A year after the crash there were roughly 8,000 community banks and roughly 8,000 credit unions. They did not cause the crash. And yet, here we are a little more than 6 years after Dodd- Frank was passed and we are down to about 6,000 each and we are not growing at all. It is pretty clear that Dodd-Frank has been a problem to the capital generator for the small recesses, as Mr. Wallison was talking about. Nobody, as I have heard today, is talking about some of the specific organizations created in Dodd-Frank and I would like to touch on one, and maybe start with you, Mr. Wallison. The Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC), another one of these very interesting organizations that was created, for a guy who is new to Congress, off the books. It is not under the appropriations process or the supervision of Congress. It works off the books. Mr. Barr states in his written testimony that the FSOC, as it is known in the alphabet soup of Washington, in making its SIFI determinations, has established a system that again, in Mr. Barr's words, ``provides for a sound, deliberative process, protection of confidential and proprietary information, and meaningful and timely participation by affected firms.'' Mr. Wallison, do you agree with this assessment of the FSOC's process? Mr. Wallison. I am afraid I can't agree with that. We didn't know very much about the process until the MetLife case, when MetLife actually challenged its designation. They described what they were permitted to see, and what the FSOC had as evidence for their being designated. They were restricted from seeing a lot of the things that anyone who is in a normal kind of investigative situation like that would be permitted to see. So the FSOC is not only non-transparent for those of us outside, it is not even transparent for the people who are inside and being designated. So you cannot call this a fair process, and I am afraid it is more like a ``Star Chamber'' than anything else. Mr. Emmer. I am glad you brought that up because another one of the quotes has to do with--I think in his written testimony Mr. Barr notes that members of the FSOC are not beholden to their agencies but rather, ``participate based on their individual expertise and their own assessments of the risks in the financial system.'' It's very interesting that when we talk about their expertise, they express and are heard based on their expertise, especially when we look at the MetLife situation. When the guy with expertise in insurance was completely ignored within the Star Chamber, as you refer to it, is there really a deliberative process that goes on in the FSOC? Mr. Wallison. There are two big problems. First of all, you might be an expert in securities, but you are the only securities expert who is sitting on the Council, and there are three bank experts sitting there, too. So the banks have more votes than other parts of the financial system. Another part of this, so troubling to me and to anyone who is concerned about the Constitution, is that the people who are sitting on the FSOC Board are all appointed by the same President. Ordinarily, in agencies that are commissions, you have a bipartisan arrangement. So a commission, when it speaks, is speaking on a bipartisan basis. But when you appoint only the person who is the chairman of an agency, that person probably was appointed by the President in power, and all of the members are sitting around the table and they are looking at one person, the Chairman, who is the Secretary of the Treasury and a very close person, a very close advisor to the President of the United States. So when the Secretary says, this is what we should do, these people are not going to be exercising their individual abilities and skills. What they are going to be doing is simply following the direction that they are getting from the Secretary. Mr. Emmer. And it looks like I am going to run out of time, but I was going to ask Ms. Peirce if putting them under the congressional supervision and appropriations process might not solve some of these problems, short of getting rid of it. But I see my time has expired, so I apologize. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New York, Mr. Zeldin. Mr. Zeldin. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I appreciate your leadership on behalf of those hard-working constituents in the 1st Congressional District of New York on Long Island trying to obtain a home loan for a new house, or to obtain a car loan, or to be able to access free checking for that small business in my district, trying to access more capital. I appreciate all the witnesses for being here today. In my district there are a lot of small business owners and entrepreneurs who have that next great product or idea and are struggling to access capital when it comes time to get their businesses off the ground. These innovators are being forced out-of-State, or worse, out of the country to find a more favorable regulatory climate. These firms are often pre-revenue, having just enough cash on hand to keep the lights on. So without access to private capital, growing their business and hiring is impossible. Most of these emerging firms are also pre-IPO and need to attract the ground-level investors that make going public and to grow, create more jobs possible. Unfortunately, major obstacles have been put in place by Dodd-Frank and other onerous laws and regulations that made it harder for these entrepreneurs to hire, grow, and make money. Ms. Peirce, I would like to start with you. What provisions in the CHOICE Act, and in particular Title IV, will most help small and emerging companies to grow and create jobs? Ms. Peirce. I think there are a number of provisions that will be helpful, including making it easier for venture capital funds and for angel investors to invest in small companies. I think that also once the company--when a company is looking for investors, it needs to look for accredited investors if it is a private company generally. The bill would expand the types of people who can qualify as accredited investors, which is a much-needed change. Mr. Zeldin. Mr. Allison, would you like to add anything to that? Mr. Allison. I think the biggest thing is the opt-out will allow community banks to go do what we did at BB&T, which is do venture capital lending for small businesses that are really too small for even the smallest end of the