[House Hearing, 115 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] SUSTAINABLE HOUSING FINANCE, PART III ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON HOUSING AND INSURANCE OF THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ NOVEMBER 7, 2017 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 115-55 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] _________ U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE 30-774 PDF WASHINGTON : 2018 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina, MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking Vice Chairman Member PETER T. KING, New York CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma BRAD SHERMAN, California STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York BILL POSEY, Florida MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin DAVID SCOTT, Georgia STEVE STIVERS, Ohio AL GREEN, Texas RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota ANN WAGNER, Missouri ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado ANDY BARR, Kentucky JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania BILL FOSTER, Illinois LUKE MESSER, Indiana DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona BRUCE POLIQUIN, Maine JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio MIA LOVE, Utah DENNY HECK, Washington FRENCH HILL, Arkansas JUAN VARGAS, California TOM EMMER, Minnesota JOSH GOTTHEIMER, New Jersey LEE M. ZELDIN, New York VICENTE GONZALEZ, Texas DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan CHARLIE CRIST, Florida BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia RUBEN KIHUEN, Nevada ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia THOMAS MacARTHUR, New Jersey WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio TED BUDD, North Carolina DAVID KUSTOFF, Tennessee CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana Kirsten Sutton Mork, Staff Director Subcommittee on Housing and Insurance SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin, Chairman DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida, Vice EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri, Ranking Chairman Member EDWARD R. ROYCE, California NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts BILL POSEY, Florida WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri BRAD SHERMAN, California STEVE STIVERS, Ohio STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan LEE M. ZELDIN, New York JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan RUBEN KIHUEN, Nevada THOMAS MacARTHUR, New Jersey TED BUDD, North Carolina C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: November 7, 2017............................................. 1 Appendix: November 7, 2017............................................. 43 WITNESSES Tuesday, November 7, 2017 Lea, Michael, Cardiff Consulting Services........................ 8 McCargo, Alanna, Co-director, Housing Finance Policy Center, Urban Institute................................................ 10 Tozer, Hon. Theodore ``Ted'', Senior Fellow, Center for Financial Markets, Milken Institute...................................... 12 Wallison, Peter, Senior Fellow and Arthur F. Burns Fellow in Financial Policy Studies, American Enterprise Institute........ 5 Zandi, Mark, Chief Economist, Moody's Analytics.................. 6 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Lea, Michael................................................. 44 McCargo, Alanna.............................................. 103 Tozer, Hon. Theodore ``Ted''................................. 122 Wallison, Peter.............................................. 132 Zandi, Mark.................................................. 145 Additional Material Submitted for the Record Beatty, Hon. Joyce: Article from Politico Pro entitled, ``Tax Plan Would Cut Affordable Housing Supply by 60 percent''.................. 154 Zandi, Mark: Written responses to questions for the record submitted by Representative Sherman..................................... 155 SUSTAINABLE HOUSING FINANCE, PART III ---------- Tuesday, November 7, 2017 U.S. House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Housing and Insurance, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The Housing and Insurance Subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:05 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Sean Duffy [chairman of the subcommittee] presiding. Present: Representatives Duffy, Ross, Royce, Posey, Luetkemeyer, Stivers, Hultgren, Rothfus, Zeldin, Trott, MacArthur, Budd, Cleaver, Capuano, Sherman, Beatty, and Kildee. Also present: Representative Green. Chairman Duffy. The Subcommittee on Housing and Insurance will come to order. Today's hearing is entitled ``Sustainable Housing Finance, Part Three.'' We have already had two hearings. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess of the subcommittee meeting at any time. Without objection, members of the full committee who are not members of this subcommittee, may participate in today's hearing for the purpose of making an opening statement and questioning our witnesses. The Chair now recognizes himself for 3 minutes. I first want to thank the panel, our distinguished panel, for coming in today and offering their insights into housing finance. We have already heard from stakeholders that represent several aspects of the housing finance system. We have heard from those who finance purchases of homes, those who build homes and those who help sellers and buyers meet for that buyer's slice of the American dream. And before us, we have those who have done extensive work in this space, have policy ideas, probably have some recommendations for the must do's and must don'ts for this committee, and I look forward to all of your testimony as you advise our committee. But for us, we recognize that the home purchase, is probably one of the largest, biggest financial and most important decisions that a person makes. Probably besides what ring you buy and who you decide to marry, this is the biggest decision that you will make in your financial life. And making sure that we have a system that actually works for all Americans is incredibly important because we have seen when things go wrong--back in 2008. It doesn't only impact those who purchased a home. It wreaks havoc throughout the whole economy. People in the industries that involve home purchases and home sales, they get ravaged. We have heard from many of those sectors where many of their colleagues and friends have lost their jobs. We have seen what it does to an economy as a whole. But what we are focused on is what it does to actual home buyers, people who purchased homes and couldn't afford them, how that devastated their financial future, crushed their families. We don't want that to happen again. And make no mistake that we are, what, almost 10 years on from the crisis, reforming housing finance is not easy. If we thought tax reform was tough, as we have seen right now play out in the House, housing finance I think is equally as challenging. And I think after the crisis that there has been no reform in this space is unacceptable. I think we have an opportunity to work across party lines to get an American solution to housing finance. We want to make sure we bring in more private capital. We want to bring in more market discipline. We want to make sure people can still get a mortgage that they can afford. Some might argue that should be a 10-year mortgage. Some are going to argue for a 30-year mortgage. But what we want to do is have a system that works for homeowners to get their slice of the American dream and the American experience, which is home ownership. So as we look to all of you, I don't know if we want to classify you as think tank world, but those of you who have worked on policy for a very long time, to give us your insight into the opportunity that presents itself to us today, and again, the advice that you have on how we can make the system work better for the American family. With that my time has expired. I now recognize the gentleman from Missouri, the Ranking Member, Mr. Cleaver for 5 minutes. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you Mr. Chairman. Let me thank all of you for being here today. This is our third in a series of housing finance reform hearings, which I hope you and others realize that because we are going through the third hearing that we are serious about trying to do something that would keep our mortgage financing system functioning at a high level or higher than it is now. And so over the last few weeks we have had the opportunity to hear numerous stakeholders regarding their suggestions and proposals for housing finance reform. At these previous hearings there has been a general consensus that housing finance reform must preserve the 30-year fixed mortgage by including explicit government guarantee. And I believe this is an essential component of our conversation. As I have mentioned in the past, housing affordability must also remain at the forefront of this discussion. Homeownership rates have been in decline, especially among minority populations where families have yet to recover from the financial crisis. The path toward GSE (Government Sponsored Enterprise) reform must include a very strong plan to make homeownership options more available for qualified borrowers and to address the rental affordability crises. Our discussion on housing finance reform should not take place in a vacuum. Currently, the Ways and Means Committee has been marking up the tax plan put forth by the majority that would make changes to the mortgage interest deduction. Specifically that bill would cap deductions for mortgages on new homes over $500,000, which is an issue we will get into a little later. But a number of groups have already raised concerns that this change could have a detrimental impact, not only on the housing market, but on the middle class. Home ownership is one of our most important tools for households to accrue wealth, and we should be concerned with proposals that would make this more difficult. And so as our witnesses today, you may have a variety of proposals that can solve this problem today. We can solve it before we have the recess with the members of the housing intellegencia here. There is no question in my mind that you have the solution. We want you to give it to us before noon. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the Vice Chair of this committee, the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Ross, for 2 minutes. Mr. Ross. Thank you Chairman, and I thank the witnesses again for being here. The Federal Government's involvement in housing finance is predicated on the idea that it is not only helpful but it is also necessary. Take a working class family, folks who are scraping by with a modest income, they are deciding that it would be best to purchase a home rather than to continue to pay rent. How are we helping that family? Reasonable people will disagree, but what is most striking to me is that we don't ask a different question. Is it possible that we are hurting that family? Let us recognize that a family may not be able to afford a home. The prices may be too high and the family's income may not rise with those prices. So the Federal Government says don't worry. We will make you a loan. This will be easy. We already know that the family can't afford the home. That loan isn't a loan, it is an albatross. It is a moral hazard. We are inducing them to take on a risk that is unsustainable. Yet time and again we do it. Why? Because we are told we are trying to broaden access to home ownership and to achieve wealth accumulation for low and moderate income home owners. That was the argument made during the three decades between 1964 and 1995, during which home ownership remained relatively static despite government intervention. Perhaps we just need to try harder. Actually we did. The following 10 years saw an aggressive increase in the Federal Government's efforts to support homeownership for low and moderate income families. We placed mandates on the GSEs, first requiring that 30 percent of all mortgages they acquired be ones made to borrowers below medium income. From 1996 on, we continued to increase the artificial ratio, until 2008 it reached 56 percent. And for a brief moment, home ownership reached new heights of 70 percent. Then came the crash and now we are at 63.9 percent. And for those at home keeping score, that is just under where we started when we kicked off this project of increasing taxpayer exposure to risky lending. With little to show for it, this project has taken on enormous costs, not just to taxpayers but through bailouts. For that family I mentioned earlier, the system has raised prices and reduced affordability of homes. The entire point was to help that family purchase a home. We have harmed it. The entire point was to help families keep their homes. I am afraid the current system makes that even harder. Let us find a better way. Thank you, and I yield back. Chairman. Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman, for 2 minutes. Mr. Sherman. As I think the other hearings have established, we need a government agency to provide the guarantee if we are going to have 30-year fixed rate mortgages available to regular working families in the United States. We had a bad program about a decade ago where we had entities that had an implicit Federal guarantee, but were private companies seeking private profit--socialized the risk, privatized the profit. We have now a much better system where we basically have government entities, and these government entities are not losing money for the Federal Government. They are, in fact, making money for the Federal Government. We are also dealing with the tax cut. Up at the board we have behind the witnesses, the total national debt. That clock will be going much more quickly if we pass $1.5 billion in tax cuts. I should point out that this tax bill will certainly make it more difficult for Fannie and Freddie because, as I think our witnesses have written, this is going to adversely affect home prices, particularly in high cost areas where homes could sell for $500,000, $600,000, $700,000. In addition, we are talking about a larger national debt, which will cause the fed to give us higher interest rates, again, making it tougher for Fannie and Freddie and the home market in general. So I realize that the jurisdiction of this committee is on housing finance, but our purpose is to make sure that homes are affordable on the one hand and that people who have their nest egg invested in their homes do not see that wiped out on the other. And the tax bill, as well as some of the issues before us, pose real risks to that average homeowner and that average home buyer. I yield back. Chairman. Duffy. The gentleman yields back. We now welcome and recognize our panel of witnesses. First we have Peter Wallison, a Senior Fellow and Arthur F. Burns Fellow in Financial Policy at the American Enterprise Institute. We next have Dr. Mark Zandi, Chief Economist at Moody's Analytics. Third witness, Dr. Lea, is Principal of Cardiff Consulting Services. Next we have Ms. McCargo, Co-director of Housing Finance Policy Center for the Urban Institute. And finally, we have Mr. Ted Tozer, Senior Fellow for the Center for Financial Markets at the Milken Institute. In a moment, the witnesses will be recognized for 5 minutes to give an oral presentation of their written testimony. Without objection, the witnesses' written statements will be made part of the record following remarks. Once the witnesses have finished presenting the testimony, each member of the subcommittee will have 5 minutes within which to ask the panel questions. On your table, most of you all know this, but you have three lights. Green light means go, yellow light means you have a minute left and the red light means that your time is up. The microphones are sensitive so please speak directly into them. And with that, Mr. Wallison, you are now recognized for 5 minutes. STATEMENT OF PETER WALLISON Mr. Wallison. Thank very much, Chairman Duffy and Ranking Member Cleaver. Thank you for this opportunity to testify on housing policy reform. My view, as detailed in my written testimony, is that the best U.S. housing policy in the future would eliminate the Government role in housing finance, beginning with the GSEs. I take this position for the following reasons. First the GSEs do not reduce interest rates. Our analysis at AEI (American Enterprise Institute) shows that since 2014, after controlling for mortgage interest characteristics, the private market, primarily banks, has been offering mortgages with lower interest rates than the GSEs. In addition, the private sector mortgages we compared to GS mortgages with 30-year fixed rate loans, which are readily available from private sector lenders without a government guarantee. Many Members of Congress have been told for years that there would be no 30-year fixed rate mortgages without government backing. But our research shows that this is false. Second, the GSEs' lending policy increases housing prices, making homes less affordable. Mortgage interest standards, not interest rates, are the key to housing prices. Today the GSEs are willing to acquire mortgages with 3 percent down payments or less, so the buyer will be buying 97 percent of the price of the home. What this really means is that the buyer reaches for the most expensive house that the loan puts within reach. This exerts strong upward pressure on home prices, which are now again rising faster than wages. This particularly hurts first time homebuyers. Third, GSEs do very little to help low and moderate income families buy homes. I think everyone would agree that if any families need help to buy homes, it would be families taking out loans for less than $250,000. Half of these households have estimated income below $66,000, which is 120 percent of the U.S. median income, yet, only 11 percent of the GSEs' activities are helping these families buy homes. An additional 27 percent of GSE activities are home purchase loans greater than $250,000 with a median borrower income of $122,000. These loans could easily be made by the private sector, especially when the GSEs, as noted above, do not reduce interest rates. The rest of the GSEs' activities, about 60 percent, is refinancing old mortgages, financing second homes and financing investor purchases of houses for rental. None of this contributes to home ownership by families that want to buy a first home. Fourth, the GSEs cost the treasury billions of dollars each year. The GSEs and their supporters often argue that because many investors, including foreign central banks, are required to invest only in sovereign guaranteed debt, the GSEs have a ready market around the world. However, because the GSEs' debt pays slightly more than treasury securities, it is often a substitute for treasury securities. This means that when the GSEs sell debt abroad, or even in the U.S., they are reducing the demand for U.S. Treasuries and thus increasing what treasury has to pay. We estimate these costs at about $17 billion to $29 billion a year. For the reasons I have described, government housing policies and particularly the GSEs, have been a failure. They are not reducing interest rates on mortgages. They are not necessary for 30-year fixed rate mortgages. They are increasing the prices of homes, especially for first time buyers. And they do not increase home ownership. In 1964, as Mr. Ross mentioned, the home ownership rate in the United Sates was 64 percent. It was still 64 percent in 1994. After HUD's aggressive increase in the affordable housing goals using the GSEs, the homeownership rate almost reached 70 percent in 2004. Then came the crash and the homeownership rate today is 64 percent. The housing finance market, home owners, home buyers and the treasury would be better off without the GSEs. The private sector is fully capable of handling mortgage finance, just as it currently handles the financing of automobiles, credit cards and other assets through a combination of banks and asset- backed securitization. Thank again for this opportunity to testify. [The prepared statement of Mr. Wallison can be found on page 132 of the appendix.] Chairman. Duffy. Thank you, Mr. Wallison. Dr. Zandi, you are now recognized for 5 minutes. STATEMENT OF MARK ZANDI Dr. Zandi. Thank you, Chairman Duffy, Ranking Member Cleaver, and the rest of the committee. Thanks for the opportunity. And thank you for engaging in this conversation. I think, as you say, it is a very important one that is much too long to address this particular issue. In addition to being the Chief Economist of Moody's Analytics, you should know I am also on the board of directors of MGIC, a private mortgage insurer. And I am also on the board of a CDFI (Community Development Financial Institutions) based in Philadelphia. And we do a lot of affordable housing through the CDFI, one of the largest in the country. Let me make three quick points, maybe two. First, the future housing finance system that replaces the GSEs, in my view, must have an explicit catastrophic government guarantee that is fully paid for by borrowers. I think this is a necessary ingredient for any future housing finance system. An explicit guarantee stands in contrast to the implicit guarantee that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac enjoyed prior to the crisis. This is important. Catastrophic in that the government should not step into the system unless we face scenarios that are darker than the Great Recession, the 2008, 2009 financial crisis. I do think it needs to be paid for by the borrowers in this part of the system that enjoy that government guarantee. I do think there has been a lot of work done, including some of my own, that shows we can do this and still maintain current mortgage rates. In my view, without this explicit catastrophic government guarantee that is paid for, mortgage rates would be measurably higher than they are today. Some of the work I did with regard to the PATH Act that was before this committee a few years ago showed that mortgage rates for the typical borrower would be as high as 100 basis points higher today than they would have been otherwise. That is for the typical borrower. For those that are less credit worthy, toward the edge of the credit box, the impact on mortgage rates would be measurably higher, and thus, the ability of the system to provide affordable loans to these borrowers would be significantly impaired. They would not be able to get loans. They would not be able to become homeowners. So point No. 1, we need that explicit catastrophic government guarantee that it is paid for. Point No. 2, there has been a lot of work done in thinking about how we should reform the system. I thought about all of them. I have gone down all of the different paths. And in my view the most viable proposal for reform, both from an economic perspective and given the current political environment, if we want to get this done anytime soon, is a multiple guarantor system. So what that means is that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would only be reprivatized until the system was able to maintain a number of--several other viable guarantors, similar guarantors, that meet the same requirements as Fannie Mae, and future Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would be required to hold as well. This will ensure that the future system will promote competition. I think competition is key in the secondary market to make sure that borrowers get the best mortgage rates and, perhaps more importantly, we get innovation in the provision of mortgage credit because the demographics of the country are changing and the way people will access credit will change. And we need a system that will be able to keep up with that. This multiple guarantor system will also ensure that we do away with too big to fail. Obviously the pre-crisis system with the duopoly, Fannie and Freddie, they were too big to fail, and thus, the Government had to step in and the resulting costs were enormous. With multiple guarantors on equal footing competing in the marketplace, we will do away with too big to fail and that particular problem. All of this can be done and ensure that there is plenty of private capital in front of taxpayers and we meet all of the access that we need for small lenders and for underserved communities, and we can maintain the current mortgage rates. So it is very doable and even if you don't think that the multiple guarantor path is the right path, again, I think it is applaudable that you are thinking about this. This is the time to do it. Do it now when, the economy is in good shape, house prices are rising, and so that way we don't have to do this in the next crisis. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Dr. Zandi can be found on page 145 of the appendix.] Chairman. Duffy. Thank you. Dr. Lea, you are now recognized for 5 minutes. STATEMENT OF MICHAEL LEA Dr. Lea. Chairman Duffy, Ranking Member Cleaver, and members of the subcommittee, thank you for the opportunity to be here today. I have an extensive background both in U.S. housing finance and mortgage markets abroad, having worked in more than 30 countries over the last 25 years. In addressing the subcommittee today, I have been asked to discuss how housing is financed in other major developed markets. My remarks will focus on five countries whose housing finance systems differ significantly from that of the U.S.: Australia, Canada, Denmark, Germany, and the United Kingdom. I will cover what is common amongst those systems, what is different, and what the U.S. might learn from how housing is financed in different countries. I begin with what is common. Current U.S. rates for adjustable and fixed-rate mortgages are comparable to mortgage rates in other countries. Recent house price increases are similar to those in the U.S. A third commonality is home ownership rates, which range between 62 percent and 67 percent, with the exception of Germany at 52 percent. There are significant differences in the size of country markets relative to the size of their economy. The mortgage markets of all the comparable countries, say for Germany, are larger than the U.S. with mortgage debt-to-GDP ranging between 65 percent and 94 percent. The U.S. has been as high as 73 percent in 2009, but is only 55 percent today, reflecting the effects of the mortgage crisis. Notably, of these countries, only Denmark and the U.S. have a mortgage interest tax deduction. There are significant differences across countries as to which entities provide mortgage loans. In Europe, mortgage lenders must be regulated banks. Banks originate and hold a vast majority of mortgages in Australia, Canada and the UK. This contract with the U.S., where banks originate only 40 percent of mortgage loans and most debt is held or backed by government entities. There are significant differences in the predominant mortgage instruments across countries. The U.S. is unique in the dominance of mortgages with rates that are fixed over the entire term of the loan and where the loan is pre-payable without penalty. Denmark uses this instrument with one significant difference. While both Danish and U.S. mortgages allow pre- payment at par if rates fall, in Denmark, borrowers can repurchase the bond that funds their loan at a discount of rate rise. In this way, the borrower can deleverage as rates rise, reducing the likelihood of negative equity. The standard product in Canada, Germany and many European countries is a short- to medium-term fixed-rate mortgage. The rate is fixed for a 1- to 10-year period over a longer amortization, after which the rate is reset at current market interest rates. The borrower can select the same or a different fixed-rate term at reset, which allows them some protection against potential interest rate shock. Australia and the UK are primarily short-term variable rate markets. Policymakers in both countries credit the predominance of variable rate loans for cushioning the impact of global recession. Mortgage rates fell close to zero when base rates were lowered. Borrower payments fell without having to refinance, unlike in the U.S. where many borrowers who were unable to lower their mortgage rates and payment due to limited or negative equity. Mortgage funding is also different across countries. The U.S. is unusual in the dominance of securitization. 