private capital market. That is a very low-risk market long-term if you do it right, and we had thousands of success stories and created hundreds of thousands of jobs, and we can't do that anymore. Mr. Zeldin. I thank you both, and I appreciate your perspective. There was a comment made earlier that I wouldn't want anyone to take the wrong way, as if there aren't other economists on this panel with a broad breadth of experience capable of talking macro economics. Dr. Michel, what have been the macro economic impacts of the hundreds of new regulations imposed by Dodd-Frank? Mr. Michel. So we estimated part of that, with a standard sort of look at banking risk, or I should say banking cost, excess borrowing cost, and we came up with a 22 basis point increase since Dodd-Frank. A colleague of mine at Heritage and I use that--that is the we--and we use that in a macro, standard macro economic approach to pull that excess borrowing cost back out of the economy. And it estimated around 1 percent increase per year in GDP. It had up to I think about a $340 billion dynamic revenue effect. It had a 3 percent per year average increase in the capital stock. This is not a model that was designed to model Dodd-Frank. This is just the standard macro approach. So quite significant cost, quite significant impact. Mr. Zeldin. Mr. Allison, do you want to add anything to that? Mr. Allison. I don't have a concrete measure, but there is no question that we have had less innovation. You can just look at the start-up numbers for new businesses. In the shift in employment where new businesses and small businesses are getting a smaller and smaller share of the economy, and a lot of jobs unfortunately in the big businesses are entry-level jobs. So the shift has impacted the quality of jobs, not only the quantity of jobs. And the creation of innovative jobs. Mr. Zeldin. Thank you, Mr. Allison. I going to yield the remainder of my time to Mr. Emmer to finish his question for Ms. Peirce. Mr. Emmer. Thank you. Ms. Peirce, so the question quite simply is, by putting something like the Financial Stability Oversight Council under the supervision of Congress and in the appropriations process, could we solve some of the issues? Ms. Peirce. Yes, certainly appropriations will be helpful in making FSOC more accountable. Taking away its designation powers is also an important step. Mr. Emmer. Thank you very much. I yield back. Mr. Zeldin. I yield back to the Chair the remainder of my time. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Georgia, Mr. Loudermilk. Mr. Loudermilk. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I thank everyone on the panel for being here. We have an opportunity to correct what I believe was one of the greatest wrongs done to the economy and the American people. I want to talk a little bit about stress tests. My doctor wanted to do a stress test, but he told me after the last couple of weeks dealing with healthcare legislation that if I am still walking, I am probably pretty good. Dealing with the stress test, the committee has had some testimony and hearings we have had here that often regulators are punishing banks for failing to meet requirements that are never stated. Mr. Allison, has the Fed lacked transparency around the stress test process? Mr. Allison. The stress test in theory can be useful, but what has happened is there has been an incredible waste of resources around stress tests because the regulators started out saying they wanted banks to come up with their own stress test, but at the end of the day they want everybody to have exactly the same stress test. The irony is that type of stress testing increases risk, because if everybody risk weights the same assets the same, you get systematic errors. A concrete example of this is very recently in energy lending, which a few years ago was supposed to be low risk and now it is high risk. And low risk weighting encouraged more energy lending and actually increased risk. So stress test, banks doing mathematical models, is okay independently. However, when they are forced by regulators, the tests lead to bad outcomes. You can probably imagine that in medicine, it's the same kind of thing. Mr. Loudermilk. I know that the Fed recently exempted most banks from the qualitative part of the CCAR stress test. Should we expand that to all banks? Mr. Allison. I would say so because the qualitative is totally a subjective judgment on the regulators' part and they won't tell you what it is. I know at my company they had to spend a whole bunch of money making the qualitative side better, even though the bank was ranked as one of the lowest- risk banks in America. Mr. Loudermilk. Mr. Pollock? Mr. Pollock. I fully agree. I think the qualitative part, which is indeed purely subjective and political, should be eliminated. Mr. Loudermilk. Ironically, Fannie and Freddie both passed those stringent stress tests right before they failed in September of 2008. Even former Chair Ben Bernanke stated it was difficult to predict future economic turmoil. Are the stress tests really a reliable tool for predicting future downturns? Mr. Allison. I think not. I think they can be a tool if they are taken in context, but we have done a bunch of studies at Cato that show the more complex a model is, and the stress test models are very complex, the more likely it will be wrong. Rules of thumb models, like debt service to income in the mortgage business, are much better than complex mathematical models, which stress tests are, because in the models, the forest gets lost for all the trees. Mr. Loudermilk. Mr. Pollock? Mr. Pollock. Paul Kupiec at AEI did a study recently of stress tests showing that their outcomes were wildly inaccurate. Mr. Loudermilk. Thank you. Dr. Michel, let us talk about the CFPB and the massive amount of data that they have been collecting, and the potential of cybersecurity risk. Now I also serve on the Science, Space, and Technology Committee in the last Congress, which led some investigations into some cybersecurity breaches. We had the Inspector General at one of our hearings and I asked the Inspector General--this was after the OPM data breach--if he would rate, on the elementary school rating scale, the Federal Government's cybersecurity posture. He said it was a ``D minus.'' The only reason he didn't give it an ``F'' is because of the minor changes that were made at the OPM after their breach. How concerned should we be with the mass collection of data with the CFPB, and what is our risk of exposure, not only just to bad players in this Nation but foreign entities? Mr. Michel. I am not a cybersecurity expert by any stretch, but I am concerned that they are collecting so much data, principally because I still don't really see exactly what they are doing with it. You have a lot of stuff that is being collected that is just sitting there in many respects with no clear purpose, as far as I can tell. Do you want me to elaborate for just a second? Mr. Loudermilk. Sure. Mr. Michel. The payday lending stuff is a great example. You have millions and millions of things in this database on all these people, and if you look at the number of complaints on payday lending, it amounts to about a 10th of a percent of transactions in the industry. Yet that has all been pushed aside. That would dictate to a rational person that maybe this isn't such a big problem. Instead, they come out with a rule and they openly say that this could kill off 85 percent of the industry. Those two things don't mesh at all. So I don't understand what the purpose is of collecting all that data. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. At this time, the Chair wishes to thank Mr. Wallison for his testimony today, and Mr. Wallison, you are now excused from the panel. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Ohio, Mr. Davidson. Mr. Davidson. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Mr. Wallison, thank you for being here. Thanks for the things that you have addressed with the FSB, and particularly the shortchanges they have done on American sovereignty. So that is a particular concern. I have enough questions for other folks. Thanks for being here. And really, thank you all. I have learned a lot and reaffirmed many things that I have already learned about the impact of Dodd-Frank, both from your testimony today and from your prior work. So, thank you. Mr. Allison in particular, I appreciate your clarity, here today, in your books, and in your work at Cato. And you all have sounded the alarm for some of the misses and perhaps unintended consequences of Dodd-Frank. While I have myriad concerns about the negative impact on families, farms, and businesses, I am particularly concerned about due process. These protections are some of the most important in our Bill of Rights. Ms. Peirce, you have talked a fair bit about some of those concerns with respect to the SEC. Under Dodd-Frank, do respondents in SEC administrative proceedings have the same rights as defendants do in Federal district court? Ms. Peirce. No, the two systems are different, and some have argued that there are some issues with the administrative proceedings and have called on the SEC to make changes. I don't think the SEC has made enough changes yet to equal out the two. Mr. Davidson. Does the mismatch create the potential for different legal interpretations of the same or similar laws, and potentially create inconsistent enforcement outcomes? Ms. Peirce. It does. There is a potential that you could get different outcomes depending on which forum you are in. Mr. Davidson. Do you believe that a respondent can receive a fair outcome when the SEC serves as prosecutor, judge, jury, and many times ultimately the appellate body? Ms. Peirce. I think that the SEC can run its system well. I think it will run it better if people have the option of going to court if they prefer, which is what the CHOICE Act would allow. Mr. Davidson. Thank you for that. And I just wanted to open up to the panel some of the concerns that you may have with respect to due process that you have seen as a consequence of Dodd-Frank changes. Mr. Allison. I think one general thing is that any regulated company, particularly now, really doesn't have practical access to the court system because by the time the courts decide, you are already out of business. And under the doctrine the court has, they think the regulator is right. You have to prove the regulator is wrong--it is like being assumed guilty and you have to prove your innocence, and that is very hard to do. Mr. Davidson. This is fundamentally a consequence of the Chevron doctrine. Mr. Allison. Yes. Ms. Peirce. A lot of the regulation is not even being done through rules that could be challenged in court. It is being done through supervision, which is a big problem in the bank regulation side. Mr. Barr. I think if you look by contrast at the way in which the court system has actually gotten involved in Dodd- Frank compliance issues, it has been quite extensive. The fact of the matter is, in the PHH against CFPB case, which is challenging its constitutionality, that is a case involving whether the CFPB followed proper procedure with respect to its internal operations. And the court seemed quite aggressive about enforcing that. I think you can see it in the MetLife case, you can see it in the case brought against the SEC. Ms. Peirce. But I-- Mr. Davidson. I want to highlight--this is pretty late in the game and fairly consequential. If you look at PHH, look at the valuation of their company and what happened, they have been decimated basically by fiat. Mr. Barr. I think if you look at the way in which the court system is overseeing-- Ms. Peirce. I would also-- Mr. Barr. --agencies, it is quite-- Mr. Davidson. Ms. Peirce, would you please? Ms. Peirce. So I would say that it is fine to cite PHH and MetLife, but those are the two companies that were able to fight because they had the resources and the courage to do so. But often it is just not worth the regulatory risk to take the fight to court. So you just suffer with the consequences. Mr. Davidson. Thank you for pointing that out. I think we are at about a 90 percent conviction rate, which is a little shocking. It basically says, yes, cave or else. Dr. Michel, were you going to say something? Mr. Michel. I was just going to add Allied to that equation. It is an example of just kind of giving up and going ahead. You have no reason, you have no contact with the borrower at all, and you are accused of racial discrimination, and you know that the race of the borrower was never even-- Mr. Davidson. Particularly when automotive lenders were explicitly excluded, carved out-- Mr. Michel. And you still find yourself with the choice of going to court or settling to get this over with. Mr. Davidson. Thank you all. Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Tennessee, Mr. Kustoff. Mr. Kustoff. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you all for being here today. Since the enactment of Dodd-Frank almost 6, 7 years ago, to me it is incredible that we have had very few new banking starts in this country. Mr. Allison, if I could, with your banking experience could you talk from a practical and procedural standpoint. Today, if you wanted to start a new bank, which I can tell from your expression that you are not particularly interested in doing, what are the real-world hurdles and challenges that Dodd-Frank presents to somebody who would want to start a new bank today? Mr. Allison. First, the biggest challenge is that regulators don't want you to start a bank. So they are going to come up with every obstacle they can dream of to start a bank. And secondly, when you do your cost analysis and your profit analysis, you are going to say, I can't make any money because I am going to have to hire an army of compliance people before I can make my first loan. So I am going to be embedded with a cost structure radically higher than a traditional community bank startup has. This is very interesting. The ability to sell your bank, it sounds like that will consolidate the industry. But actually, it encourages startups because a lot of banks are built to run for 25 or 30 years, kind of the life expectancy of the board and the management, and then to be sold. So the fact we have made it hard for people to sell their banks, ironically, has not kept banks from being sold. It has kept banks from being started because that is the payback. I can't get a high enough return in the short term, but 10 or 15 or 20 years from now I will be able to sell the bank, and that is kind of when my management talent is going to run out and I am not going to be able to hire enough people to replace me. That is the mindset. Mr. Kustoff. The converse: Let's assume that we get the CHOICE Act passed in toto, the way that it is written now. Can you predict what that would do for new bank starts in this country? Mr. Allison. I would predict a significant increase in the number of new bank starts. Pretty radical, because all they have to meet is the 10 percent equity requirement, which is really not that hard, and then they will have the option in the future if they do well to sell it. And that is kind of the carrot out there so I think you will see a significant increase in the number of startups. And I think that will be good for the economy. Mr. Kustoff. Thank you, Mr. Allison. Dr. Michel, you and I had the opportunity I believe to talk earlier at our subcommittee hearing. I do want to ask you if I could about the CFPB for a moment and the consumer complaint database, if we could. The way I understand it is, when complaints are submitted to the database, we have seen that the facts are not verified. In other words, the complaints are submitted, but there is no verification. So somebody could submit a complaint. It may be valid; it may not be valid; or it may be partially valid. Could you talk about how the CFPB could ensure the validity of these claims before they are submitted and placed in the public domain? Mr. Michel. Sure. Just find out what happened before you put it on the public database. The FTC has a similar model, where those things are kept internally and they verify the complaints internally. This isn't supposed to be about public shaming and finding out later, oh, we made a mistake. What purpose does that serve if we are talking about protecting people? Mr. Kustoff. And following up on that, do you believe or have an opinion as to whether the CFPB should remove these complaints from the public domain rather than keep the database as is? Mr. Michel. Sure. Again, I don't see any public purpose to having all of that raw complaint information public because it is counterproductive. Mr. Kustoff. How would the CFPB go about verifying these complaints once they are submitted? Mr. Michel. If we have a Federal agency that is an enforcement agency and they are doing their job, when they receive a complaint, they check it out. They verify it. They talk to the person who filed the complaint, they talk to the company that the complaint is filed against, and they go and actually investigate what happened. I don't think anybody would have a problem with that. Mr. Kustoff. Do you have any idea how many complaints have been submitted to the CFPB? Mr. Michel. I have not looked lately. I know that it was millions at some point. I don't know--I could not give you a number now, no. I have not looked lately. Mr. Kustoff. And again, none of those complaints have been verified. They are submitted-- Mr. Michel. They were simply submitted raw complaint data, yes. And I don't have the error rate off the top of my head either, but I know that they have made some statements about how many of those were not actually verified complaints. Mr. Kustoff. Thank you, Dr. Michel. I yield back my time. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Ms. Tenney. Ms. Tenney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, panel, for a great discussion. I come from a very rural area in central New York, where we had wonderful old names of old community banks--United National, Savings Bank of Utica, Homestead Savings, Herkimer County Trust, Marine Midland Bank, which was a little bit larger bank. All those have gone. We do have one solid community bank left called the Bank of Utica, and we have a, well, a regional bank called Adirondack Bank. But so many of these regulations have caused us to lose our banks. In fact, there haven't been any new banks created, de novo banks created in New York State since Dodd-Frank was passed. My concern as a small business owner who has relied on many of these great relationships--I know some of you mentioned character lending--throughout the years, and honestly, I can go into my bank and hand my checkbook to the teller and go back and talk to the bank president, who is in the same room. And I know that is a quaint situation that doesn't happen often. And these banks, some have been excluded from regulation, but many of them can't even compete in the big market because they don't have the compliance. And I think Ms. Peirce mentioned really significant, so many of them just either stop lending to their customers, force their customers