65 percent of mortgage debt outstanding is securitized in the U.S. This reflects two factors, the domination of the fixed-rate mortgage and the presence of government-backed entities that guarantee the securities. The only country that comes close to the U.S. is Canada at 31 percent. The main capital market funding instrument in Europe is covered bonds. These are corporate bank-issued bonds backed by a ring- fenced portfolio of mortgage loans. They represent over 1.7 trillion in outstanding mortgage covered bonds, covering approximately 25 percent of European mortgage debt. Mortgage underwriting is usually stricter in most other countries as well. In Europe, a typical down payment requirement is 20 percent. Canada tightened its underwriting requirements after the crisis. Purchase loans are required to have a minimum 10 percent down, refinance 20 percent. Mortgage loans are recourse obligations in all countries surveyed, and default rates have been or are significantly less than the U.S. So what can the U.S. learn from housing finance systems in other countries? There is no ideal housing finance system. Individual arrangements reflect history, market structure and government policy. No other country's housing finance system evolved with extensive reliance and securitization of GSEs. Lenders are subject to prudential regulation, but none are subject to mission regulation or housing goals. Importantly, there is skin in the game in housing finance systems in most other countries. Banks are subject to domestic and international capital rules and hold considerably more capital than that held by mortgage agencies in the U.S. In no other country is the 30-year fixed rate mortgage the dominant instrument. As we learned from the savings and loan crisis, the fixed-rate mortgage is not a suitable product for bank lenders. Rather, it requires capital market financing, which in the U.S. is achieved through the U.S. Government guarantees. Guarantees lower the relative cost of the fixed-rate mortgage, sustaining its dominance and that of the entities backing them. The result is the government, and thus taxpayers, backs the majority of mortgages in the U.S. The experience of other countries shows that high rates of home ownership, stable well developed mortgage markets can be achieved with less systemic risk than found in the U.S. In that respect, the U.S. clearly learned from international housing finance systems. Thank you for the opportunity to appear today. [The prepared statement of Dr. Lea can be found on page 44 of the appendix.] Chairman Duffy. Thank you, Dr. Lea. Ms. McCargo, you are recognized for 5 minutes. STATEMENT OF ALANNA MCCARGO Ms. McCargo. Good morning, Chairman Duffy, Ranking Member Cleaver and members of the committee. Thank you for the opportunity to testify. My name is Alanna McCargo and I am the Co-director of the Housing Finance Policy Center at the Urban Institute. The views I express here today are my own and should not be attributed to the Urban Institute, its trustees or its funders. In 1968, President Lyndon B. Johnson founded the Urban Institute to help solve the problems that weighed heavily on the hearts and minds of America, by bringing sound research, evidence, and perspective that could inform effective policymaking. At the time, the problem was the American city and its people and the declaration of the war on poverty. Johnson signed the Fair Housing Act into law that same year, making housing discrimination against blacks and other protected groups for renting and owning homes illegal. I mention this history as a reflection for this Congress as you consider the future, as we are facing some of the very same inequities that are plaguing not only our cities, but our suburbs and rural areas all over this country 50 years later. I will focus on the serious issue surrounding the housing finance system and the ways Congress can address those issues with comprehensive reform. Our country has changed as has its needs. Huge demographic shifts in race, age, income, and education are all significant drivers of what our future housing system needs to contemplate. First, there is a growing wealth gap, and it is hurting low and middle income families. The gap persists both between races and between owners and renters. We know that home ownership creates wealth through equity and asset building and it continues to be the primary way that many middle class and working families build wealth and achieve economic stability, especially for families of color. As an example, to emphasize this problem, the overall home ownership rate today for blacks is just below 42 percent, back to levels we have not seen since the 1960's before the Fair Housing Act was put in place. Major housing policy changes are needed to address systemic constraints for people of color and avoid dire consequences for the financial security and generational wealth prospects of millions of Americans. Second, we have insufficient affordable housing available for a growing number of diverse households. Over the next decade, there will be as many as 16 million new households formed and an overwhelming majority of that growth will be non- white. Our housing inventory, rental and owner, is already deficient, continues to age, and is not being built or preserved to keep pace with demand for affordability. Third, consumers have insufficient access to mortgage markets, hampering home ownership opportunity. This issue has its roots in underwriting standards and the lack of willingness from market participants to take on any default risk. Urban Institute's research finds that more than 6.3 million mortgages would have been made between 2009 and 2015 to credit worthy borrowers under reasonable lending standards. In the current system, mortgages are only being made to people with pristine credit quality, despite their overall credit worthiness. A systemic view of underwriting systems and credit scoring models should be considered. Our country deserves a housing finance system that serves the people and communities that need investment and that provides access to sustainable and affordable credit. I am going to highlight three critical elements for this reform. To start, consumers must have access to sustainable affordable mortgages. Long-term fixed-rate products allow access to credit with affordable monthly payments and without the risk of interest rate volatility. This is essential in market stability and gives homeowners the ability to build equity. Ensuring the availability of these mortgages requires the explicit backing of the Federal Government. Next, taxpayers must be protected. Private capital in the first loss position will protect taxpayers without undermining access to credit for credit worthy borrowers and access to the secondary market for lenders of all sizes. There must be a mechanism to ensure capital is available throughout the economic cycle to a broad set of financial institutions. And finally, improvements are needed to FHA (Federal Housing Administration) so that it can work to fulfill its mission. Because FHA provides a critical source of financing to historically underserved renters and homeowners, and plays a pivotal role for low income renters, first-time home buyers and for seniors, we should ensure that FHA and Ginnie Mae have clarity and certainty in any housing finance reform. FHA must work in a coordinated and efficient way in the housing finance ecosystem. In particular, FHA needs resources to significantly modernize its technology and operations in order to meet the needs of today's consumer. We have one U.S. housing market, and we should have one housing finance system and a national housing policy that safely and efficiently serves all communities and all demographics and is accessible at all times. Thank you for the opportunity to testify. I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Ms. McCargo can be found on page 103 of the appendix.] Chairman Duffy. Thank you. Mr. Tozer, you are recognized for 5 minutes. STATEMENT OF THEODORE TOZER Mr. Tozer. Good morning, Chairman Duffy, Ranking Member Cleaver, and members of the subcommittee. My name is Ted Tozer, and I appreciate the opportunity to testify today on behalf of the Milken Institute Center for Financial Markets where I am a Senior Fellow in the Housing Finance Program. My background gives me a unique look into the question of housing finance reform. Prior to joining the Milken Institute, I spent 7 years running Ginnie Mae as its president. Prior to that, I spent 25 years running capital markets for a top 10 mortgage banker. Any industry could find itself with the complacent status quo leaders. The challenge is when competitive disrupters are not able to break in. This is the situation in the mortgage market. The GSE duopoly of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac is restricting credit and slowing down innovation. A key chokepoint is restriction on the type of loans the GSE will allow to be sold into the capital markets. A reformed housing finance systems should focus on fostering innovation driven by competition. I will give you an example to demonstrate the positive impact of competition. When I joined Ginnie Mae in 2010, approximately 70 percent of the new Ginnie Mae guaranteed MBS (Mortgage Backed Securities) were issued by four large banks that had put in place credit overlays that prevented many low to moderate income borrowers from obtaining FHA financing. The average credit score for an FHA loan was around 720, limiting FHA's ability to be a countercyclical force to support housing. Starting in 2011, smaller lenders instead became issuers themselves. This meant they could bypass the big banks and set their own credit standards within the limits prescribed by FHA. Today, Ginnie Mae has approximately 440 approved issuers. And no issuer has more than a 7 percent market share of new issuance. The average FHA credit score is about 675, meeting the aim of the program in responsibly expanding access to mortgages. Adding the competition of lenders was key. This goes to the heart of the difference between the various housing finance proposals. Should it be one, two, six or hundreds of guarantors? I believe the most advantageous approach was put forward by the Milken Institute, that hundreds of guarantors should be allowed. The mortgage industry faces the challenge of changing demographics as minority borrowers become the major homebuying group in the future. And lenders need to have the flexibility to create loan programs to meet the needs of these unique communities. The strength of Ginnie Mae's structure is the guarantors have skin in the game, even while the U.S. backs the MBS. That is because the issuer is responsible to advance delinquent payments MBS whole owners and use their own funding sources to buy delinquent loans out of pools. Competition also means that the firms that do not perform well can fail without hampering the whole housing finance system. That is a huge advantage over the previous or current system centered around the GSEs. During my 10 years at Ginnie Mae, every issue we had to shut down was due to the lack of liquidity to make required payments to bond holders, not their exhaustion of capital. The goal with Ginnie Mae was to spread the counterparty risk among hundreds of issuers to enable Ginnie Mae to transfer failed issuers' portfolios to other Ginnie Mae issuers, similar to the way that the FDIC (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation) transfers deposits and assets from a failed bank to another FDIC-insured bank. A future system must assure that small lenders and guarantors have equal access to credit enhancers. If not, the potential base of hundreds of issuers will reduce substantially, and the competition and community banks' lending will be minimized. Ginnie Mae must make sure credit enhancement is equally available and credit enhancers are working with issuers to develop customized solutions to support the communities. We need to look at other options that will increase underserved markets' access to housing finance. Having hundreds of guarantors will allow community-based solutions, not solutions that are just for a national level. We need to build off the gains made by the GSEs' affordable national housing mandate at the national level and build an environment where lenders embrace affordable lending, not as a box that has to be checked, but as an economically viable part of their business model. I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Tozer can be found on page 122 of the appendix.] Chairman Duffy. Thank you, Mr. Tozer. The Chair now recognizes himself for 5 minutes. I am going to cut to the chase on an issue that I know is going to come up today because we are talking about tax. Miss McCargo, do you have a definition of kind of how much money someone makes to be middle income? Ms. McCargo. We have a definition. Standard area median incomes and it is all depending on what part of the country you live in. Chairman Duffy. Could it--if you make $100,000 are you middle income? Ms. McCargo. You can be middle income at $100,000 in-- Chairman Duffy. What about 200? Ms. McCargo. --Part of the country. Chairman Duffy. How about $200,000? Ms. McCargo. Yes. Chairman Duffy. Three hundred? Ms. McCargo. I am not sure. I don't think so. Chairman Duffy. And if you are making $300,000 a year, can you get a $1 million mortgage? Pretty tough, wouldn't it be, to get a $1 million mortgage? And I would agree with that. And I just want to make this point that when we have a conversation, which I am off topic, I am going to get back on topic in a second. When we have folks who say I don't want tax breaks for the rich but they want to argue for a $1 million mortgage interest deduction, they are not really focused on middle income Americans per your point, Miss McCargo. They are focused on rich Americans. I don't have a problem with mortgage deduction at $1 million. But it is interesting how rhetoric and policy all of sudden clash when a lot of my friends have very rich constituents, who they start fighting for in some of these loopholes and write-offs. And I have to make sure my time is running. If you want to give me another full 5 minutes, I guess? Mr. Sherman. Will the gentleman yield? Chairman Duffy. If I get all whole 5 minutes, yes, I will yield. Mr. Sherman. Come to my district. I will show you the middle class, hardworking Americans, whose homes require--sell for many hundreds of thousands of dollars more than-- Chairman Duffy. But a million? A million dollars. Mr. Sherman. Unindexed. A few years from now, absolutely. Chairman Duffy. We could talk-- Mr. Sherman. Remember that million is not indexed, neither is the half million. But yes, even-- Chairman Duffy. I am going to reclaim my time. Mr. Sherman. --Even a million dollar home with two hardworking--a nurse married to a police officer-- Chairman Duffy. I am going to reclaim my time. They actually took off a minute. But I just think that is an interesting point that we can't forget in this rhetoric is one thing, but when your constituents start to get hit by loopholes that benefit the wealthy, they start to go away. It is interesting to see people squirm. But I am not here for that. Mr. Tozer, we are having a conversation about the MBA proposal, to DeMarco-Bright, Urban Institute. Have you reviewed those plans and do you have an opinion on what would be the best path forward for this committee? Mr. Tozer. Yes, sir. I have looked at all of them, and again, I think the issue it comes down to is basically how many guarantors or issuers you want to have. That is really what it comes down to if you compare the MBA and the other programs. I think they are all basically very similar, but it comes back to how many guarantors or issuers we should have. And again, like I mentioned in my statement, I think the concept is having as many as possible that can be successful. So more lenders getting back to community lending is really important to be able to respond to market conditions. Chairman Duffy. It is important that lenders have some skin in the game? Mr. Tozer. I think it is really important for the institutions that are being backed up by the government to have skin in the game. I think they should be aligned with the government and their interests. Chairman Duffy. I am interested in the panel's opinion because right now, Q.M. (qualified mortgage) has a debt-to- income (DTI) ratio of 43 percent. But Fannie and Freddie has bumped their own standard up to 50 percent debt-to-income ratio. I am wondering if lenders throughout America would be making a lot of loans at a debt-to-income ratio of 50 percent? Mr. Wallison do you have an opinion on that? Or if they have some skin in the game might think, well, I might want a little different debt-to-income ratio if I actually am one of the first dollar losses here. Mr. Wallison. Lenders throughout the United States would be making these loans if they can sell them to the government. Chairman Duffy. But if they had to keep some skin in the game-- Mr. Wallison. If they had to keep skin in the game, they would not be making those loans. Chairman Duffy. At 50 percent debt-to-income. Mr. Wallison. 