into having second mortgages or putting themselves into credit cards to get financing because they don't want to face litigation. And it is so expensive. They can't afford the compliance cost. It is a very similar situation as it is for us as a small business owner in the area. I just thought what I would like to do is talk to you about the ability of a regulator to--and for us to look at sort of Chevron that was referenced by my colleague, with the over- expansion of the Executive Branch and how Dodd-Frank has caused over 400 different rules just to implement it, and thousands of pages, 2,300 pages or whatever it is. And how we can roll that back and come up with a way, using economic factors, to put some restraints on regulators. I would love to know if you could just comment on that, Mr. Michel, start first and we will work the panel. Because to me I think that is really where we are going with this. The regulations have proven to be so much burden for-- Mr. Michel. I know this isn't on the table at the moment, but I am not a fan of independent regulatory agencies. I think that is a problem. You are supposed to be accountable to the people who have been elected, and there should be more direct rules that come directly from Congress and there shouldn't be so much discretion. And that would be one way against that. Passing a law that gives the regulator a great deal of discretion to come up with a rule, and it ends up looking almost nothing like what was initially discussed, is incredibly poor policy. So not having those independent agencies with the ability to do that is a way around that. And I think with the CHOICE Act, you can play around with the model that is here, you have a much higher equity requirement with a much bigger regulatory relief component and that way get away from doing some of these things. Ms. Tenney. Thank you. Mr. Pollock, do you have a comment on that? Mr. Pollock. Congresswoman, first I would like to say on the small banks going down in number, which they obviously are, one of the reasons is that there are few new banks being created. We ought to have as a policy at all times the encouragement of new capacity and new entrants, which we don't have. Especially in times of trouble, when you most need new entrants, the regulatory philosophy is to cut off new entrants. On the general question of more accountability in regulatory activity, it is essential, in my opinion, for the cost of the regulation and the effects, as we have been discussing, of the regulation to be explicitly taken into account and compared to whatever benefits we think there are. On mortgage loans in particular, we have had very heavy regulatory and legal risks imposed, and the result is for little banks, talking about less than a billion dollars in assets, mortgage loans in those banks have been falling since 2011. Anybody who has tried to get a mortgage knows why. The regulations have made it extremely painful, even for quite good credits, to go through the process. Ms. Tenney. Yes, thank you. I appreciate that. As a former bank attorney, I used to be able to do maybe 10, 15 residential closings a day. I could probably only do three now just because of burdensome paperwork. And again, I know Mr. Barr is anxious to answer, but I think I am losing my time here, so I want to say thank you to the panel for really great work today. It is really an honor to have you here and talk about the CHOICE Act. And we are excited about getting it passed. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Indiana, Mr. Hollingsworth. Mr. Hollingsworth. Good afternoon. Thanks so much for being here. As she said, I really appreciate everybody's investment of time and all the great comments and conversation that we have had. There has been a lot of discussion throughout the course of the day about banks taking exceptional risk inside their trading book that has caused losses that have been covered by the taxpayer and that is why we need the Volcker Rule. Dr. Michel, would you care to comment on that and whether the true issue that caused the crisis was in the trading book or was it in the loan book? Mr. Michel. I would love to comment on that. Thank you. So first of all, this started off in the wholesale trading market--or I'm sorry, the wholesale funding market, so this has nothing to do with the banks really in that sense at all. Secondly, if we are talking about risk, banks take risks every day. Commercial loans are risky. A portfolio of commercial loans is riskier than a commercial portfolio of stocks. This makes no sense at all. Prior to Dodd-Frank, you had the Fed, the FDIC, and the OCC with all the ability in the world to stop any of those large banks from trading, doing proprietary trading, doing any of the securities investment that they wanted. Type I securities, Type II securities, Type III, all of these things are codified. This is the biggest nothing burger ever. This is just a waste of time, effort, energy, and money, period. Mr. Hollingsworth. Excellent. Thank you. Thank you for that. One of the things I also wanted to talk about, Dr. Cook, you had mentioned earlier today and talked about--gave a great, stirring introduction about how this will never happen again and how we made sure that this will never happen again. I guess my question is, does Dodd-Frank slaughter the business cycle? Do we expect that we will never have another downturn again now? Ms. Cook. Excuse me. I didn't go that far. Mr. Hollingsworth. I got a ``C'' in macro-economics, by the way. Ms. Cook. Wait, wait, let me be clear. To try to stem the irresponsible practices that were happening before. But I just want to be careful, as was stated in my prepared remarks, this is not perfect. Dodd-Frank is not perfect. Mr. Hollingsworth. I guess in that--I think what you were trying to get at was not that we slaughter the business cycle but hopefully we can dampen the amplitude of the ups and downs. Is that kind of what you were trying to convey in your introduction? Ms. Cook. No. Still focused on financial practices. Now we keep working as macro-economists on trying to--and we thought we had it figured out before the recent crisis. Mr. Hollingsworth. Can you determine what is irresponsible and what is responsible behavior? Who gets to determine that? Ms. Cook. So the Federal Reserve, all of the regulators can. Mr. Hollingsworth. So regulators determine what is responsible and irresponsible lending. So this is really--and Dodd-Frank is government pushing capital in certain directions and out of other directions, and determining who should be the recipients of loans and who shouldn't be the recipients of loans. So government-directed capital is the answer to the crisis in your mind? Ms. Cook. Oh, not at all. No, no. Mr. Hollingsworth. More regulation is not more government direction of capital? Ms. Cook. No, I want to be clear. When I say irresponsible, I don't mean it as--you are making it as a technical term. I want to make sure that I am saying this because it is not--this isn't something that a standard, that you are looking at a banking law and saying, this is responsible, or these are the characteristics, these are the criteria for responsible and irresponsible banking. But I want to make sure that we understand that the crises, the recessions that are the deepest we know from economic research are the ones that are fueled by bad financial practices, by financial crises. That is what I don't want to see happen again. The Great Depression, this Great Recession, and what is happening in Europe, we certainly don't want that to happen again. Mr. Hollingsworth. I guess back to Dr. Michel, I wanted to talk a little bit about Title VII and better understanding how Title VII might certainly, under Dodd-Frank, begin to change the way clearinghouses are structured and offer them with Title VIII some additional avenues. Can you talk a little bit about that? Mr. Michel. So on VII, with the clearing mandate, I would go back to--this isn't quite as--maybe I don't have as strong feelings as I do on Volcker, but this is another one that is a really bad idea. If counterparties wanted to have these derivatives cleared and clearinghouses wanted to clear these things, that was already happening. Mr. Hollingsworth. Right. Mr. Michel. And that is a progressive thing over time. As those things become more standardized and more accepted, that is what happens. To mandate it is a very bad idea and we end up concentrating all the risk in the clearinghouses. Mr. Hollingsworth. Exactly. Mr. Michel. And then Title VIII, and say, here you have a direct line to the Fed. Mr. Hollingsworth. We have just basically opened another avenue towards more bailouts and more opportunities for bailouts through Dodd-Frank. Mr. Michel. Absolutely. Mr. Hollingsworth. Instead of how it was sold originally. Mr. Michel. Absolutely. Mr. Hollingsworth. Thank you. I appreciate the time, and I appreciate all of you today. Mr. Michel. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New Jersey, Mr. Gottheimer. Mr. Gottheimer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you to the panel for being here today. If I could start with you, Mr. Allison. With the benefit of almost 7 years of experience now we can only identify areas where Dodd-Frank could be improved without compromising the core regulatory framework that has been put in place. One such area for potential improvement is Section 619 of Dodd-Frank that inhibited speculative investments. Former Fed Governor Tarullo highlighted this in his parting remarks earlier in April. What do you think of his assessment, and what are some of the tweaks that could be made to keep our regulations smart but also keep our regulators adequately focused on protecting the safety and soundness of the banks and consumers? Mr. Allison. I think you have to look at a bank at a meta- level, not at the parts. And regulators, Governor Tarullo in particular, likes to look at the parts. And I think that is a poor way to do it. If you look at the Canadian banking system, their regulators evaluate the whole organization and they have had much smaller, lower failure rates than we have. I think our kind of regulation tends to focus on these little parts and add them together instead of asking the macro questions, including the basic philosophy of the bank. Is it a high risk taker or not? Mr. Gottheimer. Thank you very much. I appreciate that. Related to that, Section 619 requires that five regulatory agencies examine traders' intent to effectuate the rule of prohibitions. Is that inherently difficult for regulators and the banks? Mr. Allison. I would say so. I don't think they have the skill set to do it, would be my view. Mr. Gottheimer. Thank you very much. Mr. Barr, do you think the OCC's failure to sufficiently address Wells Fargo's bad sales practices more than a decade ago shows that the agency may have been putting its consumer protection mission in a subordinate role to its other mission of improving the profitability of the bank? Mr. Barr. I do think that the failure was rather significant, and it was one of the reasons--the basic problem of the lack of prudential agencies' attention to consumer issues was one of the main reasons for bringing those authorities together under the new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau. I think the recent report on Wells Fargo reinforces that it was a good idea to bring those authorities together under the CFPB, to give it the power to protect American families and to really have as a core mission and a set of expertise protection of consumers. So I think it reinforces the choice made in Dodd-Frank and frankly undermines the choice made in the CHOICE Act. Mr. Gottheimer. So you would say what happened with the big account scandal, it is what the mission of the CFPB, it meets its mission in that case. Mr. Barr. Yes, I do think you want a consumer agency that can stop the kind of abuses we saw at Wells Fargo and at payday lenders and in other markets, where there have been significant problems with taking advantage of consumers repeatedly over time. I think that is one of the core reasons you need the consumer agency to have supervisory power and not take it away, as the CHOICE Act would do. So I think having an agency that has supervisory authority and rule-writing authority, and enforcement authority across the market is really important to creating a level playing field for consumers and for banks and non-banks alike. Mr. Gottheimer. Thank you so much. I yield the balance of my time. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Trott. Mr. Trott. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Dr. Michel, let's talk about Title II of Dodd-Frank. Some of my friends today have offered a couple of arguments as to why OLA is better than a bankruptcy solution. First, they have suggested that the FDIC has it covered. There is no need to worry about taxpayers being at risk again. And the second argument is that the FDIC will do a better job than a bankruptcy judge at resolving a failed financial institution. So let's look at the first argument. How has the government done at maintaining insurance programs and ensuring they are solvent in the event of a claim? For example, how have they done on the National Flood Insurance Program? I think it is $24 billion in the hole. How have they done on the Pension Guarantee Corporation? I think it is $79 billion in the hole. Or for that matter, how have they done on FHA? So do you think, based on the government's track record, that they are going to do a good job at making sure the FDIC has the money in the event of a failure? Mr. Michel. Do I think so? Mr. Trott. Yes. Mr. Michel. No. Mr. Trott. Well, let's assume that the examples I just gave--yes? Mr. Michel. I was going to say, I would throw in the FSLIC, back from the S&L crisis, and then I would throw in the FDIC from the recent crisis because without TARP you have an FDIC bailout. But I'm sorry, go ahead. Mr. Trott. I only have 5 minutes. Mr. Michel. I'm sorry. Mr. Trott. Just kidding. So let's assume all these examples are just an aberration though, and that the orderly liquidation fund is adequate to cover a failure of the top 6 financial institutions, which would total about $10 trillion. So taxpayers might not be funding that if the money is there, but indirectly wouldn't consumers still have to pay a price because all the healthy financial institutions have to pay for the failure of their competitors, and ultimately that cost is going to be passed on to consumers in higher fees? Mr. Michel. That is exactly right. These assessment fees, somebody pays for those, and ultimately customers pay for at least a part of those. Mr. Trott. Let's assume that they don't have the money, so they can go under section 210 and borrow $10 trillion from the Treasury. Would you agree that at that point taxpayers are in the crosshairs again? Mr. Michel. Very much so. Mr. Trott. So indirectly or directly, the first argument fails because taxpayers are going to be exposed. Let's look at the second argument. So the FDIC is going to do a better job than a bankruptcy judge, so these--because they have more knowledge and experience. So these are the same folks who were in charge before the last crisis, right? Mr. Michel. That is correct. Mr. Trott. But now they are all a whole lot smarter. Let's look at transparency. Let's compare the FDIC folks sitting in a closed room versus a bankruptcy judge sitting in an open court. Which is going to be more transparent and lead to a fairer result? Mr. Michel. I would go with the open court. Mr. Trott. Oh, you are answering all the questions right. It is really something. Let's talk about predictability. So you have a bankruptcy judge who has years of precedent, case law, previous decisions, and attorneys, creditors, and shareholders can look at that. Which is going to lead to a more predictable result, a bankruptcy court that has years of precedent, or the FDIC, that every now and then has to deal with a financial institution that fails? Mr. Michel. Bankruptcy court, again. Mr. Trott. I spent a lot of time in my previous career in bankruptcy court representing creditors, and by and large my clients thought it was a fair, predictable, transparent result. But a lot of times they didn't really like the result because a lot of times they didn't get any money. Sometimes there was no money in the bankrupt estate for them, or they were deemed to be unsecured creditors. Sometimes the money given to them was deemed to be a fraudulent transfer or a preference. But that risk in the bankruptcy proceeding kept some integrity in the process. So my question is, don't you think having a bankruptcy process where creditors and shareholders are at risk versus the taxpayers is going to lead to a better decision-making process at the banks and financial institutions because of the threat of the bankruptcy court giving them zero? Mr. Michel. Yes. I don't see how there can be any doubt, honestly. And I hear the criticism that, well, if we do that, you won't have as many of these repos and you won't have as many of this broad money, as much of this broad money. I am kind of flabbergasted because that is exactly the point. Mr. Trott. It is kind of like the bond ratings for Fannie and Freddie's mortgages, isn't it? Mr. Michel. Yes. Mr. Trott. Thank you. Mr. Allison, I really enjoyed your opening statement. I thought your comments and perspective, the real-world perspective was refreshing. My only caution it is probably too much common sense for us here in Washington, but it was certainly interesting to hear your comments. And I am going to put up on the screen, if it is here somewhere, I would appreciate the staff helping me out. That is a puzzle of all the different regulations that affect financial institutions. So I want you to just to comment in the 30 seconds I have left, what all those regulations have done to the banking industry, which in turn what that has done to the small business community, which in turn what it has done to what we all care about most here. Democrats or Republicans alike agree on one thing. We all would like to see more jobs created in this country. What has that done to job creation in this country? Mr. Allison. It has made banks less efficient, it has made them less able to provide the credit that drives the economy. It has reduced innovation, creativity, and it has made a lot less good jobs. It has reduced the number of good jobs in America. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair wishes to advise all Members that votes are pending on the Floor. We have two Members remaining in the queue. Without objection, the remaining two Members will be afforded 3 minutes apiece. The gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Budd, is now recognized for 3 minutes. Mr. Budd. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And Dr. Michel, let's talk about price controls, which are put into place on the theory or belief that the market for a good or service just isn't working. So we have a long history of trying to do that in our country. Mr. Michel. Indeed. Mr. Budd. Nixon tried that in 1971, Carter in 1980. And if you look at it recently outside of our country, the Venezuelan food prices controls, they were unsuccessful and are unsuccessful. So Dr. Michel, is the Durbin Amendment, which is a price cap, is it helping the American public or is it failing like these other attempts? Mr. Michel. It is failing like other price controls always do. Somebody finds a way around it, somebody finds another way to get the money that they lose from the price control. And we see that already. It ends up not helping the people it supposedly is going to help. Not that I believe that, that they really wanted to help the people they say. Mr. Budd. So about those people that we are talking about, the consumers. Mr. Michel. Yes. Mr. Budd. In terms of the effect on their pocketbooks, the Richmond Fed has said that a sizable fraction of merchants raise their prices or debit restrictions as their cost of accepting these debit cards increase. However, few merchants reduce prices or debit restrictions as these costs decrease. So take ideology out and history out just for a second. The bottom line, the practical cost of the Durbin Amendment price control is that consumer pocketbooks, these people we are talking about, are you saying they have been hurt in terms of increased banking costs? And they haven't seen any other relief in prices. Is that correct? Mr. Michel. The evidence ranges from unaffected to harmed. Yes, that is correct. Mr. Budd. So these that we are supposed to help, these consumers, but it didn't, why is that? Mr. Michel. The idea that we were going to get rid of a regulation for a small group of large retailers, and those retailers were going to just pass that cost directly back, cost savings directly back to their consumers is fantasy. And then there would be no other impact, with nobody who has lost the revenue trying to pick it up from somewhere else. It is not practical. Mr. Budd. Mr. Allison, so from my hometown, you mentioned something about at the end of the day, somebody pays. Would you care to reiterate on that? Mr. Allison. The Durbin Amendment has been particularly bad for low-income consumers. Banks were providing free checking accounts. The way they were doing that was with debit card fees that merchants were paying. The Durbin Amendment is a huge subsidy for big merchants, for Walmart at the expense of low- income consumers. The low-income consumers are the big losers. Now the way the banks have been hurt, banks invested billions of dollars to develop the technology to make this system work. Banks have lost part of the incentives of technology for new things that consumers might benefit because it might be stolen by legislation. Price controls never work. Mr. Budd. Thank you. In my remaining time, a quick question. So have the prices for merchants that do a lot of small ticket items-- Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from West Virginia, Mr. Mooney, for 3 minutes. Mr. Mooney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Recently, proponents of the Dodd-Frank Act have rolled out numerous anecdotes and favorable data to prove that with Dodd-Frank in place the economy is growing, banks are both profitable and lending. But what you don't hear about is the overall regulatory costs imposed by Dodd-Frank that are weighing down our economy. A current analysis by the American Action Forum found that compliance with the Dodd-Frank Act has cost $36 billion and 73 million hours of paperwork, the equivalent of almost 37,000 employees working full-time on paperwork for 1 year. As I travel my district in West Virginia, with small community banks and small towns, the pain that I hear from folks who work at banks that they have to hire full-time employees just to do paperwork and pay them salaries, money that could otherwise have been lent to buy a home or start the American dream of owning your own business is evident. So Dr. Michel, has Dodd-Frank helped ``lift the economy'' since it was enacted in 2010? Mr. Michel. No, and I wouldn't have believed that to begin with. We have done some analysis. We have done, as far as I can tell, one of the first real macro economic modeling analyses of this very question. And we do show that it had a significant impact, I think I mentioned before of about 1 percent per year in GDP. That would be the loss associated with the increased costs. That would be the gain from removing it. You have a significant decrease to the capital stock in the Nation. And there is a dynamic effect on that in terms of the revenue effect that we have on the budget and just on the economy in general. Mr. Mooney. Thank you. A quick follow up, what have been the macro economic impacts of the hundreds of new regulations imposed by the Dodd-Frank Act? Mr. Michel. Unfortunately, the part that we do is very narrow. Or I shouldn't say unfortunately, but I should say that the part that we looked at was a very narrow look. So I would imagine it is much worse. I don't have the macro analysis because I can't--it is almost intractable, the problem. We are talking about over 400 rules, we are talking about rules that span the entire financial spectrum. Macro economic models can't really handle a lot of that stuff very easily, so you have to start doing a lot of subjective manipulation, I will call it, and we didn't want to get into that. So I suspect that it is pretty severe. I would add that a lot of the stuff where everybody talks about how we have had the worst recession since the Great Depression, well, yes, and a lot of that actually happened after we started doing all of this stuff. So that doesn't get a pass. Mr. Mooney. Thank you. Thank you all for your testimony today. Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. I want to thank our witnesses for their testimony today. The Chair notes that some Members may have additional questions for this panel, which they may wish to submit in writing. Without objection, the hearing record will remain open for 5 legislative days for Members to submit written questions to these witnesses and to place their responses in the record. Also, without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit extraneous materials to the Chair for inclusion in the record. I ask our witnesses to please respond as promptly as they are able. This hearing stands adjourned. [Whereupon, at 3:06 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X April 26, 2017 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]