50 percent debt-to-income. But if they do make the-- Chairman Duffy. Why not, Mr. Wallison? Mr. Wallison. One of the reasons they would not be making those loans is that it is exceedingly risky. These loans are exceedingly risky. These people, by definition, with a DTI of 50 percent will have a lot of obligations in addition to their mortgage obligations. And that kind of borrower is someone who has a high risk of failure, especially if housing prices should fall. Chairman Duffy. I heard a stat that half of Americans are a $400 financial crisis away from being in financially hard times. And it seems like it is this very person who has a debt- to-income ratio of 50 percent that we are allowing to get into a home that maybe they should take a little more time. Maybe they should write their debt or make some more money before they actually get a mortgage because, as Ms. McCargo indicated, you get people who their main investment is their home. And the government is subsidizing or incentivizing people to get mortgages that they probably shouldn't get, and when things go wrong for them it financially devastates them. Mr. Zandi, I appreciate your testimony. I guess we have had a lot of agreement today. It was great. Do you--of the plans that you have evaluated, which one do you like the best in your viewpoint? Dr. Zandi. I think the most viable is the multiple guarantor system, which is similar to the MBA proposal. I agree with Mr. Tozer that it is not dissimilar for the DeMarco-Bright proposal, but the multiple guarantor system, I think, is just more doable. It is-- Chairman Duffy. Why? Dr. Zandi. Because you are using the existing infrastructure, the common securitization platform, the risk transfer process, all those other things that the GSEs have been doing since they have been put into conservatorship. So you are leveraging all of the work, the good work, that they have done to get private capital into the system and make sure that you can have entry of other guarantors into the system. So I don't think we want to throw that away. I think that is very valuable and useful. And if we go down the DeMarco- Bright path, the sort of expanded Ginnie issuer system path, that is just a wholly different system and you are not using all the work, all the good work that we have done. And it will be very hard to get, to be frank, from a political economy perspective, all of the stakeholders involved here to sign onto that. They just can't get their mind around it. Chairman Duffy. Right. Dr. Zandi. The multiple guarantor system, they can't--and you get a lot of the benefits that you want, the competition, the getting rid of too big to fail, a lot of private capital in front of the government guarantees. So I think that is just the most viable approach. Chairman Duffy. My time has long expired, but I look forward to more lengthy conversations with all of you as we go through this process. The Chair now recognizes the Ranking Member, Mr. Cleaver for 5 minutes. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just a point of the average cost of a home in my State in Missouri is $169,000. The median price of a home here in D.C. is $551,000, and most of the people who live in those homes are not rich. They are struggling. I look at many of our staff members will just rent an apartment with four of five people living in their apartment together because even the rental rates are very high. But I just mention that to speak to the mortgage cap being capped at $500,000. Mr. Zandi, thank you for being here again. In your opinion, why would the disadvantages of a private GSE system largely outweigh the advantages? Dr. Zandi. I am sorry, can you-- Mr. Cleaver. But why would the disadvantages of a fully private GSE system-- Dr. Zandi. Right. Right. Mr. Cleaver. --Largely outweigh the advantages? Dr. Zandi. So to go to a fully privatized system without a government backstop, without an explicit catastrophic guarantee that is paid by a borrower, that would result in my view, in significantly higher borrowing costs for everyone, everyone in that part of the system. For the typical borrower, kind of in the middle of the distribution in terms of credit characteristics, the average mortgage rate would rise about 1 percentage point. So instead of 4 percent today, it would be 5 percent. For those that have credit characteristics that are not as good as the typical borrower, their rates would be even higher than that. So if you get toward the end of the credit box where the GSEs are able to make a loan or insure a loan, mortgage rates would be so high that these folks couldn't afford to buy a loan, so they would be locked out of the market. So I think that is the most significant-- Mr. Cleaver. Right. Dr. Zandi. --Disadvantage. And I will make another point, another second point. I am not sure it is even viable because if you get into the next crisis--think about it. You get into the next Great Recession. The financial system is imploding. Hopefully, that is not in our lifetime, but it will be in someone's lifetime, do we really think the government won't step in? It will. Mr. Cleaver. Yes. Dr. Zandi. And so let us just recognize that, acknowledge it, and pay for it up front instead of waiting for that to happen and just taking our chances. So let us just be honest here about the reality of this. Mr. Cleaver. Yes. I agree. I was here. Mr. Chairman, and I don't want to get into it because I got too--time. Because Mr. Wallison, you had mentioned earlier that in your opinion we could make it without the GSEs, and so if you could answer briefly because I want Ms. McCargo to also deal with it. So Mortgage Company A in Kansas City, Missouri is financing all of these mortgages. Aren't they going to be limited if there is no secondary market? There are just so many mortgages that a local mortgage company could handle. Aren't they going to face a problem which eventually falls on the whole population of our city? Mr. Wallison. No, because there is a private securitization system that will grow up to take those mortgages that the banks do not want to hold in portfolio. Mr. Cleaver. What do you base that on? Mr. Wallison. The existence of a private mortgage. The private mortgage system that we had before--the mortgage securitization system that we had before the financial crisis and the existence today, and before the financial crisis, of securitization systems for credit cards, for auto loans and for many other assets. So the private sector is well able to handle all of these things, and there is no reason to have the government involved. And as I said in my testimony, the government causes higher prices so your constituents, as well as everyone else's constituents here, cannot afford even the entry level homes because of the way the government is driving up housing prices. Mr. Cleaver. Yes. Ms. McCargo? Ms. McCargo. Thank you, Congressman. The privatization of the GSEs: We have come out of an era when they were operating as both private and public under a dual mission and we learned a lesson from that. And that is something that I don't think we want to go back to. Having the GSEs available to ensure that there is a guarantee, provide certainty, and protect taxpayers with others and with other private support in a first loss position is a healthy way to sort of move us forward. I think the lack of an explicit guarantee takes away the opportunity for markets to open up--for lenders to participate in small communities, in rural communities--in a way that is meaningful. And I think that, if we had a private market that was willing to take all these risks without anything we would have a much healthier situation right now. No one is making--these loans are not being made without some sort of catastrophic loss guarantee from the government, and I think we need to make sure we keep that preserved for any future system. Mr. Cleaver. My time is up. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the Vice Chair, Mr. Ross. Mr. Ross. Thank you, Chairman. 33 years ago, my wife and I purchased our first home. We did it under FHA, and we put 5 percent down. And at the time we also paid, what I learned, was co-PMI, private mortgage insurance. And the reason we had to pay that is because unless we put 20 percent down and financed 80 percent, we had to have the guarantee in there just in case of a default. And it led me to believe then I needed skin in the game, but more importantly, also to this day, shows me that there was capacity in the market from the private sector to take some of that risk. And I guess what we have seen over the last two panels that appeared before you on this topic is that a government backstop is absolutely necessary because apparently the private sector cannot accurately price or set aside reserve for deep in the tail risk of a severe turndown on the housing market. Is that something that each of you agrees with? Mr. Wallison? Are we losing? Is the private sector so inept that we can't allow them to have confidence in their pricing in the event that we have another crash like we had in 2008? Mr. Wallison. One of the reasons we had the crash in 2008, or the major reason we had the crash in 2008, is that the government had driven up, through its policies, a housing crisis beyond the level where they made any economic sense because the government was buying those mortgages. And so, when we had the crash, the housing prices fell and a lot of people, especially low-income people, lost their homes. Mr. Ross. To that end, let us assume that back then we had a viable private market of buying these mortgages, would it not almost self-regulate because it wouldn't take the risk that was being purchased then by the GSEs? Mr. Wallison. One of the things that we have to understand, and what doesn't seem to be understood here, is that there is a tradeoff between underwriting standards and housing prices. And if you reduce down payments to a very low level, you increase the amount of debt that the homeowner takes on. When the homeowner takes on a lot of debt not only does that homeowner become a riskier credit, but in addition, that drives up housing prices and so fewer people can afford houses. So in other words, when we reduce underwriting standards, especially down payments, we make it harder for people to enter the homeownership system because housing prices have risen much faster than wages are rising. As a result, we are stuck at 64 percent. We could have a much more viable and a higher homeownership system in the United States if we allowed prices to go to a level that the private sector would produce, and that would be through using solid underwriting standards including solid down payments. Mr. Tozer. Can I answer your question?-- Mr. Ross. Please. Mr. Tozer. --Real quick. Basically, that is at the heart of our proposal because we look at the facts, and there are two sets of investors. There are investors that will invest in credit risk and investors in interest rate risk. Mr. Ross. Right. Mr. Tozer. The proposal of Milken Institute is that the government will backstop the investors that invest in interest rate risk because they need to have a commodity that they can trade to manage their interest rate risk. But our proposal is to let the private sector hold all the credit risk in the form of the issuer's holding the tail risk and the people who hold the credit risk in front of the issuer. You mentioned PMI. Mr. Ross. Right. Mr. Tozer. I think PMI is the natural in a future state where the PMI companies can begin to take on, not only up to 20 percent down payment, but maybe let us go to even 40 percent. And that way the issuers are protected, but the government is simply stepping in to support interest rate investors the same way the FDIC protects depositors-- Mr. Ross. Right. Mr. Tozer. --Like depositors are protected by FDIC. FDIC does not guarantee the loans that are in the banks' portfolio-- Mr. Ross. And there is enough capacity waiting to do this, isn't there? Mr. Tozer. And that is exactly how Ginnie Mae works. Ginnie Mae does not guarantee any loans. We guarantee the issuer's ability-- Mr. Ross. Right. Mr. Tozer. --To handle their bond payments. And that is the heart of the Milken proposal is to say that we have hundreds of issuers. It doesn't mean we have hundreds of banks. And they are able to all go and get interest rate protection in the capital markets, but the credit risk is held by the private sector. Dr. Zandi. Congressman, the-- Mr. Ross. Yes. And Dr. Zandi, I am going to you. Dr. Zandi. Just to make clear, Mr. Tozer's proposal, though, has an explicit-- Mr. Ross. Backstop. Dr. Zandi. --Has catastrophic government backstop as payment. Mr. Ross. Right. Dr. Zandi. And that is the point. If you want-- Mr. Ross. But you seem--they can offload these credit relationships with incentives to the private sector? Dr. Zandi. They can offload all of the risk except the catastrophic risk. You need a government backstop to take the catastrophic. And if you don't, then mortgage rates will be higher in long-term fixed-rate loans. Mr. Ross. How much-- Dr. Zandi. Thirty-year loans-- Mr. Ross. How much-- Dr. Zandi. Fifteen will-- Mr. Ross. How much higher? Are we talking in terms of basis? Dr. Zandi. For the typical borrower, and I am just going back to the PATH Act. That was the last attempt at this. Mr. Ross. Right. Dr. Zandi. So let us take that as our benchmark. That would have raised mortgage rates for the typical borrower by almost a full percentage point without that government backstop. So now, of course, there is a lot of other moving parts in PATH and that could be mitigated-- Mr. Ross. Right. Dr. Zandi. --But that is what you are talking about. And that is the person in the middle, right, not-- Mr. Ross. But that is the elimination of a taxpayer bailout for that extra point. Dr. Zandi. That is you have no government backstop. Mr. Ross. Right. Dr. Zandi. That is what you were giving up. And then if you did that, then basically you are saying we don't--30-year fixed rate loans, 15-year fixed rate loans, there would still be some out there like there are some in other systems-- Mr. Ross. Some of them are-- Dr. Zandi. --But they will be a very small piece of the pie. Mr. Ross. I see my time has expired. I yield back. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman, for 5 minutes. Mr. Sherman. And Mr. Chairman, you paint a picture of luxury if someone has a mortgage of over a $500,000 in California. I welcome you to go to the average home in your home State, knock on the door, say you have so many bedrooms in that most average home, you are living in luxury, because I assure you that the average home on the average lot in the State of Wisconsin would cost over a $1 million if located within commuting distance of Silicon Valley. Those are the prices. And perhaps we need to organize--we go on CODEL (congressional delegation) to strange and foreign countries. Perhaps we need a CODEL to California so that you will see that things are different in my State than they are in yours. As to our housing finance system, we currently have a 30- year fixed rate, non-recourse-- Chairman Duffy. Can we go in January or February? Yes or no? Mr. Sherman. Yes. Maybe when the Grammys, the Emmys, we will talk. It is about time. On foreign affairs, I never thought of a CODEL from this committee, but I think it would make sense. We have the 30-year fixed rate, non-recourse, pre-payable loan. That is the best deal homebuyers have anywhere in the world, and oh, by the way, with a 10 percent down payment. In so many countries, if you don't have parental help, if you don't--you can't buy a home. You can't get the down payment. The tradition in Iceland was that you work for many, many years on ships in order to get the down payment. And so I think we have a system that is good for homebuyers. It has also been profitable over the last few years for the government. It is not true that back in the 1960's we didn't have government involvement. What we had then was savings and loan institutions with enormously high leverage. All supported by the government. That provided good mortgages until it collapsed at government cost. Ms. McCargo, you are absolutely, right. We need to build more homes. Mr. Zandi, a lot of people in my district, which the Chairman will be visiting this winter-- Dr. Zandi. Can I come too? Chairman Duffy. Absolutely. Mr. Sherman. They have saved all their lives. They have put their kids through school, and what they have is about a 20 percent equity in a home that is worth between $500,000 and $1 million. So let us say we limit the home mortgage deduction to $500,000, we limit the property tax deduction at $10,000, and they go to sell their home. The buyer is going to know that those limits exist. And oh by the way, the buyer is going to know that the limits aren't indexed. So 10, 20 years from now when they go to sell their home, the word half a million dollars will mean a very different thing than it means now. What happens to the value of that $500,000 to $1 million home if the tax law changes? Dr. Zandi. The analysis I have done is to take the entire House bill and that includes all the things you mentioned plus the increase in the standard deduction-- Mr. Sherman. Yes. Dr. Zandi. --Which reduces the value of the MID (mortgage- interest deduction), as well as the impact the larger budget deficits would have on interest rates, which matter for the housing market. Mr. Sherman. Right. Dr. Zandi. So in that context, with all of those moving parts, including the $10,000 cap on property tax and the $500,000 cap on MID, nationwide all else being equal, house prices would decline by 3 percent to 5 percent. In districts like yours, I don't know yours specifically, but I can guess-- Mr. Sherman. OK. Dr. Zandi. --In areas around where I live in suburban Philly, New York, New Jersey, the price declines will be double-digit, 10 percent, 12 percent. Not that I am a fan of the MID. I am not. And we can talk about how you might want to do this is a better way. It is very costly, and I don't think it is as effective in promoting homeownership as it should be. So I am not a fan. But I think it is important to recognize that if this plan were adopted, those are the kind of HPI (House Price Index) house price declines you should expect in those. And that is obviously, going to be a lot of stress for those people-- Mr. Sherman. Yes. Dr. Zandi. --For the lenders that made those loans. It is meaningful. The economy will-- Mr. Sherman. Or the Federal Government that has ensured those loans. And if you have 20 percent equity and your home goes down 12 percent in value and then you have some transactions cost to sell, you are just not going to be able to retire to Wisconsin after you sell your home. And finally, there is this--oh, well, I have run out--I yield back. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Hultgren, for 5 minutes. Mr. Hultgren. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you all for being here. I appreciate your time and your expertise on this important discussion. First, I would like to address my first question to Dr. Zandi. With respect to the concept of recap and release, you make the point that this might be the most politically feasible option, but I also think there is plenty of agreement that this would have its drawbacks. Can you please speak to the economics of recap and release? Dr. Zandi. Sure, and I don't think it is politically viable. You could argue it might be the least disruptive to the system because you are just basically going back to the future. In a sense, it is no reform at all. So I think there are a couple of very significant problems with it. Most importantly, we are not changing anything. We are going to go back to a too big to fail duopoly that dominates the system. And, yes, maybe the GSEs in the future system will be at higher levels of capitalization, regulatory oversight, but you are still left with a system that is very vulnerable to the thing that got us into this mess in the first place. Why would we do that? Second, these institutions are going to be released into a system they are going to have to capitalize. It is systemically important because they are too big to fail. They do have costs that they have agreements with treasury, and taxpayers paid a lot of money to bail them out. And I think taxpayers deserve some compensation for that. If they have any kind of backstop, they will have to pay for that. So when you consider all of the costs that they will face as reprivatized institutions, in my view, it will mean that mortgage rates will be higher than they are today. So why would we do this exactly? So in my view, recap and release is a pretty bad idea. Mr. Hultgren. Yes, yes, OK. That is helpful. Let me drill in a little bit more, if I could, Dr. Zandi? Your testimony notes--and you kind of referenced this, and I will quote from your testimony. ``The GSEs would likely owe the government for the taxpayers' financial support,'' end quote. How much do you believe they owe to the taxpayers or would owe to the taxpayers? Dr. Zandi. I don't know the exact number. And in fact, that is a matter of significant debate and discussion. It is in the legal system. Let me put it this way. I am an economist. This is at a higher pay grade than I have. It is a real thorny question. I would say that the taxpayers bail these guys out and taxpayers should be repaid for that. And in the way they bailed out--this is an important point--the way they bailed out the Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac was not a loan. This was equity. We took equity in these institutions and that is at a higher cost. And I think taxpayers should be reimbursed for that cost. What that number is, I am not sure. Mr. Hultgren. OK. Dr. Zandi. That is, again, a thorny question. I don't know. But I think that should be part of the calculation. Mr. Hultgren. That is helpful, thank you. Mr. Wallison, your testimony points out that the United States is the only developed country with a housing finance system completely dominated by the government. Why do you think that is? Do you think other countries have observed the lessons of U.S. policies? Mr. Wallison. I doubt it. I would like to believe that was true, but I think we really have a case of path dependency here and that is that the United States began to have a role in housing back in the 1920's. And we continue to grow that system using, for example, the S&L system. When that failed, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac came up to pick up their activities. So it is something that has grown in the U.S. system over time. And once that happens, it becomes very difficult to change-- Mr. Hultgren. Right. Mr. Wallison. --As I am sure everyone here is finding. That there are a lot of people who have come to rely on this system, especially those like realtors and homebuilders who enjoy the fact that housing prices rise as a result of this government involvement. But then again, from time to time, we have these crashes which we had in 2008 as a result of these government policies. So we really have to look at this whole thing again from the beginning and start talking about whether it makes any sense to have the government involved in the housing finance system. And in my testimony, I have shown that all of the things that we are talking about here, the 30-year fixed rate loan, lower housing prices, or what we should have as lower housing prices, lower interest rates, helping the people who want to buy first homes, does not occur with a government program. So we start all over again with a private system, which will produce, as the private system always does, the things that the American people want at a price they can afford. And I would point out, in my testimony, I show what happens in the auto market, which is also a gigantic market. The prices there have been stable for 40 or 50 years in terms of the median income in the United States. And the reason for that is simply that this is a fully, private market where people, consumers, negotiate with the producers. We don't have that in the United States for housing prices because we have the government inserting itself and requiring lower underwriting standards as a result of which we have much higher housing prices. Mr. Hultgren. My time has expired. I may follow up with some other written questions, if that is all right? I yield back. Thank you. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Massachusetts, Mr. Capuano-- Mr. Capuano. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Duffy. --For 5 minutes. Mr. Capuano. Mr. Chairman, I was in my office doing very important work until I decided to come over and have some fun. First of all, Mr. Zandi, I appreciate your comments that without a government backstop the rates really wouldn't change a whole lot, but rates are only one factor in determining monthly expenses. I am a homeowner, and to be perfectly honest, I own a two- family home because I needed the rent to be able to meet the mortgage when I first bought the home. And for me, and most homeowners, it is how much do I make every month and how much can I afford every month, monthly payment, not the general. All the other stuff works into it. And if you are going to talk about the rates without a government backstop, we have only had this experience. We haven't had it since the 1930's. Prior to the 1930's, it was a fully private market. There was no government backstop, no government involvement, and the rates were about the same as the rates today, pretty much. But it was a 50 percent down payment, 5-0 percent down payment. I don't know anybody in any market who has 50 percent to pay down on a home. And it was a 5-year payback period which effectively takes the average monthly principal and interest and doubles or triples it, depending on the math you do, 2.5 times. Tell that to the average American they love. You can keep your 30-year mortgage, if you can get in. And the answer is, most of us could never get in. We have done the purely private market before, it didn't work. We are not going back. Period. And those of you who want to go back, I dare you--I dare you to put it on the floor of the House for a vote. It would be a wonderful debate, and it would be a wonderful result in the next election for those of you who thought that was a good system. I also want to talk quickly about the tax bill that we are all debating, this million-dollar number. Sounds like a lot. Before I came over, in all of 10 seconds I looked up average home prices in Boston. And like most Americans that search brought me to Zillow. Here is what Zillow says the average home price in Boston is $561,400, just the city of Boston. That does not include our expensive suburbs. And by the way, Boston is geographically one of the smallest cities in the country--$561,000 average median. By the way, it sounds like well, gee, that must be a problem. That home price has increased 9.3 percent in the last 12 months, and it is expected to increase 3.9 percent more in the next year. That is a pretty good market, the way I look at it, even though it is expensive. And by the way, I also looked it up, as of this very moment, as of right now, there are 428 homes for sale in Boston that are for $1 million or more--428. I can't afford that. But a $500,000 mortgage is not out of the norm for most people in places like Boston and California and New York and Chicago and many places in Florida and on and on and on. And I just happened to purely circumstantially look up another town, a nice town. I have been there, actually. Matter-of-fact, I did very well. I went there for John Kerry and they liked me there. I went to this town, and I looked up their average price. Purely circumstantially, I looked up Wausau, Wisconsin. It really is a nice town, and they did like me. The average home in Wausau, Wisconsin is $100,000, 20 percent of the cost in Boston. Now, I am sure it is a great home, but that is the difference. The geographics makes a difference. And that home has increased 5.4 percent, half of the increase in Boston-- Chairman Duffy. Will the gentleman yield? Mr. Capuano. --And is expected to increase 2.5 percent. It is not the same. And the bottom line is people in Boston make a little bit more, but not that much more. Chairman Duffy. Will the gentleman yield? Mr. Capuano. Sure. Chairman Duffy. I appreciate you bringing up my hometown, but I would note that the $500,000 of mortgage deduction which is included in the bill would include then the median income in Boston-- Mr. Capuano. On a median income-- Chairman Duffy. --So you are covered. Mr. Capuano. --But median is made up by people that are over it as well. Chairman Duffy. But you advocated that-- Mr. Capuano. --Because there are lots of homes in Boston that are at $700,000, $800,000, and they are not big expensive homes. For that kind of money--I have always known. I watch HGTV. Chairman Duffy. Me, too. Mr. Capuano. For the amount of money I can get for a home in Boston, I can get the greatest home in the world in Waco, Texas, according to what they show on HGTV. I am shocked. You cannot buy a parking space in my district for the amount of money you can get 40 acres in Waco. And that is not good or bad or indifferent. It is not a statement. It is just a fact. And it doesn't make any good things about Boston or bad things about Waco or Wausau. It just means if we are going to make national policy it has to be adjusted to regional cost, No. 1, No. 2, and I appreciate the extra time. As far as the 30-year year mortgage goes, it is not just one factor. There are multiple factors that lead into the decision that the average American makes, and those factors are totally played against them without a government backstop. Mr. Chairman, I really appreciate the extra time, and I can't wait to get back to Wausau. Chairman Duffy. I might differ with you on that point. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr. Rothfus, for 5 minutes. Mr. Rothfus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Wallison, in your written testimony you debated the merits and the necessity of the 30-year fixed mortgage. You also discussed the role that the government has in insuring that this product exists. Does the 30-year fixed rate jumbo loan mortgage market have a Federal backstop? Mr. Wallison. No. Mr. Rothfus. Why has the jumbo market thrived without a Federal backstop? Mr. Wallison. Because we don't need a Federal backstop to have a 30-year fixed rate mortgage. Mr. Rothfus. Dr. Lea, in your testimony, you compared the housing finance systems in similar developed markets. I was interested to see that Australia, Canada, Denmark, the UK and the U.S. all have fairly similar homeownership rates despite significant differences in the housing and finance systems in each country. We are often told that the 30-year fixed rate mortgage is essential to ensuring that our homeownership rate remains high, yet you point out that, quote, ``In no other country is the 30- year fixed rate mortgage the dominant instrument.'' Of course, without the government support that we currently offer, this product likely would not be as ubiquitous as it is today. How important do you think the 30-year fixed-rate mortgage is? Dr. Lea. As you can see, from the data, and I go beyond the countries that I specifically referenced, is that you don't see this instrument around because it has a lot of interest rate risk associated with it. So you have credit risk and interest rate risk that is inherent in mortgages, and you have to distribute that some way. And other countries that have decided that customers can take or be exposed to a bit more interest rate risk, and as a result you don't need the government backstop in order to ensure that you get sufficient amounts of credit and high rates of homeownership. So the fact that we use and built a system around the 30- year fixed rate mortgage has, by definition, almost meant that we have to provide this government support. And I would point out that this didn't work with the savings and loans. We crashed the system back in the 1980's, and we crashed the system again in the mid-2000's. So the question is do we have to build a system based on the 30-year fixed rate mortgage? And if that requires government guarantees, you have a self-fulfilling prophecy. Mr. Rothfus. Mr. Tozer, in your testimony you wrote, quote, ``With their protected government advantage status and the powerful economic benefits that accompany it, the GSEs have achieved gains at the cost of crowding out a potentially significant measure of market competition and additional innovation.'' Assuming that the government provided advantage to the GSEs was diminished or abolished altogether, what would some of the other impediments to private sector competition be? Mr. Tozer. Again, the issue gets back to this whole concept, like Dr. Lea said, you have interest risk and you have credit risk. And so the big impediment to this concept is that you need the government guarantee to support the interest rate investors who are able to take on the credit interest risk, like Mr. Lea said. Banks really can't do it. And the question is do borrowers continue to avoid interest rate risk or do you shift interest rate risk to the borrowers with an adjustable mortgage? And that is the big question. So again, the impediment is that once you take Fannie and Freddie out of the mix and their duopoly, then you need to make sure that you have access to credit enhancement from all the various issuers that enables them to be able to compete on an even playing field with all of the other issuers so we have a well-functioning market for small to medium-sized lenders. Dr. Zandi. Congressman, can I make a quick point about the jumbo market? Mr. Rothfus. Yes. Dr. Zandi. The jumbo market is dominated by large, banking institutions. Those banks are classified as systemically important financial institutions. By definition, they are backstopped by the government, so there is a backstop there. It is not like they are operating in a vacuum without the government back there. Mr. Rothfus. So there is no bank out there that is making a jumbo loan? Dr. Zandi. No, there are, but the-- Mr. Rothfus. OK. Dr. Zandi. --The market is dominated-- Mr. Rothfus. Yes. Dr. Zandi. --The vast, vast majority of those are-- Mr. Rothfus. Mr. Wallison, do you want to comment on that? Mr. Wallison. Yes. Those banks and other banks, not necessarily the too big to fail banks, are also making these loans. And the point is that we studied this market very carefully. We can provide a memorandum on what we found in this market, and in every case where a bank was making a loan since 2014, a mortgage loan, it was lower cost than a GSE loan. Mr. Rothfus. If I can-- Mr. Wallison. What we did was compare the jumbo market to the GSE market saying--just a little bit below the GSE market, a little bit higher than the GSE market for the jumbo loans and we found that those loans that when they were being made were being made at a lower interest rate. So it is not necessary to have a government backing of any kind in order to keep the interest rate at a competitive level. Dr. Zandi. One other quick point-- Mr. Rothfus. My time is expired. I would like to go on, but my time is expired-- Dr. Zandi. Oh, I am sorry. Mr. Rothfus. --So I yield back. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Ohio, Mrs. Beatty, for 5 minutes. Mrs. Beatty. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you to our Ranking Member, and thank you to our witnesses here today. Before I go into my questions, I would like to make a few brief statements. But first, I would like to say to my colleague, Congressman Sherman next to me, I would like to be included in that 30th Congressional District CODEL along with Duffy and Cleaver. So I just want that entered into the record, Chairman Duffy, that I want to go on the CODEL. Now to the witnesses-- Chairman Duffy. Without objection. Mrs. Beatty. Thank you. To the witnesses here, thank you for being here. And certainly while we are here today to talk about sustainable housing finance part three, I noticed that we have certainly not been absent of talking about tax reform. And I was very pleased to see in your written statement, Ms. McCargo, that you addressed the potential impact of the House Republicans' tax plan and the effects it can have on affordable housing. As a matter-of-fact, Mr. Chairman, I would like to submit an article for the record from Politico entitled, ``Tax Plan Would Cut Affordable Housing Supply by 60 percent.'' Chairman Duffy. Without objection. Mrs. Beatty. Thank you. Let me just take a few seconds of my time to quote from that article. And that article states that builders, local governments, and other housing advocates are rallying against a provision of the House Republican tax plan that would eliminate a key funding source for affordable rentals. As a matter of fact, it says the tax proposal would do away with private activity bonds, which we all know is a growing source of financing for low cost housing. The cuts would reduce the supply of new affordable rentals by more than 85,000 units a year or more than 60 percent, according to an analyst from the Novogradac and Company. One last thing, private activity bonds are issued by local or State governments and are designed to attract private capital funds to large projects. They have evolved into a common financing mechanism for housing as the supply of low- income housing tax credit, the primary source of financing and it has been outpaced by the need of low rentals. So with that and hearing from the articles, can you briefly describe the problem you see with regards to the affordable housing when it comes to the Republicans' tax cut bill? Ms. McCargo, do you want to start? Ms. McCargo. Certainly, thank you, Congresswoman. The fundamental concerns, even without the tax plan, the affordable housing issue is a significant issue both on the rental and buy side, on both sides the issue. The Low Income Housing Tax Credit has already seen a lot of pressure going into this, and I think that one of the most important things as a houser, and thinking about what is happening with the tax plan, is that the fundamental decisions that are made--whether it is the mortgage interest deduction, low-income housing tax credits or other plans--is that we are continuously looking at how we can put money that is taken from one part of the plan back into housing. One of the concerns in particular is for example the mortgage interest deduction. If we are looking to really spur home ownership and move forward we might want to look at how we might be able to take--if that was to be reduced--those dollars and how do you put those back in the housing in the form of a tax credit, for example? So I think affordability is a critical issue whether you are renting a home or owning a home across the Nation today. And that the tax plan and the decisions that are made to make cuts or any revisions that affect housing needs to be thought about in terms of how do we make sure that we are enabling affordable housing and finance? Mrs. Beatty. Thank you. My time is about to run out, but I would like to make a brief comment as we talked about earlier when you were asked the question of what is middle class. We all know the numbers that we are given, but I think it is important to say it depends on where you live. Ms. McCargo. Right. Mrs. Beatty. If you take my district, I have the entire city of Bexley, and we have $10 million homes there and $2 million homes, and some of those individuals would probably call themselves middle class that own a $1 million home. So I think to Mr. Sherman's point, it definitely depends on where you live. But also, I was elected to represent rich people and poor people. So I don't think you could make it an either/or or say to her that it is unfair if people want a tax deduction on a $1 million or a $2 million house. So I think we have to figure out how to do both. Not to take away those things for those who are less than middle class, but not to punish others. My time-- Chairman Duffy. The gentlelady's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Budd, for 5 minutes. Mr. Budd. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am also interested in Mr. Sherman's CODEL California. My only fear is that I would check in but never leave. So Dr. Lea, in your testimony you noted that Canada has a government guarantee, correct? Right. So what percentage of the Canadian mortgage market is covered by this guarantee? Dr. Lea. The Canadian system is similar or pretty much modeled after the FHA-Ginnie Mae combination. So in Canada all loans over 80 percent loan-to-value ratio have to be insured, regardless of whether they are held by banks or in securitized form. So the CMHC is providing most of that mortgage insurance, and I think roughly about 50 percent of all mortgages have government mortgage insurance. The second element of that is, like Ginnie Mae, they provide a timely payment guarantee on securities, mortgage- backed securities that are issued and the market share there is about 31 percent. Mr. Budd. So that is a separate guarantee, the timely payment guarantee? Dr. Lea. Correct. It is a layered guarantee. So if you hold the loan in portfolio you don't have that second guarantee, but if you sell the loan then they put that timely payment guarantee on that. Mr. Budd. So by contrast, about what percentage of the U.S. market is guaranteed by Ginnie, Fannie, and Freddie? Dr. Lea. 61 percent is the number there that is the combination. Mr. Budd. OK. Dr. Lea. Oh, no, I am sorry--no. It is 65 percent. It is 31 percent in Canada, 65 percent and then looking around the rest of the world there is no other country that has more than 10 percent of loans securitized and almost all of those are private label. You don't see government guarantees in most other countries. Mr. Budd. So what are the credit characteristics of the loans that are covered by the Canadian government? For instance, what is the down payment requirement or the debt-to- income ratio of the borrowers? And you did mention an 80 percent number earlier, but if you would describe those requirements? Dr. Lea. Right. So after the crisis they used to have 95 percent loan-to-value ratio maximums. They lowered that to 90 percent for purchase loans and 80 percent for refinance loans. They have since relaxed that a little bit and for loans under $500,000 you can go back to 95 percent there. Importantly, loans are recourse in Canada. So that also provides a significant deterrent against mortgage default. Mr. Budd. So is there a limit on the amount of a loan that is covered under Canada's guarantee? Dr. Lea. Yes there is. And that was actually lowered after the crisis. I am trying to remember what the maximum is. There is a maximum cap. I think it is maybe something like $400,000 or so, but I would have to actually check that. I don't remember off the top of my head. Mr. Budd. About $400,000 then. So does Canada have a conforming loan limit? Dr. Lea. No, because they don't distinguish between government and non-government loans. Mr. Budd. OK. And how about any limits on borrower income eligibility? Dr. Lea. They also have that and the most recent numbers I think they will allow that to go up to 45 percent. Mr. Budd. Very good. Thank you Dr. Lea. Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Dr. Zandi. I think it is important to point out that they are willing to move those standards up and down on a regular basis. Unlike here, once we make a change we generally don't change it. They are moving those thresholds all the time. It is a macro prudential tool they use. Mr. Budd. Yes, very good, noted. Thank you. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from-- Mr. Royce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We have a very distinguished-- Chairman Duffy. So the gentleman from California, Mr. Royce, for 5 minutes. Mr. Royce. Thank you very much, Chairman. And you have put together a very distinguished panel here of witnesses today. And I wanted to ask Mr. Tozer, given your past experience, and this is an issue we have spoken about it in L.A. at the Milken Institute out there. But given your expertise, again, if we wanted to explore what the risk transfer deals at Fannie and Freddie and NFIP (National Flood Insurance Program) have taught us thus far, if we look at risk transfer. We have had some deals through the bond and reinsurance market. My understanding is that they could be doing a lot more than they are doing already. Gwen Moore and I have legislation to encourage them to do that. In addition, I have recently been briefed that in light of the damage caused by the hurricanes, the contracts that the NFIP purchased will pay $1 billion of reinsurance. And that would return to the taxpayers 85 cents on the dollar as a consequence of those reinsurance contracts. So given these and other examples, is there any reason why the Federal Government as an entity should not seek to maximize the transfer of credit risk and the transfer of insurance risk and other taxpayer exposures to the capital markets and reinsurance market when practical? Mr. Tozer. I agree. I think you should transfer as much of the expected credit loss as you can. The question you run into is diminishing returns. Most analysis I have seen shows that if you transfer 40 percent of the loan amount, for example, you have a $100,000 loan and you transfer $40,000 of risk to a third party, you are going to cover 99.9 percent of the chance of issuer having to cover a loss. So the question we run into is when does the cost become prohibitive? It is like buying too much insurance for yourself-- Mr. Royce. I understand the concept, but let me ask you, are we currently approaching, in your opinion, the point where-- Mr. Tozer. The thing we need to realize is with the GSEs and when they have a loan that has private mortgage insurance, they are insured down to 65 percent exposure right there. The borrower is paying to get the issuers exposure to 65 percent, so the big area that they are concerned about are the loans with a 20 percent down payment. So I think the concern is making sure the loans that only have a 20 percent down payment are credit enhanced up to at least the 65 percent or 60 percent area. The loans secured with private mortgage insurance are probably close to proper level of credit enhancement because they are at 65 percent coverage level. But I think you need to look at this whole concept what is a tipping point of the cost versus the benefit to the taxpayer. So the question becomes between all of those layers, I think the question is the government should make sure that all the losses are absorbed by the private sector. Mr. Royce. Right. And in your testimony you state that many have cited deficiencies and weaknesses in PLS (private-label securities) contracts, governance structures, and collateral as a leading cause of many billions of dollars of misallocated losses. The misallocated losses spurred a crisis of confidence and the resulting trust gap on the part of the institutional investors who bore them. So we heard similar concerns at our hearings last week, right? Mr. Tozer. Right. Mr. Royce. My question is a straightforward one here to you. What reforms could we make to help prepare the trust gap and reignite the PLS market here? Mr. Tozer. The key is I think we have to have an active master servicer, because what has happened is, for example in the Ginnie Mae world, if an issuer hires a servicer they are on the hook for the losses. So they are going to keep them honest to make sure there is no misallocation. If a servicer messes up, they pay the losses. The same thing Fannie and Freddie are acting as a master servicer to make sure the servicers are held accountable, if the servicers mess up they lose. In the private label securities it was kind of like trust me. The servicer was the fox that kind of, guards the hen house. So the key thing is having a layer of someone there to do the oversight over the servicers to make sure that if they make a mistake that causes losses, that those losses are absorbed by the servicer and not passed on to institutional investors by making stronger contracts, but also having an organization that actually has the teeth to enforce those contracts versus letting the servicers police themselves. Mr. Royce. Anything else that could reignite the PLS market? Mr. Tozer. The PLS market, in general, I think it is always going to be relatively small, not so much because of the credit side. I think there is tremendous appetite for credit investors. The problem is interest rate investors want the homogeneity of being able to have a government-backed security that they could trade. They could trade large amounts in the TBA market. So I think the concept is--I think the PLS market as far as the credit side, through the support CRTs (credit risk transfer), I think it is critical to develop a PLS CRT market because if we can move to the point where more and more credit transfer is occurring, especially if we get to the point where we have more and more issuers that we talked about in the Milken proposal, we need to have a good working private sector credit transfer process. And I think that is what we need to make sure we have in place. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green for 5 minutes. Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank the Ranking Member as well. Thank the witnesses for appearing today. Please permit me to ask a question that was a burning question some time ago. Was the CRA (Community Reinvestment Act) a cause of the 2008 downturn? If you believe that it was, the CRA created the 2008 economic debacle, would you kindly extend a hand into the air? Thank you. Now do this for me, and I want you to be as terse as possible, but this is really important. I need for the record to reflect just who you are. So if you would, let us start to my far left and just give your name and the company that you represent. Would you do so please, sir, at my far left. Your name and the company you represent. Mr. Wallison. My name is Peter Wallison, and I am appearing for myself. I am an employee, however, of the American Enterprise Institute. Mr. Green. Thank you, sir. Next please? Dr. Zandi. Yes, I am representing myself, but I am the Chief Economist of Moody's Analytics a division of the Moody's Corp. I am on the board of directors of MGIC, one of the Nation's largest private mortgage insurers and I am also soon to be the chair of the Board of Reinvestment Fund, which is a CDFI headquartered in Philadelphia that does affordable lending. Mr. Green. Thank you, sir. Dr. Lea. I am Michael Lea. I am a self-employed consultant in Sand Diego, California. Mr. Green. Thank you, sir. And ma'am? Ms. McCargo. Allana McCargo, I am representing myself. And I work for the Urban Institute as the Housing Finance Policy Center Co-director. Mr. Green. Thank you. Sir? Mr. Tozer. I am Ted Tozer, and I am a Senior Fellow at the Milken Institute and basically representing myself as my background, as well as the Milken Institute. Mr. Green. Thank you. This has been a concern that the committee has had to address. I just marvel at how we have gone from the CRA being the genesis of the crisis, and we really did have that debate in this committee. I remember Mr. Frank talking to Ranking Member Cleaver and I about this. And if you recall Mr. Cleaver, we went to the floor because there was the widespread belief that it was the CRA that caused the economic downturn. And this is going to be of benefit to me as I go forward, dear friends. I just want to cite that it is Tuesday, November 7th, 11:43 a.m. All of these noted experts, persons who have some degree of knowledge in this area have indicated to us that it was not the CRA. Now let us move onto something else before I come back to CRA. The jumbos, Mr. Zandi, you wanted to say more about the jumbos and you didn't get the opportunity to. I would like for you, if you would, to be as pithy as you can but please speak on it. Dr. Zandi. Yes. I think the other point about the jumbo market is that it is to very high quality borrowers with very high credit scores, low loan-to-value ratios, low DTIs. So that isn't the market we are talking about here when we talk about housing finance reform. So it is a very, very different market. Mr. Green. And you also mentioned that there is a backstop for it. While it may not be direct, there is an indirect backstop. Would you comment on that please? Dr. Zandi. I would say it is very direct. These are systemically important financial institutions that dominate this market and they have a backstop. And I would also point out in the case of Canada and in most other countries across the world, the lending is done by large systemically important institutions and there is no debate about it. And they have a government backstop. So the system is backstopped by the government explicitly. Dr. Lea. But it is not a mortgage-specific backstop. So banks are diversified and aren't concentrated just in mortgages. What differs in the U.S. is we do that for mortgage- specific institutions. Mr. Green. Thank you. Let us move to one other area quickly. Is there anyone who believes that there should be absolutely no government involvement at all? Remove the government completely, no backstop anywhere involved in this process at all? If so, will you kindly extend a hand in the air? I believe there is at least one. All right sir, I would appreciate your comment. Would you tell me, Mr. Zandi, why you are of the opinion that there has to be some backstop, some government backstop? Dr. Zandi. I think if we want long-term, fixed rate, pre- payable mortgages to be the mainstay of our system, 30-year fixed rate, 15-year fixed rate loans, we need a catastrophic government backstop. It has to be explicit and it has to be paid for. The borrowers have to pay for it. And that is a very doable thing, and we should do it because that is the system that we believe is the appropriate one and that provides the best service to the American citizen. Mr. Green. Thank you very much. I will put a to be continued, Mr. Chairman, on the CRA. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The committee is now going to go into a second round of questions, but we are not going to do 5-minute questions. We are going to do 2-minute questions. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr. Rothfus, for 2 minutes. Mr. Rothfus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am just--during this hearing, really and hearing from all of you and thank you for being here. Mr. Zandi, I just want to go back, and then we talked a little bit about this concept of a catastrophic backstop. Can we quantify that in any way? Dr. Zandi. Yes. I think that the system, the entire financial system is now coalescing around a capital standard for private capital that takes the first 5 percent of loss. After that, that would be considered catastrophic, just to put that in context. Mr. Rothfus. 5 percent of loss of what? How would that play out? Dr. Zandi. Yes, just to give you context. In the Great Recession financial crisis, the Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had total realized losses of not quite 3 percent. And you have to recognize that prior to the crisis, there was no Q.M. rule. There was no governor on the kinds of underwriting they were doing. Post crisis we now have this governor and so the quality of the loans that they are able to purchase and to ensure is measurably higher. So even under the Great Recession scenario where unemployment would get 10 percent, house prices would decline to 30 percent. The stress tests that are being required by all banks and financial institutions, including the Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are being required to engage in, the losses would be measurablly lower than that, probably if you did the arithmetic, 1.5 percent to 2 percent. Mr. Rothfus. Yes, and my-- Dr. Zandi. So 5 percent is a lot of capital. Mr. Rothfus. I might want to follow up with you on that question just to again, get in some parameters-- Dr. Zandi. That is it, it is 5 percent. After that it is catastrophic. That is-- Mr. Rothfus. The question I will follow up with in a written form is, like, 5 percent of what? That is what I am-- Dr. Zandi. That is the number of loans that default times the loss would be incurred because of that default. That is the total loss. Mr. Rothfus. If I could, real quick, go to Mr. Wallison? In your testimony you explained how reduced underwriting standards can actually make housing less affordable. You described our existing affordable housing policy as leading to, quote, ``higher leverage, a lower home ownership rate and reduced affordability.'' And I would guess higher home prices, too? Mr. Wallison. Yes. In fact that is the whole problem, that the-- Mr. Rothfus. And I guess, Ms. McCargo, can you respond? What is--because it makes sense to me what Mr. Wallison is saying, that all these policies have really driven up the cost of housing which it makes it a--it is an affordability issue, is it not? Ms. McCargo. So that we definitely have an affordability issue, I just cannot find the way to express that I don't think that issue comes from 30-year fixed rate mortgage or from the-- Mr. Rothfus. I don't think he is saying that. Ms. McCargo. Yes, or from the government guarantee or the government's involvement in this process. Going back to 2008, if you look at the lending that was going on, which before 2008 leading up to the crisis, and you look at the people, the private label investors that were in the market at that time, and you look at the performance on the loans that were made prior to that period--I would just say 2005, 2006, and 2007--loans made prior to that period where you had a huge proliferation of risky products that were not 30- year straight mortgages. Mr. Rothfus. But weren't Fannie and Freddie securitizing Alt-As and some prime loans, too? Ms. McCargo. They were some. They were not all. There was a huge market called the private label securitization market that was a big market and had much more share at the time than Fannie or Freddie and they were holding those loans. And when 2008 happened, those players disappeared-- Mr. Rothfus. But the portfolio-- Ms. McCargo. --From the market. Mr. Rothfus. But the portfolio of Fannie and Freddie's paper, significant percentage of Alt-A and sub-prime, no? Ms. McCargo. There was a percentage of it. And but it was-- Mr. Rothfus. And my time is way over expired. But Mr. Chairman, thank you. I am going to yield back. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. I am going to change the rules midstream. We are going to do 3 minutes because you did take 3 minutes. Chairman Duffy. So the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Cleaver, is recognized for 3 minutes. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you, Ms. McCargo. Again, thank you for being here. The McKinsey Global Institute put out a study recently which says that by 2025, we will have about 1.6 billion people globally living in homes that are either unsafe and decrepit or housing that is unaffordable that would be available. Do you have any suggestions on ways in which this committee and the U.S. Federal Government, can help create the atmosphere for a larger stock of affordable housing? Ms. McCargo. Thank you. The affordable housing issues have exploded since the crisis. We have seen a lower vacancy, less construction in the affordable space, a lot of constraint on builders. A regulator and the cost of construction to build housing is incredibly high and that makes the building and the ability to create affordable housing stock very, very difficult. One of the key things--and I am just going to go back to the GSEs for a moment--I think that is a good move, is the Duty to Serve rule that is requiring that the GSEs look at the preservation of affordable housing as part of how can they have more of a footprint and an impact on preservation of affordable housing? Most affordable housing stock in America is old. And it needs to be preserved. It needs to be renovated. And there needs to be investment made there such that folks can afford to get into those homes, and we can have more stock brought to the marketplace. I do believe we have a credit crisis on one side where people are having trouble getting into housing. Once this Congress fixes that problem, we then have a serious problem of there is not going to be enough housing stock available for people to buy or rent at this point in time given the direction. Mr. Cleaver. One of the problems when we are talking about rehabilitating housing, which I agree with it, we have done enough demolition, but the cost is going to exceed the value of the home or the property. And so, you get criticized by giving a loan on a property that is not valued at the level of the money that went into it to rehab it. It is a conundrum that many urban areas are facing, and if any of you have any ideas on how to solve that problem, it would be helpful. Ms. McCargo. Can I-- Mr. Cleaver. Yes? Ms. McCargo. One more thing on affordability and again, I will go back to Duty to Serve and the focus that has been put on manufactured housing, modular housing and different types of affordable housing stock. I do think we have the opportunity to think about better financing structures to support those types of affordable housing opportunities is something that, again, the GSEs are looking at and exploring. And I do think that is another space where in housing finance reform and what the GSEs are doing in housing policy there could be help for finding more ways to get at that type of affordable housing as well. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes himself for 3 minutes. Mr. Zandi, you have said several times, I believe, that you believe that the borrowers should pay for their guarantee. Is that correct? Dr. Zandi. Correct. Chairman Duffy. How do you set the guarantee? How do we know that we are collecting enough money to actually have enough resources for that guarantee? I think that becomes the context of the million-dollar question. I don't know, and then I have to get-- Dr. Zandi. Yes, it is a great question. I don't think there is a good answer. I would set it high enough that I would feel very comfortable I am collecting enough money and building that mortgage. I would set up a mortgage insurance fund, just like a deposit insurance fund-- Chairman Duffy. Like a contingency fund of some sort? Dr. Zandi. --And put the money in there and keep building it, and I wouldn't stop. You can do the arithmetic. Go back to the multiple guarantor system, and pay a 10-basis point fee. Chairman Duffy. If we feel like to raid those kind of funds. Dr. Zandi. Pardon me? Chairman Duffy. If we feel like to raid those kinds of funds. Dr. Zandi. No, no. You can't raid the DIF (Deposit Insurance Fund). You can't raid the DIF, so don't raid it--you can't. Just design it exactly the same way so you can't raid the MIF (Mortgage Insurance Fund). It is there to backstop that system if it ever gets in trouble, and just let it build. And it will, it will build. If you put a 10-basis point fee on every mortgage that is insured by the future guarantors that take over for Fannie and Freddie, that will raise a boatload of money, and we will be fine. We will be very conservative. Chairman Duffy. Mr. Wallison, do you agree with that? I know you have thrown all these policies to the side-- Mr. Wallison. Yes. Chairman Duffy. --I know, but-- Mr. Wallison. The private system would work anyway, but just talking about mortgage insurance, the FHFA has required that all mortgage-backed securities be backed by mortgage insurance and has required the mortgage insurance industry to have sufficient tangible assets behind its insurance. So it would be the private system that would set mortgage insurance premiums. The problem with that, of course, and Mr. Zandi didn't address it, is that very risky mortgages with low down payments, with low FICO scores, et cetera, are going to be very expensive under any system where you have a private mortgage insurance. Chairman Duffy. And therefore should you have a one-size- fits-all or do we have to have a guarantee fee that meets the risk of the mortgage? Is that your position, Mr. Zandi? Dr. Zandi. For the catastrophic backstop, no. I wouldn't do that. Chairman Duffy. One-size-fits-all? Dr. Zandi. Yes. And what the other thing I would do, though, is that I would have a clawback ability so that if you ever got into the MIF and you blew away the MIF, and I can't even imagine that scenario, but let us--who could imagine the Great Recession, then you have the ability to claw that back with higher fees in the future to future borrowers on that system. Chairman Duffy. And I only have 30 seconds left. And Mrs. McCargo, I want to chat with you later. We have a housing issue in rural America that is very challenging for us that we aren't able to get our hands around. Ms. McCargo. Absolutely. Chairman Duffy. I am concerned we only focus on urban America and because rural is sparsely populated we don't get the same resources and effort. And it is just as devastating for our communities. I am sorry that we had a conversation about taxes today, but we have seen tax policy and housing policy intersect especially in the conversation of the day. I would just say this. I think when we use economic warfare and talking points, but then we accommodate the talking point with tax policy, all of a sudden we see people get really squeamish. And we start saying that million-dollar homes are for poor people or middle-income people, and it is a head- scratcher for me. Maybe we are better off not playing that economic warfare and go what is the best policy? Let us stop bludgeoning each other, because when you bludgeon each other, you might not get the best policy. And when you see that policy accommodates rhetoric, it doesn't end up being the best policy. With that, my times has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman, for 3 minutes. Mr. Sherman. Mr. Chairman, I wish not to bludgeon you but to invite you to southern California for critically important committee business in January or February. Chairman Duffy. I have already agreed to come. I am there. Mr. Sherman. Yes. Ms. McCargo, you are absolutely right. We need to build more housing. In my area, the problem may be local government and land use planning as much as anything else. We are told that we ought to blame Fannie and Freddie and the Federal guarantee. I would say that perhaps Fannie and Freddie are so pernicious that they caused the meltdown in 2008, 2009 in Iceland, Ireland, the United Kingdom and Denmark and that they have a pernicious effect on home affordability so great that they have made homes unaffordable in London, Tokyo, and Vancouver. So we have meltdowns. Other places have meltdowns. We have some areas with high home prices that are difficult for people to afford. So do other places. What is unique to the United States is that we have the 30- year fixed rate, pre-payable, non-recourse loan very often with a 10 percent down payment. And people whose parents can't afford to help them can still buy a home. Mr. Zandi, the takeaway for me at this hearing is double- digit loss of value of homes in my district. Dr. Zandi. If you give me your address--no, only kidding. Dr. Zandi. In fact, I will send you, if you are interested, a worksheet that shows by county the HPI decline I would expect at--the peak HPI I would expect as a result of the bill. Mr. Sherman. Yes. I need that. Dr. Zandi. I will give that to you. Mr. Sherman. I will look forward to getting that from you and to sharing it with my colleagues from the variety of counties in California. One, we have now, Mr. Tozer, is we have the GSEs. They have seller servicing guidelines. They both have underwriting standards. It is not a race to the bottom in the underwriting standards. You can't have one guarantor cutting its underwriting standards to gain marketing share. One could imagine that if there were a different system, that there would be a race to the bottom, and then many of the mortgages wouldn't have title insurance, wouldn't have insurance to say that it is, indeed, a first priority lien. What are the ways we can prevent a race to the bottom in terms of lien quality if we have more than two guarantors or securitizers? Mr. Tozer. The key is that you need to make sure that guarantors transfer the credit risk to a third party because that way that third party will play policeman to make sure that you don't get out of control. I think the best place to start is the private mortgage insurance companies because they are taking on all the credit risk now. If you don't put 20 percent down, the PMI companies take on the credit risk. So I think credit investors are the good policemen to put a floor in there because they are on the hook for the losses. And then as far as when it comes to the issue of mortgage insurance for it, it gets back to the point again that the guarantors have to take on the catastrophic credit risk because if the mortgage insurances aren't there, it affects them. The government only steps in when the issuer completely fails, because it is a huge incentive to be viable financially before the government steps in. This will avoid the race to the bottom, because the government is not going to bail you out if you survive financially. Mr. Sherman. I believe my time has expired. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman's time has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green, for 3 minutes to talk more about CRA. Mr. Green. Yes, the CRA, and other things. Let us start with the other things quickly. Is there anyone who believes that there won't be a government backstop regardless of the plan if we find that the economy is about to go under? I don't believe in government backstops. I would rather not have one. It is better to plan one than to have to develop one when you find the economy about to go under, as we had to do after 2008 and 2009. Seems like we ought to look at having an orderly process as opposed to something that we have to do on the fly. I remember when the Secretary came in and explained to us that we were about to have a crisis unlike we have seen in our lifetimes, a good many of us. I don't want a government backstop. I just don't know that there is any other choice because we want our economy to continue. And we could have refused to bail out the banks as we see it, but the results would have been catastrophic. If there is anybody who thinks that it wouldn't have been catastrophic, raise your hand, please? You don't think that it would have been catastrophic? I am going to give you 10 seconds on that, maybe 20. Go ahead. Mr. Wallison. I am just saying it wouldn't have been catastrophic. We caused that problem. Mr. Green. But let us talk about the point where the problem had to be dealt with. If we had not bailed them out, what would have happened? Mr. Wallison. Probably nothing because-- Mr. Green. Probably nothing? Mr. Wallison. Probably nothing. Mr. Green. And banks wouldn't lend to each other? Mr. Wallison. The banks were lending to each. By the time-- Mr. Green. No, no, no, no. By the time of the--when we got involved, the banks were not lending to each other. Mr. Wallison. That is not correct. Mr. Green. It is correct. Mr. Zandi, would you give your commentary? Dr. Zandi. Yes, it would have been catastrophic. The system was shutting down. The commercial paper market wasn't working. The large non-financial corporates couldn't get funding. We were on the verge of a complete meltdown. The loss--remember back, January 2009, we lost over a million jobs. In my book, that is catastrophic. And it would have been much, much worse if we had not stepped in aggressively through the TARP. Yes, no one likes bailing out big banks or banks in general. Mr. Green. I am one of those. Dr. Zandi. We actually had to do it. Mr. Green. Yes. Let us go to Mr. Tozer. Sir, would it have been catastrophic? Mr. Tozer. Yes, it would have. I was a mortgage banker back then, and just to put an example, I had mortgage trade on where I had sold a Ginnie Mae or a Fannie Mae security to Goldman- Sachs. And I had bought one from Morgan Stanley, and they wouldn't even take each other's trades. Normally, I would assign the trades. They wouldn't let me assign the trades. Mr. Green. I hate to interrupt you, but I have to say this. This is the problem that we run into. We run into this problem of persons who still believe that the CRA caused the crisis, and that if we had done--you are not one of them, sir. You are not one of them. But there are those who do believe this. And this is a part of the problem that we have in resolving the crisis that will come forward at some point in the future. Trying to find a way to get beyond some of these fallacious arguments that dealt with the crisis that we had to encounter. Look, thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have gone beyond my time. Chairman Duffy. The gentleman-- Mr. Green. I will yield to you time to respond. Chairman Duffy. You have no time left to yield, but I appreciate that. Mr. Green. I will yield the time that I don't have to you. Chairman Duffy. But I thank the gentleman for yielding back. I want to thank our witnesses for their testimony today. I would just note that this is, as we can see, a complicated and involved process. I look forward to, and I think the committee does, to have more in-depth and longer conversations with all of you to make sure we get it right. Thank you for taking the time today and providing your insight and expertise to the committee. Hopefully, the panel will respond in a prompt and timely manner, so you get questions from the committee. With that, and without objection, our hearing is now adjourned. The Chair notes that some Members may have additional questions for this panel, which they may wish to submit in writing. Without objection, the hearing record will remain open for 5 legislative days for Members to submit written questions to these witnesses and to place their responses in the record. Also, without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit extraneous materials to the Chair for inclusion in the record. [Whereupon, at 12:05 p.m., the subcommittee was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X November 7, 2017 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]